An empirical exploration of exchange-rate target-zones

An empirical exploration of exchange-rate target-zones

Carnegie-Rochester North-Holland Conference Series on Public Policy 35 (1991) 7-66 An empirical exploration of exchange-rate target-zones Rob,er...

3MB Sizes 6 Downloads 88 Views

Carnegie-Rochester North-Holland

Conference Series on Public Policy 35 (1991) 7-66

An empirical

exploration

of exchange-rate

target-zones

Rob,ert P: Flood &&rn’ht%‘on~~ ‘konetary

Fund

Andrew K. Rose University

of California,

Berkeley

and Donald

J . Mathieson”

International

Monetary

Fund

Abstract In the sumption determinant

context

of a flexible-price

of uncovered of exchange

interest

parity,

rates.

Daily

monetary

exchange-rate

we obtain data

model

a measure

for the

European

and

the

as-

of the fundamental Monetary

System

*The authors are, respectively: Senior Economist, Research Department, IMF; Assistant Profess0 i School of Business Administration, University of California at Berkeley; and Chief of 9 inancial Studies, Research Department, IMF. Rose thanks the International Finance Division of the Board of Governors of t,he Federal Reserve System and the Center for Research and Management at Berkeley for financial support. For comments we thank: Willem Buiter; Ricardo Caballero; Harold Cole; Susan Collins; Frank Diebold; Hali Edison; Martin Eichenbaum; Joe Gagnon; Peter Garber; Dale Henderson; Alexandra Jones; Karen Lewis; Ben McCallum; Allan Graciela Kaminsky; Eric Leeper; Leo Leiderman; Meltzer; Dick Meese; Dan Sichel; Chris Sims; Gregor Smith; Ken West; seminar participants at Ohio State and Yale Universities; workshop participants at the IMF and the Federal Reserve Board; and participants at the Carnegie-Rochester, CMSG, MSG, and NBER exchange rate conferences. Steve Phillips provided stalwart research assistance; Kellet Hannah and Hong-An11 Tran assisted with the data. We thank Lars Svensson for continuing discussions and encouragement, as well as uncovering an important error in an earlier draft. This is a condensed version of a working paper wit,h the same title, issued as IFDP 388 and NBER WP3543. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent t,hose of the IMF or the Federal Reserve System. 0167-2231/91/$03.50

0 1991 - Elsevier Science Publishers

B.V.

All rights reserved

are used exchange are also

to explore rates

and

considered.

the

importance

fundamentals;

of nonlinearities data

from

three

Many implications of existing

in the other

relationship

between

exchange-rate

systems

“target-zone”

exchange-rate

models are tested; little support is found for existing nonlinear models of limited exchange-rate

flexibility.

I. Introduction In this paper,

we characterize

the behavior

of nominal

exchange

rates dur-

ing managed exchange-rate regimes. When exchange-rate management takes the form of an exchange rate “target-zone,” enforcement of the zone sets up expectations that alter the relationship between the exchange rate and its fundamental determinants. Such effects are the focus of a theoretical literature concerned with exchange rate “target-zones.” We assess the empirical importance of these nonlinearities, focusing on the six long-term participants in the Exchange R.ate Mechanism (ERM) of the European Monetary System (EMS). There are two motives for this paper. First, a comprehensive description of exchange-rate behavior during managed floats is potentially of great value in comparing the merits of alt,ernative exchange-rate regimes. Second, this paper is a contribution to the sparse empirical literature on exchange-rate target-zone models. By implicitly using a. flexible-price monetary exchange-rate model and the assumption of uncovered interest parity, we are able to obtain a daily measure of the funda.mental exchange-rate determinant. With this variable, we search directly for a nonlinear relationship between the exchange rate and fundamentals. We use three different modes of analysis: graphical study; parametric testing for non1inea.r terms; and out-of-sample forecast analysis. We also test) five implications of target-zone models that do not rely on our measure of fundamentals. Our EMS findings are corroborated by data drawn from three regimes of limited exchange rate Aexibility: the post-WWII Bretton Woods era; and the inter-war and pre-WWI gold standards. Our findings are mixed. Our graphical tionship between the excha.nge-rate and it,s different” in an exchange rate target-zone change rates. However, the exchange-ra.te not resemble

that suggested

by current

analysis suggests that the relafunda,mental determinant “looks tha.n it is in freely floating exfundamentals relationship does

theories.

Our pa,rametric

testing

for

nonlinear terms usually indicates that a model that fails to account for the effects of the target-zone is misspecified; nonlinear terms are statistically significant determinants of t,hc exchange rate, although the sign pattern of the estimated coefficients is usually inconsistent with theoretical predictions. However, these effects are also nppa.rent for floating rates. 8

More importantly,

nonlinearities

do not help to predict exchange

when we examine measure

implications

of fundamentals,

of target-zones

rates out of sample. that

Finally,

do not depend on our

we find little evidence of target-zones.

Our mixed findings make us cautious in our conclusions. Our graphical analysis suggests to us that fixed exchange rates behave at least somewhat differently than freely floating exchange rates; this seems unsurprising. However, our more intensive target-zone

models.

study of the data reveals little support for existing

We think our results are not surprising.

Our more inten-

sive statistical work is often quite model dependent. The auxiliary assumptions required to derive close&form solutions for models in this literature seem to be poor assumptions that do not much aid our understanding of the data. We conclude that models of limited exchange-rate flexibility work about as poorly as do models of flexible exchange rates. In the next section of the paper, the relevant theory and our empirical strategy are outlined; Section III provides a brief survey of the existing literature, while a descript,ion of the data is contained in the following section. Section V provides a discussion of how we determine o, a parameter that is important in our model because it is required to identify exchange-rate fundamentals. Our analysis of nonlinearities in conditional means of exchange rates is contained in the next four sections, which constitute the core of the paper. Section VI provides graphical analysis of the relationship between the exchange rate and fundamentals. Parametric tests for target-zone nonlinearities are reported in t,he following section; the forecasting abilities of linear and nonlinear models are compared in Section VIII. Various auxiliary implications of target-zone models t,ha.t do not rely on measurements of fundamentals are analyzed in Section IX. A brief summary and concluding remarks are contained in Section ><.

II. Theory In this section,

we present a. simple model of exchange-rate

target-zones.

We

then use this model to derive distributional implicat,ions for the exchange rate and fundamentals. Finally. we out line our approach to measuring exchangerate fundamentals.

The model The model we use in our study is standard in the target-zone literature (e.g., Krugman (1990), and Froot and Obst,feld (19S9a)). In the model, the natural logarithm of the spot, exchange rate, et, (measured as the domestic currency price of a unit of foreign exchange), is equal tjo a scalar measure of exchange9

rate fundamentals, of change

of the exchange

In the typical that

ft, plus an opport,unity

enter

of cquat ~OII (I ). jc is a linear

market,

of money

demand;

pectation

operator,

Et,

the nature

ing” relevant in the

WC follow

is based

switch,

governing

for exalnplf,,

exchange

market

fin

to protect

order

process.

uiiglit

irl\ml\.f>

lx~lic.!.

to specific

a11 c~sclla~lp-ratc~

in rat,ioilal

f~xpf~ctatiolis is H f’llll(.tio11

additional

that

t IIC~ I’IIIIC~ iota hf> iI twicf,

of thfl

t hc currf~til,

The

precise

process

sta.tv.

form

switches.

of obscrvatioIl, In the

\2:f, co~lsiflf7~

Hencefort~lI.

atwcncf~ of’ airy

where 11 is the drift rate, During

‘A typical simple

procc3s

type

of process

benign

to alkr

neglf~t

the cours(b of that

ttic> SOIW

variable,

wit,h thrb

cont.inuousl~

I)olic.ies aii(l forcing

diffcrent,iablc procfw,f3

wtifxrf‘

on t 11f, nature

of conttmplat

\vf’ will 1ls~~all.v drop the not,atiorl

t)rocfw

s\\-it f,trfx,

f’llnfianwi~tiils

follo\v:

r/f//+ ntl:

(:I!

cT is il posit ivfx coilst ant, and & is a standard s\yitf-hf3.

flrxibl+t)rict~

changes

t IIc ,f t)rowss

IIWII~~~~I~~IIIO~ICI consists

(m - p = &j ~ rri + 5); ~IIP tlrfinit~ion

c,schange

rate.

and an asterisk

Weinri

to anot her procf5s

of: a domestic

money-demand

dc~~otr~ forclgrl

of

variahtes.

and interest, rates leads to ( 1). where t Ile fundamcnt~als 11 denotes velocity. given by L’~ = -@I?/~ + C,~ - p; (1989a)

or Svensson

interest-parity our

analysis

(199Oc).

ecpat.ion;

this

ml

for t,hc t,imcL

t lw wat cxctiange rate (q = E + and uncovered intcrcs( i)ari(y (i - i’ = I:(t/c )/dt); whr-rc 17~ is the tog of thr money p denotes the tog of t,he price level, y ctc~~ot IV, 1hr tog of real income, t dcllotcs the interest rat,f,, E is a shock t,o t lr~, doliml.ic money-demand equation, 4 denotes

equation

uf

for c~znt~~pl~~. f = .q(I. f).

f!/‘ :=

process.

from

t II~’ stat (‘:

of t 11c 9 1’1111clif>11 dqx~~ds

I, writing.

swit.cb

we mean changes

of t11c>relc\-ant state

oIII>.

\;aluv ot’ f’s\ltni71arizf3

cx-

latter

of the model,

wf‘ coIijecl,urc~

iiiotlcls.

rate

frltlctiou

t. The

‘~proccss

One

iutervent,ioIls

senii-

The

ZOII~‘.

t.ion for the exchange condit,ion

time

switching”

swit.ch

rate

here.’

and any

(1983).

of variables

intkrcst

jt, a.nd the structure

Garbcr

a

is the through

condition

and

function

interpret,ation

By “process

f; Flood

fundamentals

As is typical

variable.

of 1,11(xc~quilihriurll

to the forcing

process

0

that.

OII information

values of the only forcing

including

while

quilihrium.

elasticity includes

to the rate

rate cxxpectc~t at- I. Et(de)/dt:

derivation

money

cost, term proportional

(krtaitl

types

is discussctt

to n~ottr~ts wil Ii sticky

prjc(5.

Etirnination are defined

zt). of risk prcmia

furthrr

I)etow.

of cndogenous

y’ - p): supply. r~on~inal the

real

priers

az !I = m( + ~1~(whcrc

See, e.g., Froot and Ohst,fctd can be added to t.hr uncovcml

In fret urc work,

we plan

to ext.cn(l

dictated

by the particular

policy switch.2

Using our trial solution from (2) and invoking Ito’s lemma: E(de)ldt Substituting

from equation

= qg’(f)

(4)

+ (g”/2)g”(f)

(4) into equation

(l),

we

obtain:

s(f) = f + VS’(f) + w2/wv) Equation

(5) is a second order linear

differential

(5)

equation,

which has the

general solution.3 g(f)

= f +

07

Alezp(X1.f)

+

+

A2edhf)

(6)

where x1 = -(?]/a)

+ (l/a2)J_

x2

-

=

-(71/u)

(7)

(l/c”)+l’

+

pa’/(Y)

(8)

The integration constants Al a.nd A;! are determined by process-switching side conditions. Different side conditions result in different settings for the constants. Indeed, during periods of policy volatility, agents’ settings for the As should shift with policy perceptions. Three patterns for the setting of the constants have emerged in the literature. First, if agents pay no attention t,o the policy side conditions, then (ruling out bubbles) Al = A2 = 0.” S econdly, if the target-zone is credible, agents must anticipate that the authorities will stop the drift of fundamentals out of the zone when funcla.mcnt.als a.nd the exchange rate reach the boundaries of the target-zone. Consequently, credible target-zones give rise to “sure thing” bets about fundamentals

at the boundaries.

In order to keep

such bets about fundamentals from being translated into profit opportunities, agents require “smooth-pasting” conditions at the boundaries. These smooth-pasting conditions ensure tha.t the exchange rate will not change in response to anticipated

infinitesimal

int,ervention

at the boundaries.

Smooth

pasting requires Al < 0 and A2 > 0. This result is true for all credible zones, with or without intramarginal interventions. Thirdly, the target-zone may 2Pesenti exchange 3Tlle

Alezp(Alf) similar

allows solution

+ A+rp(A2f).

t,he drift. rate

to vary so as to induce

is f + on, Lewis

(1990)

while the d evelops

mean

reversion

in the

solution of the homogenous part is a different model with qualitatively

properties.

4Froot market;

(1990)

rate. particular

and Obstfeld see also Flood

(1989b)

provide

and Hodrick

a discussion

(1989). 11

of bubbles

in the context

of the stock

are unconstrained until not have full credibility. In t.tlis case, the constants alternative policies are specified; see, e.g., Bertola and Caballero (1990b). Most, of our empirical

work relies

ncit her an explicit

on

model

of interven-

tion nor target-zone boundaries that coincide with the declared boundaries. When we nlake use of t tit, s~wcific functional form suggested in equation 6. anr \ AZ to 1~ free parameters. In much of our work, we always allow ill we do not Thus,

even

coIlstrain

els based

on regulated

1 is a graph interventions zone.’

The model ohscrvablcs.

the rc~ducc+form

equation

work is tlirc,c-ted at the general

our empirical

I3rownian

motion

of the exchange

class of target-zone

for a single

of t.htl exchallgf, rate against, fundamentals at cretliblc exchange-rate bands are used

state

variable.

rat,e. mod-

Figure

when infinitesimal to defend the target

prc~scntctl ~II ccluat iolr ( I ) bears only a limit.cd White t hrt cschangc, rat P is ohscrvahlc almost

direct relat,ion to continuously, the

model offers little guidance on how to observe the triplet ft, CY,&(de)/dt.” We note, however. t#hat if w(‘ (-orlId observe any two mpmhers of the triplet, Our empirical t,hen, by using equation ( I), wc would have t,he third member. strategy entails obt,a.ining ~ncasur~s of o a.nd E,(de)/df and deducing a measure for exchange-rate fundamentals. Ji. ‘l’his approach obviously precludes tests of equation (I ). since thr latter is 11set1 to construct measured fundaOur st,rat.rgy rlocs. howrver, allow IIS t.o construct and compare’ mentals. reduced-form

tquat.ions

It, is relatively Sect,ion

V. Assurniikg

based

on c~q~~ation ( 1 ).

cas>’ to ol)sc,rvc, E,( dc)/dt; covc~rc~l iii1 crvst

parit.y

we defer discussion for cant t-acts of length

of 0 to h:

where: il,h is t,he interest rat<, at titnc, f (x1 domestic funds borrowed for a period of 1engt.h h; i;,h is I hrt col,rt,sl”‘rlc_lillg foreign int.ercst rate; FRt,h is the forward exchange ra.te quot~ctl at t i~nr, t for delivery at f + h.; and E& is the tevel of the spot exchange rate at t,irncx f. The rcalationship between the forward rate and the c~xp~ctrtf f1itlii.c spot rat<> is given by:

6

4 EXCHANGE RATE

2

(e)

reduced form

0 -2

----------

-4 -6

l

-6

1

0 FUNDAMENTALS

Figure 1: Credible

13

Target-zone

5 (f)

where RP,,h is the risk premium at time t for cont,ract,s of length h. If agents the foreign-exchange market IllaxirnizrL t,hca cxpccta.tion of an int,erternporallj separable

utility

funct,iolr.

tjher~:

RPt,h = [C’()l’t(l”(C’t+,~)/Pt+/~. ER,+h)]/[E,(lr’(C,+h)/p~+h] where:

Covt( ., .) denotes

in

t,he c-ovariance

opera.tor

conditional

ut ilit,y of consumption at time t; l.J’(Ct+h ) is 1.h(, nlargillal Pt+h is the price level at time t + h.

(11)

informa.tion

on

at, t,ime t + h; and First. utilit,y

We intend to ignore risk prcmia, in this study for two reasons. Svensson (1990a) ha.s shown that for constant relative risk-aversion

functions, the risk prenlium in a credible target-zone (with potentially moderate devaluation risk) is small. Second. in the empirical part of this study, we rely on daily observations of t,wo-day interest, rates. Regardless of the functiona,l form of the period llt ility funct,ion, the risk premium rmlxdtld in such short contra.cty is liI<(~l>~to I)(, nc~gligiblc, compa.rcd with the rxpect,etl rate of change of the cscl~angt~ rat(x.‘*” Once risk premia hal-t, ht~cn asslImed (IO) to yield: I:‘,( iii?,+,,

risk prrrtlium

in two-(lay

between

I”(Ct+h)/Pt+h

an(l

between

two variables

it, hard over In

t,o believe

the

our

course

view,

at, least rat,e

that.

both

risk

of the further

days

and

rat(’

prenlium

exchange

rati,.

al)nut

go

woultl Ovc,r

;rssulllillg

hotll

can

be rspected

surprises compared the

risk

to wro over short go to zero

longc,r away

fast,er

cont.ract

over wit,h prc,miurll

horizons, than

periods,

risk prernia.

conditional

Engel

would such

t,wo

covariancc covariancc

in the two magnitudes.

plans

ark sticky while

applying

‘I’he conditional

of surprises

pricing

Thr-r+,forf>,

and

bc dutx to two-day

t,o r~~atcl~ eschangr-rate

horizorl

less complacent

provide

consulnptiorl

of t.htx c,xchangc,

consumption-based much

would

WIIP~C h is two-days.

pricc>s a11d corlslllllplio11

at. till, ‘L-day

of change

cottt racts

is tllf\ (>xpcac.t(>d I)roduc(.

of two

of change

(1’)

= (I + it,,,)/( 1 + l;,J

)/I:/<,

I:‘/<,+,,

(!I) antI

quat.ions

logarit hrns of c,ach sitlc of this cquat,ion. we arrive at.:”

Taking natural . . approximations, ‘The

away. we combine

We find

to change t,he same the and

exchange, the

we think the

nluch

t.wrrdays. rate-,

rxpect~~tl t.hat

expected

as a nlont,h,

(1990) and Hodrick

t,ht, rattt

WP are (1987)

analysis

“Bertola and Svr~~sson ( I UUU):I\ low that t IIC~implied two-day forward raLe. ( I + should tw a biased predictor of ER,+,, in our &+h)E’n,/(l + i;+h) w t Lere h=two-days, dat)a samples (which arc between EMS realignmrnt,s). Standard tests of unbiasedness on our EMS data do in f;lct rcljcct tlrts 11u11 hypothesis of unbias4ness. This is a standard finding

for floating

“The

rates

approximat.ions

(Hodrick arc:

In(

( 11)X7),Drool, and Thalrr (1990)). 1 + i) - 1n(l + i*) z i - i’ and In(EtERt+~/ERt)

(&et+,, -et). The second approxirnxtion logarithm is a nonlinear opcralor, which using only t,weday forrlcasts. otlr r’rror this

assertion

exchange We found

rate that

by sirnulat.ing

t,llr> aI)pi-oxl~ilat

wit11 1.11~ zonk

bountlarieh

thcx av~ragc’

z

is lnuch the more worrisome of the two since thr irrducrs Jcnsr~n’s inquality problems. Since WC artof approximation may h(x small. WP investigated 2.25

ion rrror percent

;rl~sc~l~~lr~;il,l,rosiirl;rt,iorl

for

a credible

around f’rror

central is abolit,

t.arget-zone parity

and

on

t.hcl

o =

I. lr(, of t.hr> avrragc

1

Etet+h - et = it

h

i$,

-

(13)

When we study flexible exchange rates below, we find that our exchangerate model works well, despite our assumption of uncovered interest parity. We observe interest rates on contracts with a two-day maturity; by equation (13), that is equivalent of the exchange exchange

rate.

to observing

We treat

the two-day expected

the two-day expected

rate as the instantaneous

expected

rate of change

rate of change of the

rate of change of the exchange

rate. Succinctly, we measure exchange-rate fundamentals as fi G e, -cr(i -i*)t. Even assuming that uncovered interest parity holds, this measure will not be literally correct as long as cy is unknown; we use sensitivity analysis to account for uncertainty about cr. Also, this measure does not directly link exchange rates to “raw” fundamentals such as money and output. Nevertheless, for reasonable choices of CI, all interesting moments of the f distribution will closely match moments of t,he e distribution in the sampZe. Given the poor performance of exchange-rate models that use raw fundamentals, compelling argument for 0111‘measure of fundamentals.‘0 III. Previous

this is a

findings

Most previous empirical examinations of nonlinearities in exchange-rate behavior have focused on non-linearities that affect even moments of the exchange rate process, often the conditional variance of the exchange rate. For instance, it is known that excha.nge rates manifest substantial leptokurtosis; conditional forecast varia.nces of exchange rates also exhibit serial dependence (Meese and Rose (1991) p rovide references). However, relatively little empirical work has been done to link mentals in an intrinsically nonlinear to be no theoretical reason to pursue (1990) and Smith and Smith (1990) side conditions

imply deviations

the level of the exchange rate to fundafashion. Until recently, there appeared such avenues. The papers by Krugman p resented exchange-rate models where

from the linear exchange-rate

solution.

There is another, more important, explanation for the dearth of nonlinear empirical work on conditional means of exchange rates. Empirical work on exchange-rate determination has been dampened by the negative results of absolute expected rate of change of the exchange rat,e. We are also assuming tions costs.

away any measurement

So long as bid-ask

spreads

error which may be the result of transac-

are small in relation

to interest

differentials,

this

error is likely to be very small. “Our

methodology

fundamentals answer Obstfeld

can,

are difficult

the question

we think,

be extended

to measure,

of interest.

fruitfully

to other

so long as reduced-form

One example

(1989b).

15

is the existence

environments

estimates of bubbles;

where

allow one to Froot

and

Meese and Rogoff (1983). 11ww and Rogoff demonstrated equipped wit,h a. variety of linear structural exchange-rat,e ex post

knowledge

to forecast

more

of the, dr~terlrlinants accurat.c,ly

than

a naive

noted that ta.rget-zone modt~ls require set of fundamentals to which a(ltlitiollal presence

of a ta,rgct-zone;

at the very least,

of such random

models

that models would

walk model.

and a.ct,ual not

he abk

It should

bet

a strrlctnral linear model (that is, a nonlinear terms are tacked on in tllc>

see cqliat ion (6)) . so that. target-zone

all t,he problcnls

a forecaster

of fioating

excha.nge-rate

models

have,

models.

Only a small amount of rf,lt>vanl. clnpiricat research has been conduct~ed to date. Almost without, cxcept~ion, econon1ist.s have t,aken heed of t.he negative result,s of Meese and Rogoff and abstained from posit.ing explicit parametric much of t.hc work present,4 below is models of fundament.a.ls (in contrast,. techniques and find parametric). Meese and ROW ( 1990) use nonparametric little evidence that nonlinear models fit exchange-rat,e data hct)ter t.ha.n linear models during fixed eschangc>-rat c periods. I)icbold and Xason (19YO) and Meese and Rose (1991 ) find c~olllpa.rablc rcslllt,s hot 11 in-sample and out-ofsample during float,ing eschangc~-rat<, rcgirnc’s. using Itrrivariat e and mult ivari(1990) usfl 1.hf, ate data, rcspectivel!,. S~WIICY~I‘ ( IWO) RII~ Smit.ti and Spmcf,r method of simulated momcl~t s to a\.oitl positing an explicit) empirical model of funda.menI.als ill n~octc~ling ts. ~%=rt.ola and (:aba.llcro (199Oh) prcsr,llt. infornlal (~vidf~ncc OII t trrc>c aspects of two EMS excha.ngta rates from the ea.rly- t.tirorigtl Iriitl- l!)SOs. Svrnsson (199Ob. 199Od) uses a variety of techniques wit 11 Swctlistl data to t.c,st. and corroborate a model of target-zones with realignmcllt risks wit.hout relying on a model of frlndamcntals. Pessa.ch and Razitl (l!)!)o) is t tic paper that is closest t,o ours in spirit: they use Israeli data in a ~)ara~twt.ric fashion and fired evidence of symmetric nonlinear effects implicrl l)!- target -zfJilc ~rmflf~ls iii t hf, rate of ctiangf* of t tic exchange

rat,<,.

IV. Description

of the data

The major focus of this paper is the F:1IS regime of fixed. but adjustable, exchange ra.tes. We concctntratc on t trc, ICiLlS both for its intrinsic and current. interest, and for easy comparisorl with the lit,erature. Relevant fcnt,ures of the institutional structure of the E3,IS a.re described in Folkerts-1,anda.u and (1989). Mathieson (1989) and C:ia.vazzi and Giovannini Our EMS da.ta were obtained from t.he RIS. We also use non-EMS countries. and for I’MS collntries during the period ERM.” The da.ta are daily; exchange rates arc recorded at the fixing” while int,erest rat,es arc arlnualizctl simple bid rates at,

I fi

RIS data for preceding the da.ily “official 10 a.m. Swiss

time.‘2~‘3~‘4 We focus on 2-day interest rates (which will be taken to be “the we use l-month and 12rate,” unless explicit,ly noted otherwise);

interest month

rates

t,o check our results.

Two-day

interest

rates

have been used

because they are the shortest available interest rates (they also reflect the yield on a deposit that has the same maturity as the two-day settlement period in foreign-exchange markets). l5 The interest rates are Euro-market rates and should be relatively free of political, credit, settlement and liquidity risk premia, at least for interest-rate differentials across different currencies at the same maturity. I6 Two-day

interest

rates are unavailable

for Denmark

and Ireland until February 1982 and November 1981, respectively.17 data have been checked for errors in a number of ways.” “The

rates

are averages

13Belgium

has

used

for current

EMS

rules

account

market; rate

14We treat,

each

daily

or holiday that

analysis

financial

not

The and

observat,ion time

effectively

We use

central

rate

floats

and

ignoring

any

stops

on the time-series

our

cannot

parametric

results

are never

“The that

work

risk

with

premia

different

interest

rates

political

risk

this

problem.

they

could

even

Italy. Giavazzi The longer risk,

and

liquidity

17Japanese ‘sin

and Giovannini version of this

by computing

of our

excessively dummies do differentials

from

In some

other

of

data;

our

markets domestic

reflects

payments

the

fact

systems

in

which

issues

of the

the yields

of funds

the

once

it should

the differentials currencies

matures.

be relatively

unchanged

also

during

as well as between Moreover,

this

help

a particular

domestic

wedge

for countries

discussion. (1989) p rovide further paper contains discussions of credit

risk,

free of

to alleviate

demonstrated

markets,

uniform

Euro-currency

be relatively

should

on instruments

eased

deposit

between

should

Euro-markets

de-

it is physically

this period, political risk the extent of the political

currency.

progressively

Eurc+currency

in which

deposit,

Thus,

the

of the country

period, in different

and

offshore

may

vary

over

time

such

as France

and

settlement

failure

premia.

short-t.erm

particular,

been

As much

levels.

data

day-

implicitly

we are not

significance Friday

our

of, e.g.,

we are

t.hat. day-of-the-week levels and interest-rate

in the

the bank

were relatively

in the same have

place

several

in t,he Euro-currency controls

take

in different

across bet,ween

also checked

weekends.

is

division.

on the transfer

m&u&y

controls

a wedge

and

which

to following

account

of the data,

capital controls throughout study of the EMS. While

denominated

capital

no special

in foreign-exchange

that

of denomination.

Sampling

denominated capital

the

affected.

deformation,”

out

by the government

or taxes

with

on deposits premia. If such

instruments because

vary

currencies

rate,

in the t,ransaction.

the possibilit,y

restrictions

introduce

currencies,

are involved

Italy have maintained are important in any

might

across

must,

be confronted

new

As France and considerations risk

reflects

by this period

of funds

currencies

may suddenly

located

affected

We have

at, conventional

also separated

set.tlement.

transfer

whose

“Political posit

tweday

ultimate

countries

be rejected we have

substantially

typical

the

generally below,

freely.

on holidays

worried about this assumpt,ion. Furt,her, the hypot.hesis not enter significantly into regressions of exchange-rate on a constant

official

is committed

are not

take

“time

properties

the

bank

our conclusions

identically,

By

depend

markets. Belgian

the financial

data,

effects.

economic

does

Euro-markets.

exchange

t,ransactions.

with

of-the-week

several

of dual

for the official

key results

assuming

across

a system

The

interest

we checked descriptive

rates

for outliers

st,atistics

are also unavailable from

and examining

both

levels

until and

early

1982.

log-differences

t.he datagraphically.

Some

of the series 150 apparent

IJnless rates;

otherwise

for interest,

noted, rates,

plus the int,erest

rate

work.

is trcatfld

Germany

are always differentia.ls

tli~ Dhl

pricf,

use natural

always

as t Ire “home” of 011c unit

of colllparison.

of exchange

logarithm

of one

by 100.” In our EMS so that exchange rates

divided

country,

of foreign

C~erniai~ intf~rf3l

logarithms

11se the natural

p0int.s).

(in percentagf‘

are always

For the purposes

we always

wft almost.

exchange,

ratf,s minus

and

foreign

interest-rate

interest.

WP also 11s~ data for the period

change rates t,hat preva~ilcd drlring the classical gold standard. rat,e dat,a arp taken frown Andrew ( 1910). who tabulates data

rat,es.2”

of fixed cx-

Our exchangeon weekly nom-

inal exchange rates of the 1I.S. vis-i\-vis the I1.K.. France, a.nd Germany for The rat,es are the a.vcrage of weekly t,hc National hlonet,ary (‘orrlrrlission. int,erhighs and lows. licmmcrt~r ( I!) IO) Jprovides weekly data on American est, rates. also gatherf~d for t hc Nat iollal Monet.ary (bmmission. The rate% is a week1.y average call loan ratf, for t 11(xNYSE. The National Monct,arv (‘ommissiorl ( 1910) tahlllatt,s 13ril isll call Irlonr’y rates and French “market from hack rates of disf,ollnt ..* Our (’It\rlrlall irtt c,rc,st-rat v data wcrf’ gathered issues of 7’hf ~f~ouorttrsl. ‘l‘tifb c.lassical golf1 st antlard flat a span lSS!b 190X. ‘I’hfw data arc monthly We also usf’ data OH t hc intt,r\var gold standard. a.nd are t,akrn from hrrking trud :\/orjr tclr,!J .4tntistics 1914-1941; the data ifa f~sf.hangf~ raic3 are averages of flail)span .lune 1925 t,hrorigli .July I!):< I. ‘1‘1 rates; interA rates arf’ II~llall>. s~lortbtcr111 ‘.privatf> fliscount rates.” Finally, we use mont,tily caxchangc rates. Inrlirnior~.

data

frorlr

Ttifw

data

1Irf> tjr.f,t 10~ l\‘ootls wfw‘

ol)t ainfd

regime

of adjustahtc

1‘1.0111 l,lic, OFX~I~‘s

‘l’hc ex~.l~it~~go rat (‘5 it[‘f’ Imilrt -itI-t ilrrrl spot. r;tks. q~~otf~(l l’or 1Jkrf~c~-rrrolrtII clolwst

:llnin while

pf,gged t:‘co7torrric~

the int,erest

The data are drawn frolri the lolrgf~st siriglt> l)f,riotl of f3f~~iiirigf~-ra.lc traIlqiiiliiy fliiritrg the 1960s (e.g.. t.tlo (:~~~III;III data Iqirl aftcsr t hcb\larch I !j)tiI revalllation arlcl end before the Octohr,r I!Ki!) rft\-alliat ioli ). t’i)r hot h the gold standarfl and raks

arf‘ usually

Hret,ton Figliws

b’igure

if.

‘t’rf~as~lr?;

Woods c1at.a. 1tic l..S..\. is t.rf~alf~(l as tlifl liorlw 2 and 3 colit aitr plots of’t tiv hasif, daily data

2 colitains

t illif’-s(>rioh of t Iit> Iloillillal

cxcha.llgf‘

hills.

colintry.

for t hc EMS pf,riod.” rates

(mcasrlrf~fl,

as

always, as the natural

logarithm

of the DM price of one unit of foreign ex-

change);

the upper and lower (implied)

included

in the graph.

EMS exchange-rate

Tick marks along the bottom

bands are also

of the diagrams

delin-

eate calendar years; the ticks along the top mark realignments which affected either of the two relevant currencies (e.g., either the DM, the Belgian Franc, or both, in the case of the DM/Bf r rate). Figure 3 contains time-series plots of the 2-day interest-rate differential (as always, the German rate minus the foreign rate). As is true of most of our graphics, scales are not directly comparable across countries; the Dutch exchange rate has actually been much more stable than the Italian exchange rate, even though the relevant exchange-rate bands appear wider on the graphs. The EMS

has experienced

a number

of realignments.

Our use of fine

frequency data enables us to split our data into thirteen different corresponding to the periods between the twelve different realignments EMS.22 We divide our data for a number of reasons. A split sample us to check the sensitivity of our results. Dividing the sample also

parts, of the allows allows

us to check for policy shifts such as the often-noted increasing credibility of the EMS (which should result. in changing types of nonlinearities) and timevarying capital controls. 23 Bertola and Caballero (1990a) also argue that the nature of the nonlinear relationship is expected to vary over time with the level of reserves. The thirteen different samples are tabulated below; it should be noted that the number of potential observations varies dramatically across regimes. In virtually all of regime-specific work below, data for the business 22The exact

ERM

realignments

were as follows

(percentage

changes

in bilateral

central

rates are also shown):

Regime

Date

Belgium

13-3-79

EMS Begins

Den.

24-9-79

+3.0

29-11-79

$4.74

France

Ger.

Ireland

Neth

-2.0

22-3-81

+6.0

4-10-81

+3.0

21-2-82

-5.5

+3.0

-5.5

$8.5

12-6-82 8

21-3-83

-1.5

-2.5

$5.75 +2.5

9

21-7-85

-2.0

-2.0

-2.0

10

6-486

-1.0

-1.0

11

3-8-86

t3.0

-4.25

+2.75

-4.25

-5.5

+3.5

$2.5

-3.5

-2.0

-2.0

+6.0

-2.0

-3.0

-3.0 +8.0

12

12-1-87

13

5-l-90

23Government

Italy

-2.0

-3.0

-3.0 +3.7

authorities

and differ from declared

may also defend implicit. target-zones

t,argrt-zones;

split,ting the sample

19

which change over time

may alleviate

this problem.

‘I

.05

'2b1'6 Years

"'

2i2'

Japan

Calendar

Ireland

“’

-0

-0

&, 2915 Years

“”

Belgium Relevant Realignments

o-’

- 0412

"I'

vary by Country Relevant Realignments

'-,a,,!,,, 0 Calendar

,045

Scales

165 Calendar

Y t2bi’k

Years

13

-

UK

Calendar

1990:5:

#2b1'& Years

16

Figure 3: Interest Rate Differentials

0

Denmark Relevant !?eallgnments

14’1

1979:3:

-1775.,,

-

Relevant Realignments

,’ Calendar

'2$1'& Years

-1262-m,,

0

1

USA

Calendar

I,

Netherlands

Calendar

'2b1'i

'2b1'6 Years

Years

France Relevant Realignments

0

-3.95 -,

Relevant Realignments

As

is

well-known.

t.o test work samplf,

for

t hfx ICIZIS has hf~~~iit~ illcrf3sirlgly

lxdwfw1 rfxligll1llf~lit.s

the periods

that

ot,ller

WC kntl

mallil;3t

t,o f’oc~is on

corlllt r.v; t,his is apparf7rt arc

dads),

associatfd

ncithf>r hand,

‘l‘lif77

f’ \~)lat ilit.!. \xrif,s

arc’ tllr>.

interest,-ratf%

;Issociat.fd

Ll’hilc

\ulat,ilit,>.

t.o lx

kss

recent by

wit II f~sccptionall>~

fliff;~rf~llt ial:, ~~11

time

descriptive

more

(meastlrcd

la.rgc, difff~ix~tlfx~:-~~~tm+ cx)llilt rks

art’

over

iI1 l~igltrf~ 2. 2s \vcll a.s siml)lc wit.11 lligll

empirical

as it, is a long

t argfxt-zolrf>.

dramatically

papf~).

we inknd

In our

of tjhf, MIS,

crfdihle

in t.hc sense-

longer;

crttlihilit~y.

t IIV t~~~lft Ii rcgimc

it1 t IIC b\orl;illg

tal,lllatcd

trot, grnrrally other

of iilcrtasiilg

of tl;Lt,a tlra’iz’ll 1’rotll a IJo1 fblrt iillly

Wfa 110tfx t.llat. fxdikiuge-ra1 (which

at ioIls

fxdihlc

S~Y’III t.o lx growing

for fxcl~ st.at,ist,ics

regimes

historical

low volatility. volatile

ill Imtli

morf’

arc> st an-

OII the rfxcf-ntly.

exchange-rat,c

and

ratfx volat,ililv

t hari t lit ot 11cr l:hlS

t IIC Nf,t hcrlantls ha.s much lower exchange roullt ries. Ilowf~vf7~. 110 t.ratle-off I)f+ween

exchange-rak

alItI irlt f>rf>st-tliflcrcxllt

ial \.olat ilit,?: is apparf‘nt,

Ilri’ -1 pro\:idcs

stackf~cl

intcrcst,-rat

variate

c \olat

fift,l-ortlcr

ilit.>.. I>or illst anut.

l)ar (.lli\l’th oI’s( illlfliirfl

in t,hc t1at.a.

tlf’viiIt ioIls of rf3idrlals

\..:I11 of’ irltf~rc~st -rat fx (liffcrcnt,ials

and

cscha.nge

from rates.“’

Figa bNo

m 1

2

4

5 6

3

4

5

6

Eelglum

3

stderrre

2

8

9 10

7

r-In

0 stderrrl

7

c] stderrel

11

12

1113 12

13

,

1

2

3

# stderrde

4

5

6

fl stderrdl r-I

4

5

6

Ireland

1 stderrle

1

9

10

0 stderrll

8

1113 12

11

12

13

1363

01

2

3

1 stderrfe

4

01

2

3

2833

0

1

I

2

3

stderrle

rl

5

6

Denmark

0257

01

I

1

2

3

stderrbe

4

5

6

Italy

4

8

9

10

n

9 10

7

8

9

10

0 stderrbl

7 8

0 stderrll

7

8

9

10

6

ill3

11

12

12

13

013

0

1

1

1

I

7

8

9

10

3 4

UK

O

5 6

Figure 4: Conditional

Volatility

Measures

7

2

3

stderrae

4

USA

5 6

9 10

7 8

9 10

0 stderral

8

n stderrhl

Netherlands

2

Stderrhe

France

Interest Dlfferentlal and Exchange Rate Standard Errors

Japan

7

5

0 ‘stderrfl

1113 12

11

11

12

12

13

13

-orlllslpl

0839

oiJllihi

01

1 stderree

‘1325 11111111

0249

.I243

Residtia: Standard Errors of Exchange Rate ar?d Interest Dlfferentlals Data for 13 EMS Regimes, from blvarlate 5th order VARs: Scales Varv

relationship deliver

is apparent

the same

Iwtween

the two measures

result. and are contained

(uncondit,ional

in t.hr working-paper

estimates version).

[Init-root

trst.s (allowing for wrial dependence through the rnethod sugthat unit-roots are pcrvageskd by Perron (1988)) indicat,e. unsurprisingly, sive throughout the dat,a (t hc statistics are tahula.ted in the working paper). More precisely. the null hypothesis that. a IlllitLroot exists cannot, usuall! be rejected

at conventional

fundamentals

(using

significance

Q =.l):

Itw~ls in each of: the excha.nge

alltl t,hc interest,

differential.25

While

rate:

this Inay

be the result of low power (Froot alld Ohst,feld (19901))), it, is extremely dist,urbing that the interest differential appears t.o be nonstationary. ignoring drift ~ the difference het,wcel1 t II(~ c>xchange rab and fr1ndamenta.b is the expect,ed rate change of the excha.nge ra.t,e; ullcovertd interest parity implies that, the latter is the same as the interest, different,ial. A nonstat,iona.ry irlterest diffcrelit.ial is illf-onsistcwt \vit II crcdihle target -zones: t hc persistence in t.llix seric3 which c‘;~lll~r)t I)(’ ;~c.c~ollrltc~l for 1)). f~~ll~lillll~~Ilt~~lS will ret 11r11lo haunt, 0111’tlypot tiesis t cxsts 121 t (‘I’. cannot typicall!, I)(% ‘l‘liv hypot licsis t,tiat f~t~~(l;~~~rc~titals Ilavr, ii Iinit-root Ie\:els. III fact. t,lie assumption t.liat rr:jccted at conventional sig:llifi(.allce furidalncntals follow a drift Ic+. ra~itlonl walk, while not likrally true, serwi~ t,o Iw a good

approximat

V. Deternlination Our

of

i011.”

alpha

strategy will 1-w to fiti(l a11 al)l>rol>rialc rnr,yf for 0: wv t hcW conduct 0111 for reasonal)lc \.iil~iw of 0 sl)afiliillg this range. We cst,imate 0 I)! two mct,Iiods. First. \vv 1i5v Olil' (la12 to (31 inlatr> 0. SNond, w(’ 11w cstinnat,cs aria.l;sis

frown the litcrat uw.

Estimating

CYfrom

If the increments intervention

daily data

to fare

generated

by equation

to defend a target-zone,

(3) with infinitesimal

then integrating

band

dfover one day results

in: .ft where. the discrete-time

ft-1

(14)

et

7) +

=

period is one day, 7 is the daily growth rate of fun-

damentals, and tt, which is the integral over one day of gdz, is the daily disturbance to the fprocess. Substituting from equation (14) into equation (l), we obtain: et -

el_l

=

n[Et(de)/dt] - [Et-l(de)/dt] + et

77 +

(15)

Equation (14) can For estimation we replace Et_,(de)/dt with (i,_, - &). then be used to estimate 17 and cy. The structural parameters (Y and 7 are identified because fundamentals are exogenous almost everywhere. Our estimates of alpha are presented in Figure 5. This figure graphs the point estimate of alpha with a two standard-error band.27 The estimates are almost uniformly small, although they vary considerably across country and EMS regimes. With the exception of a few imprecise estimates for Denmark and France, there is little statistical evidence that alpha exceeds .25 for EMS countries; lack of interest-rate volatility makes it much more difficult to pin down cy for non-EMS countries. Indeed, there are numerous negative estimates of alpha; the hypothesis that alpha is zero does not seem unreasonable from a purely sta.tistical point of view (although we exclude that possibility, and hence many of the point estimates, (1 ~riori).‘~

27As sample of varying 2sWe tution

have

also

of actual

typically mate

size varies

confidence tried

to estimate

exchange-rate

delivers

tional

volatilities

ARCH-like

The

the residual

purposes). plus

assumptions

than

data,

estimates

our

bands

-1.

since

One

could

correspond

could

to intervals

t,his method (this fby

approach

f; it is potentially reflect.ions

for the f process.

2.5

on McCallum’s

movements;

above,

be extended

also measure

target-zone

relies

volatilities

volat.ilities

to be f. This

about the

As discussed

differentials;

for conditional

which

of anticipated

conditional

technique

the constant

on additional are

in place

of a near

latter

specification

for estimation

error

o wit,h a technique

regime-specific

of int,erest-rate

zero.

the t,wo standard

changes

estimates

(Y by regressing

of cy near

by regime,

levels.

we have

typically would

deliver

regressing has the

(i-i’) advantage

with

of fundamentals

data

technique

tried

rates

delivers

regimes

important

also

of exchange

within

substi-

this

to esti-

on condian estimate

by employing more

on e and of not sampled can

an

observations

bias

defining

depending less finely coefficient

i

0

Estimates

of a in the literature

We have interpreted money demand,

a as the negative

of the interest-rate

semi-elasticity

of

a parameter

that plays a widespread role in both theoretical This parameter has previously been estiand empirical macroeconomics. mated in the literature; Goldfeld and Sichel (1990) provide a survey. The short-run semi-elasticities reported are quite similar to one another and average -.4.2s330 These estimates by the average

quarterly

are converted

to long-run elasticities

speed of adjustment,

.32/quarter,

by dividing

giving a long-

run semi-elasticity estimate of -1.25, which we take to be representative semi-elasticity estimates for industrial countries during normal times.

of

There are two ways to apply these estimates to daily data. First, in the spirit of the models upon which equation (1) is based, one can think of a model of continuous long-run money-market equilibrium such that an appropriate choice of o is 1.25. More rea.listically, one can think of equation (1) as resulting from a Goldfeld-style partial-adjustment model of the money market.31 In this view, it is the short-run, interest-rate semi-elasticity which is relevant to the problem; this is obtained by dividing -.4 by 90 days per quarter, giving a daily short-run semi-elasticity of -.0044, so that a=.0044 seems appropriate. Our various methods of uncovering (Y have led us to a range for this parameter. We think of cr=.l as being a reasonable value; a=1 is certainly representative of the high end of the range, especially given our point estimates. In preliminary estimation, we searched a grid of (Y values spanned by (.05, 3.0). I n most of our work below, we report results based on cu=.l 2gThe

average

units

so that

that

10 percent

estimates The

need has

change

of asset

mean

prices.

that

historical

30The periods;

Goldfeld 1962:l

Italy closely

interest-rate

semi-elasticity.

summarized

convention,

the

product

Under

report and

units

are the

units

study

interest-rate

the

Goldfeld

units and

so

Sichel

of a speed interest

of adjustment, demand,

having

or expected

annualized

interest

rates

rates

of

so our

years.

rather

than

equations. of cy are

we use two-day

Also,

too

low;

Euro-rates

increased Canzoneri

are

currency and

Diba

usually

used

substitution (1990)

as may

discuss

the

further. and

Sichel

report

involve

- 1985:4,

Japan

1966:l

- 1985:4,

it is important

chose

We choose

of money

of the

1971:1-1985:4, U.K. 1958:1-1986:l. the results for t,he US. in terms

in a single

they

as 10.

semi-elasticity

time

this

rates

estimates

1969:1-1985:4, match quite 31However,

our

of the

have

substitution

estimates Canada

but

as .lO.

quarter,

in money-demand

of currency

is -.004, entered

Sichel

inverse

interest

report, was

Throughout

domestic

rates

effects

the

semi-elasticities

Quarterly interest

per

Sichel

for example,

by 100.

and

percent are

and

year,

is ent,ered

Goldfeld

which

interest-rate

per

to be multiplied

units

units

Goldfeld

per year

estimates

which time

number 10 percent

to recall

model-determined

t,hat

the st,ate

analysis.

27

the

following

France

countries

1964:1-1985:4,

The results for these of the magnitude of the

assumption variable

that

and

countries short-run

fundamentals

is maintained

data

Germany

throughout

can

be the

and cu=l. Several different manifestations of the data a good choice for this key paranleter; see also Diebold Given frequency

differentials

our measure tials.

that

cr=.l

is

an cy value, t,he fundament,als can be measured at the monthly and compared with t.hc tradit ionA reduced-form determinants

of flexible-price exchange-rak monthly IFS measures of Ml rithmic

indicate (1986).

between

models, money, and output.32 WC obtained and intlust.rial production,33 computed loga(icrman

of fundament,als

The regressions

and

on act.ual

are compukd

foreign

variables,

money-supply

from 1979

and

through

and

regressed

output

differen-

1990 on a count.ry-by-

country basis. Our measures of fundamentals are typically highly correlated in levels with actual money and out,put, differentials; for instance, the R2sfor our six countries have an a.verage of .63. On t,he other hand, the coefficients on actual fundamentals are not signed consist,ently, and there is substantial residual autocorrclation. 111 first-diffcrc,ncc~s. our fundamental measures arc’ essentially

uncorrelatcxtl

VI. Graphical

A direct

with

~lloncl~- nrrtl out put.

analysis

escl,,m.in,cr,,tron

tions hip In this sect.ion of the paper. LVCana.lyzc the rclat.ionship between exchanges rates and funda.mentals, using graphical tc~chniqucs. Our conclusions will 1)~ corroborated below wit,h mor(~ rigoroIls c~~)r~ornc~tric techniques. WV bc,gin with the assumption (I=. 1. Figures 6 and 7 cant aiu a wealth of descriptive information about the relationship bet,weerl t hc r~sctlangc~ rat<, (c ) and fundamentals (f). ‘l’hc~ figures contain fourk[i “slilall Ilirllt,ipk” c : j scatter-plots; one for each of the thirteen

EMS regimes.

alltl anotllcr

covering

the whole sample

from 1979

through 1990. Tl 1c USC of slnall multiple graphs allows the data. to be conipared easily across rcginles a.nd count,ries. I:or the sake of brevity, only data for the Netherlands (a rcalati\-4y credible participant in the ERM) and Italy (a relatively participants

incredible co111ltr>.) arc usctl: comparable are availa.blr in t tie working pa.l)er.

In any given

scatter-plot

. each of t tie individual

figures

for other

point,s represent,s

ERM a single

daily observation. To guide t 1lc cyc ill connecting t,he dots of the joint t,ribution, a nonparanlctric “data snloot.tltxr” is drawn as a solid line.“4 32We temporally t,o correspond 33Quarterly 3”The five) and

average fundanwnt.als (instead I hat illdust rial protluct,ion

Lo t.hr way

in the cases

smoother calculates

divides

of Bclgiaul thv

alltl

horizotlt.al

(.liv ci-osc;-l)kdiall

of

of sctcctivrly

sampling

disWC

fundamentals)

is nleasurvd.

Francc~. axis

int,o a number

of bands

f iilld f wit tlill racll band.

The

(we genrLrally

use

cross-mrdinns

arc

29

use the shapes

of these

smoothers

extensively

in our search

for nonlinear

re-

lationships between e and j The smoother can easily handle the nonlinear patterns implied by the target-zone theories above; conversely, the absence of sensible nonlinear smoother that the theories work poorly. The marginal each observation

patterns

suggests

(though

density for e is displayed to the right is represented with a single tick mark.

right of the marginal

density,

a box-and-whiskers

it does not prove) of the scatter-plot; Immediately to the

plot of the marginal

density

is also displayed. The line in the middle of the box marks the median of the marginal distribution; the box covers the interquartile range (i.e., from the 25th percentile range to the 75th percentile range). The whiskers extend p oints beyond to upper- and lower-“adjacent values”; adjacent values are usually considered outliers. 35 A comparable marginal density and box plot for fis graphed above the diagram. This combination of graphs allows one to evaluate the marginal and joint distributions simultaneously. Target-zone theories place a number of restrictions on the marginal distributions of e and f, as discussed above. For instance, the simple model of Krugman (1990) im ’ pl ies that, (with perfect credibility and infinitesimal interventions on the bands), the exchange rate is expected asymptotically to have a bimodal symmetric density which would be directly apparent in the marginal distribution, and manifest in the box-plot as a relatively wide symmetric interquartile range with sma.11 whiskers. The model of Bertola and Caballero (1990b) d e 1’ivers a very different set of restrictions. In addition, some theories (e.g., Bertola and Caballero (1990a)) present restrictions on the relationship entire sample.

between

e a.nd f across

regimes;

hence

the

scatters

for the

The (implied) EMS exchange-rate bands are drawn as horizontal lines in the figures, so that the vertical dimension of the Dutch graphs represents +/-2.25%, those of the Italian graphs +/-6% (until January 1990). Consider the top left graph in Figure 7, describing tween e and f for Italy during the first EMS regime,

the relationship which prevailed

befrom

March 13, 1979 through September 23, 1979. The data are grouped in the upper portion of the graph, indicating that the Lira was relatively strong during this period; the box-plot for e indicates that the median value of the exchange liers. The apparently

rate is moderately

high in the band,

and there

fundamentals are approximately symmetrically normal distribution. The relationship between

are no negative

out-

distributed in an e and fappears to

then connected with cubic splines. Meese and Rose (1991) use a different nonparametric smoothing technique (locally weighted regression) and arrive at results consistent with ours. See also Diebold and Nason (1990) and Meese and Rose (1990). 35Adjacent values are defined as 150% of the interquartile range rolled back to the nearest data point,. 31

he monotonic,

positive,

and liliear.

No simple general charact,trization can be made about However, a number of features do seem apparent. ships. importantly, remarkably few nonlinearities which are typica.lly vicwcd as being nlore the Dutch Guilder) Third, nonlinearities than

more

are apparent,. Second, currencies committed to the ERM (such a,s

have fewer (not more) appear t,o be growing

important;

t,he absence

the e : f relationFirst, and most

manifestations Icss important

of nonlincarities

of nonlinea.rities. over time, rather

in the twelfth

regime

is

noticeable. However. incrcastxd credibility sltould be manifest in a relationship between the exchange rate and fundamcntjals that comes increasingly to become more unlikely.% resemble Krugman’s S-shape, a.s rea1ignment.s Fourth, while some nonlincarities are apparent,, they tend not to have shapes that are even vaguely similar to those implied by extant. t,heories. Countries that have cxperienc-et1 frqIlc,nt realignments (such as It,aly) do not appear

to liavc

iuvrrtrtl

S-shapf‘s.

as implied

by the

Bertola

and

Caballero

(199Ob)

model; crctlibl~~ count rics (such as the Nc1,herlands) do not have t.hat, arf’ apparent do not Krugman’s S-shape. ‘1‘hat, is. t11(’ ilonlincarities seem to have sensible idrnt,ifiabl(* pal.t urns across eitllcr time or count,ry. Fifth, much of thca flat a is clllst,ered iI1 11~~nliddle of t,he declared exchangerat,e bands, especially for Iat(,r r(xgillles. Assuming that. the act,ual exchangcrate bands coincide wit11 the dr,clared ba~~ds, nonlinearities a.re difficult to detect visually if t,hc c,xchangc ratf’ stays in the middle of the zone.3i This may indicate that, t,hc, aut Irorit ios defeIldcd implicit, bands well within t,he declared bands: in this case our t hc~oretZical ana.lysis applies for the a.ctual implicit bands. so long as the Inarkt,t recognized t,llis fact.“’ The fact t,hat, exchange rates spend n~ucll of (heir tinIf\ irt t,he interior of the band may

instead be a small saInpI(~ prol)l~~111. C:ivc,rl the sample sizes involved and t.hc nature of t,hc forcing process IIII~W that IIIIII hypot,hcsisl we are skeptical of t,his view; however, noIllin(~arities would IW milch more difficult to detect if exchange ra.tes happened to have avoided the periphery of the bands. the t : ,f relatiouship

Finally,

appears

to be approximat,ely

linear

over t,he

entire sample. consistcxnl wit.h t Ilrx ~nodel of Bcrtola and Caballero (199Oa). Figures 6 and T rely OII our assumpt iolr (1 = .l. (‘Iearly as N falls, the scatter-plots in these figures IIIOVVcloser towards an exact affine relationship between e and f; if (1 = 0, c = .f csactly. Figllres Al and A2 are the analogues to Figures 6 and 7, comput,r~tl \vitll (1 = I. ii valurx that, is implausibly large analysis of Fkrt.ola and (‘al)aIlt=ro ( 1990a.l)) implies

3”Thr earit.irs

should

he changit~g

370n the other

hand, the eschangc

target-zone, =This Edison bands.

is t.rue as long as and

(:racicla

over

t ilnc%fro~r~arr illvvrtcti

t,hat. the shape

S-shape

tIlta problt~~r~ is vsplicltlv a s~nall sample prohlpm. rate ~rlay sp~rrd most, of its t,ime near t,he bands.

the implicit.

Kaminskv

bands

arc’ currcnt,ly

arc constant twt.ing

of the nonlin-

to Krugman’s

(as the declared t.hr, hypothesis

S-shape. In a credible

bands

of constant,

are).

Hali

implicit

in our view. These figures indicate nonlinear effects of substantively greater importance, although it is a.gain difficult to detect patterns over time or country.

Again, the smoother

by extant

exchange-rate

Comparison

shapes bear little resemblance

to those implied

models.3g

with other

exchange-rate

regimes

While the scatter-plots of Figures 6 and 7 do not seem consistent with the implications of known nonlinear exchange-rate theories, we hasten to add that countries participating in the EMS do not look similar to countries in (relatively) free floats. Figure 8 is a graph (comparable in every way to Figures 6-7) for the British Pound Sterling, an exchange rate which was floating (relatively) freely against the DM: (comparable figures for the Japanese Yen, the American Dollar, and the Swiss Franc are similar and are available in the working paper). Figure 8 also has fourteen small graphs, one for each of the thirteen regimes, a.s well as one for the whole sample. While actions such as the Louvre Agreement lead one to doubt the assumption of perfectly free floating the e : f scatters look much more linear for non-ERM countries than they do for ERM countries.40 Our model predicts e = f for flexible exchange rates: manifestly this prediction is satisfied in spite of the assumptions used to build the model. This encouraging result bolsters our confidence in the empirical framework. The EMS can also be compared with other regimes of fixed exchange rates. Figure 9 provides graphs for the post-WWII Bretton Woods regime of pegged but adjustable rates (the data a.re drawn from the 1960s); Figure 10 provides comparable data for the pre-WWI and inter-war gold standards. Both figures use cy = .1.41 The relationship between the exchange rate and fundamentals seems to be decidedly more nonlinear for the gold standard than for the EMS; the dollar/yen rate also appears t,o be nonlinearly related to funda.mentals during the Bretton

Woods era.42 However, most of the Bretton

Woods data appear

consistent with linear e : f relationships, while the smoother shapes in the gold-standard data, are not implied by existing target-zone models.43 3gThe

working-paper

40Linearity was founded; 41Using

version

cont,ains

is also the hallmark further

a higher

detail value

is available

of a (say,

in the

1) changes

working the Bretton

Woods

higher values of alpha (e.g., 1) appear unreasonable Higher alpha values (say, .5) for the gold standard

43This

however,

may

shapes upper

be, in part,

are vaguely tails

appear

the result

and

reminiscent

33

base

graphs

are extremely

wiggly.

country. before

the ERM

considerably; Below,

the

we show

in a number of different data do not greatly change

of Krugman’s

to be essentially

of movement

as the

in t.he 1970s

paper.

that much dimensions.

tails;

sloped

Italy

float.ing

do not

lower

to be positively

with

currencies

smoothers

the graphs. 42The smoother

tend

analogues

of ERM

S-shape

for parts

of the

linear.

in t,he gold points.

These

are the exchange

35

Is there

a “honeymoon

effect”?

As discussed above, the thrust of the original target-zone proposal was to make the exchange rate less responsive to fluctuations in exchange-rate fundamentals,

the celebrated

“honeymoon

effect” of Krugman

(1990).

The the-

oretical framework of Section II implies that the e : f slope should be unity in a floating rate regime, lower in a credible target-zone. If the diminished impact of fundamentals on the exchange rate in a credible target zone is the “honeymoon effect ,” then the possibility that the impact might be magnified in an incredible target-zone (Bertola and Caballero (1990a,b)) might be the “divorce effect.” It should be remembered, however, that we are studying relationships; the start of a targetgovernment policies, not interpersonal zone is more likely, we think, to be characterized by low policy credibility than high policy credibility. Estimates of the slope t,hus provide a specification test of the target-zone model. Actual estimat,es of the slopes for all countries and EMS regimes are presented in Figure 11; we simply regress et on ft and an intercept; Newey-West covariance estimators are used. These specification test,s are independent of the theory results in Section II. Consistent with the honeymoon effect (and inconsistent with the work of Bertola and Caballero (1990b)), for cy = .l, the e : f slope is often less than unity for EMS countries, though rarely by a large margin. However, for any given country, our point estimates of the slope vary considerably over time, being greater than unit)y for around a. t,hird of the regimes considered; point estimates of small slopes also tend to be imprecise. Further, there are few identifiable patterns in the slope estimates. For instance, the unstable regimes of the early 19SOs are a.ssociated with small slopes, while the credible regimes of the late 1950s seem t,o have higher slopes. Also, slope estimates for countries a.s different as Italy and the Net.herlands do not appear to be very different.

It will be shown below that the nonlinear

rise to the honeymoon the data.44 to unity.45

effect in target-zone

linsurprisingly.

non-EMS

effects, which give

models, are not usually found in

countries

have e : f slopes very close

An errors-in-variables argument leads to the conclusion that a choice of (Y which is too high will lead to an e : f slope which is too low. Given our rates

at which

costs;

the gold

ing the gold further implicit

standard.

gains were

44Slopes

bands);

however.

from

market,

hlyers

analysis. Movements EMS exchange-rat,e

declared

important

if exchange

rates

physical forces

(1931).

transportation

which

Officer

limited and

(1986).

of gold fluctuations Spiller

the smoot,her

patterns

to t,he spread statistical and

problems

fundamrntals

are very

between afflict

transportation

and

Woods

similar bands

rates

(1988)

dur-

provide

to movements in which differ from

different.

maximal the

exceed

in exchange

in the gold points are conceptually bands (when the aut.horities defend

are also unrelated

45Potentially countries

arbitrage points

and standard

are nonstationary.

minimal errors

values for

of e. non-EMS

i” I

uncertainty about cy, we conduct sensitivity analysis. Figure 12 is comparable to Figure 11 but uses cr = 1 (the graphs with c~ = .05, for which there is essentially no evidence that the e : f slope strongly differs from unity, are in the working paper version).

For cr = 1, all point estimates

(across six ex-

change rates and thirteen EMS regimes) are less than unity, virtually always by statistically significant ma.rgins. Indeed, the e : f slopes are clustered closer to zero than to unity. We view this as another manifestation of our hypothesis

that unity is an excessively

high choice for CY.

Summary Some nonlinearities are apparent in the scatter-plots between the exchange rate and fundamentals; the e : f relationship tends to look much more linear for floating exchange rates than it does for fixed exchange rates. However, in a number of different dimensions, the nonlinearities do not seem to conform to the patterns implied by target-zone models. The few nonlinearities that exist do not appear as one might expect in more credible exchange rates (such as the Dutch Guilder), more recently (e.g., since 1987), or in the S-shapes implied by existing theories. Similarly, although there is modest evidence of a “honeymoon effect ,” the size of this effect does not vary in a sensible way across regimes; in any case, the existence of the effect depends strongly on c-y,and reasonable values of o are consistent with no honeymoon effect. Our relatively naive graphical approach has yielded, at best, weak supWe now attempt to clarify the issue by port for target-zone nonlinearities. applying more econometric firepower. VII.

Parametric

In this section, nificance significant

tests for nonlinear

we estimate

of nonlinear explanatory

terms.

target-zone

effects models

directly

and test

We find tha.t the nonlinear

power in sample.

terms

the sig-

often add

However, the finding of statistically

significant nonlinearities in-sample is too robust; it, occurs for both fixed and floating exchange ra.tes. Also, coefficient signs are not those predicted by target-zone models, and a number of other aspects of the model are rejected. The structural

model which we wish to estimate ft = 71+

is:

ft-1 + et

et = or/ + ft + Ale.v(b.ft)

+ &ev(Mt)

where we selectively sample et a.nd .ft daily. In our empirical with a slight extension of (16):

39

(14) (16) work, we work

where:

;I is the estimate

of 11 from equation

rate); i1 and i2 are the roots to equation in place of true 0 and 7; 6 is the estimated

(14)

(adjusted

to an a,nnual

(7) with estimates (T and 77 used standard error of the residual of

equation (14) (adjusted to annual rates); and Al and AZ are free parameters unconstrained by zone size or credibility assumptions. We estimate (17) with OLS, ignoring any biases in $ and 6 which may result from, e.g., small-sample bias, generated regressors, or misspecifications of (14). We maintain cr = .I for most of the analysis which follows. We allow for two potential

misspecifications

of the model by including O0

and 0,; a finding either of 00 # 0 or 03 # 0 is an indication of mcdel misspecification (multicollinearity considerations often preclude free estimation of 0,). An error term ha,s also been added to the equation; Froot and Obstfeld (1989b) suggest that this can be interpreted in a domestic context as a result of time-varying income tax rates that are conditionally independent of ft. We also examine thr> serial correla,tion properties of this disturbance below. Since there a.re cross-equatiou restrict.ions, estimation of these equations should be conducted jointly; for convenience, we pursue two-step estimation below.““>“7 Thus, we estimate (13) with OLS; consistent estimates of 77 and u are obtained from the intercept a.nd standard error of the residual, respectively. These estimat,es are t,hen used t,o estimate X, and X2; (17) can then be estimated directly with OLS. ~1~ and A2 can he consistently estimated by O1 and 0,; from the latter. t.he exchange r&e bands, eL and eU can be estimated. In practice, we test the hypothesis O1 = O2 = 0(<= Al = A2 = 0). Two problems affect this work iu pract.ice. First, our regressors are exponential funct,ions, which can lead to computa.tional complexities. Such problems can be avoidetl by a.ppropriate resealing of the data. Second, there is often severe multicollinea.rity between the regressors of (17), making tests of individual coefficients unreliable. For this reason, tests of the joint hypothesis 01 = O2 = 0 are tabulated in Table estimated signs of the 0 coefficicnk. As shown and A2 are of opposite sign in most theoretical

1. Table in the

1 also presents

theoretical

target-zone

section,

the

Al

models.48

46Simultaneous estimation is complicat,rd by two facts: (1) the well-known leptokurtosis in exchange rates is manifest in gross violations of normality of t,he shocks to t,he fundamentals equation (14); and (2) choice, rather than estimation , of (Y precludes serious statistical work, unless one is willing t,o guess t,he covariances of CI with other parameters. IV estimat,ion using Durbitl’s ranked instrumental variables does not change results; Bartlett’s variant of Wald’s indicat,or iustrrrnlental variables leads to enormously higher standard errors. 47Equations for individual bilateral exchange rates can also be estimated jointly with Zellner’s seemingly unrelated tecllnique for greatrr &iciency. 4”Froot and Obstfeld (1989b). 5Ilow that 0, and 02 arr well-behaved with the additional assumptions of normality of U’~and independence of ct Froot and Obstfeld (1989b) provide further analysis. 11

Tahlc Hypothesis

Tests

Joint Hypothesis

1:

for Nonlinear

Terms,

cu=.l

Tests for Nonlinear

Terms

Relg.

Den.

France

Ireland

Italy

Beth.

.oo

n/a

.oo

n/a

.oo

.oo

11/a.

2

.oo

n/a

.OO

II/11

.oo

.oo

n/a

3

.oo

H/ii

.oo

11/a

.oo

.oo

n/a

4

.oo

n/a.

.oo

u/a.

.oo

76

n/a

5

.oo

n/a

.oo

n/a

.OO

100

n/a

6

.oo

.oo

.uo

.OS

.oo

.oo

.oo

7

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

8

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

9

.oo

.oo

.oo

.OO

.Ol

.oo

.oo

R.egime

.Japan

UIi

10

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.OO

.oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

I1

.oo .oo .oo

.oo

.oo

.UCl

.OO

.oo

.oo

.oo

1

12 I :1 Entries 711~.

arc-

Regime

ant1

used,

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.oo

.OO

.oo

.I)0

.oo

.OO

.oo

.oo

.OO

significanw

o = .I:

~cgililr,-sI)c,cillc..

CJ~ and r/ (ar~tl thucforr .Yc>wc-v-\Ymt,

= O2 = 0 + O,f,

+

X2) arc

wtirnat,ors

Neth.

.la~pan

ITli

+~

II/11

t-

-+

Illa

+-

-t

II/d

-t

-+

n/a

+-

II/;1

-t

it

II/A

Il/il

-+

+-

Ii/i1

t-t -+

-4

II/i, St

-t

St

1.

t +-

+-+

0,

X1 and

cova.riance

Signs of 0, and 0, l;‘laII(‘(‘ Irc~lar~tl Italy

-+

-+

icst

+ 02wp(X21;)

wit.11 six lags.

Belg.

++

Icvcl for joint

(‘I - ,f; - (II/ = 0,t.r/1(A,.f;)

+t 2 :1

.OO

.oo

Throughout~,

count,ry-

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

arc marginal

in regressiorl

USA

-+ t+i

++-+ +t-+

+-

++ +-

-+

-+

-t +

++

-+

-+

-t

+-

++

+t+

t -t -+

n/a n/a

-+

t-

IlS,Z ++ -+ t-+ -t -+ -t-

-t

++

-+

-+

~+

4

-+ -+ -+

m+

-t

tt -+

Q-Tests

for Residual

Serial Correlation

Regime

Belg.

Den.

France

Ireland

Italy

Neth.

Japan

UK

USA

1 2 3

.oo .27 .oo

n/a n/a n/a

.oo .oo .oo

n/a n/a n/a

.oo .02

n/a

.oo .Ol .oo

4 5

.oo .oo

.oo .23

n/a

.oo .oo .oo .oo

6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

n/a n/a .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .17

.oo .99 .oo .oo

n/a .oo .oo .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

.oo .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

n/a n/a n/a n/a .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

Entries are ma.rginal significance levels for serial correlation of wt from regression et - ft - cq = O1 exp( X,f,) + &excp( X,f,) + 03ft + Wt,ff = .l.

T-Tests Regime

Belg.

1

.97

2 3

.oo .Ol

4

.Ol

5 6

.60 .oo

7 8

.oo .oo

9 10 11 12 13

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo

Den.

of O3 = 0

France

Ireland

Italy

Neth.

n/a da n/a n/a da

.28

n/a

.05

.13 .42 .Ol

n/a n/a n/a n/a

.54 .ll .oo .29

.oo

.33 .04

.25 .oo .oo

.oo .oo .oo

.25 .oo .oo .36

.oo .oo .oo .29

.05 .oo

.oo .52 .oo .35 .Ol .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .oo .93 .oo .oo

.06 .04 .52 .22 .98 .17 .83 .oo .20 .45 .oo .93

Japan

n/a n/a n/a da n/a .oo .03 .24

.oo .oo .oo .57 .oo

UK

USA

.oo .31 .48 .oo

.oo .oo .oo .oo

.oo .oo

.oo .oo .09 .64

.25 .08 .03 .oo .oo .97 .53

Entries are marginal significance level of t-statistics of hypothesis 03 = 0 in regression et - ft - cyq = Olezp(X1ft) + &esp(Xzf,) + @,f,

+ UJt.

.oo .oo .oo .96 .oo

1 also prr3rilts

‘I’able

two spC,cificat ioir tests

(the

restrict,iou

OO = 0 was

rq~~rt~c~l in ‘Tahlr, I ). First, the marginal O-test, to txaminc t,he serial correlation

imposed for the analysis level from a standard

significance properties

of t,he residual from ( 17) is ta hulat~cd; a low number indicates statistically significant a.utocorrc~latiorl. S~ond, the nlargirial significance level of a t-test of the hypothesis (3, = O is also prvscnt 4. also another indicat ioll of IIIO~CI failllrf‘. The

result,s

is almost

I illdicatc

of l’ablc

that

R
t JIG joint

of t,his hypot.hclsis

hypothesis

O1 = 0,

is

= 0

alwa.ys

reject rd a.t conventional significance levels. This result, is quite strong; rejections occur for n~ost c-orlnt ries and most EMS regimes. The existence of nonlinearit ivs of t,hv type implkl by targbzonc models seems, at, first blush. to hf% ov~rwllrlrrli~lg~~ sllpported. WC have also cxaminrd a numbfar of pf73urhat~ions of 1hc ha.sic rfpssion framework including: set ting o = I: and a lil~~t-cliff’c~l.c~l~c.c~cI v(‘rsioll of the test. Neither perturbation changes t,lie basic i~slili~ of l‘al)lf~ I .l‘hc rcjcction of 0, = (!I2 = 0 is also t 0: 1iw ol‘ 0 = .O.T:(.11oicf\ of :I(Ltla!, (as opposed t 0 ‘L-day int crf3t rates); the f>xact sailil)lr~ ~~riotl (\vv t ricd c>scluding hot 11 (a) 011ly ttic day antI (I)) t lie wliok niont Ir 1~(~1;1rvarrtl al’1 (‘I’ imlipniiif~ilt s); aild day-of-t hc-wcf,k f+ fects (wfx cstimatcY1 ( IT) for ))ot II ICriclaJ2i antI non-Fritlays, wpara,tcly). This wjf~rt~ion also diarac_tf~ri/,c3 a11 1II<>cilrrfwcif~s in t,llf, l3rd ton \Voods and golfl-

insf7isil.iw

st.alldard

rcgiilws

sl.rongly sampI

wjfdf~tl: nonliiif3rii

of tisc~l

ratc5.

l‘lrc IIypot Jichis

\vf’ (~oli(~lu~lt~ 1 jl;rt 1Ircx finfliiig iw

it) t II<, c.oticlit iolial

iiic’iiils

C-1, =

(32 =

of st atist,ically

of c~sf.haligc~

0 is risiiall> signifif-arlt

rak

iii-

is clilitf’

roblIst. I’hc signs iii t Ilf, thcorfd targf+milc~

time,

of Gl ailcl (3L a13~ also tabrllntccl in Tahlf~ I. As dcinonstratcd ical swt ioil. t lir~- i~rf‘ f5pf‘f.t ml t 0 hc of oppositf’ sign ill most nmdf~1s (I)ot II cwflil)lf~ aritl iircrfdihlf~). ~Irotinfl a t,hirfl of t Ilc,

1hc signs

01’ hl

alr(l

(I)2 c~c~~~f~sponfl t 0 t,llosf> irriplicd

by targf+zoue

rnoclds.

IIowcvf~r. t hft st.iLt ist ical ~irotld (low llot wit.llst alltl flirt.hcr strut iny. ‘l’hfmt is st roilg cvidciicf~ of sf>vf7~‘ rf5itlllal alltf,c-ol.rclatic,ri (Ncwey-West covariancc cst,imat~ors lla\.f> LWII IIS~YI, I)(T~IIs~~ ot’ t llis a~lt~oc.orrf~lat.ion, rcsitlual ,IRCH is also apparent ). Only ill ;I f’t~w c‘ases cari oilf~ re.j_jcl the null hypotjlicsis of 110 a~lt~of~orrelat ion. t“rlrt lwri~iow. t Iif> 1110df~l sfmns to I,f% inisspccified in that, O. is oftc,ii sigliificant,lv diti’cv~ilt 1’ro111 zero. .Igaiil, tlif3c results arc rf>latiwly robust.. hlost import alit I>.. t hexIl!.l)ot Irf3is C-11 = O2 = 0 is uslrally rf~jcctfd for float.ing f~xcliarrgf~ ratfts 2s ~(~11 as fisf~l f~x(.llailgf~ rates, as is apparerlt froni ‘I’aI)lc, 1. ‘l’his iliflicatc5 t Irat OIII’ iloiilitlc~ar lcrms r~iiiy 11fx I)ic.king rip somf~ gcllf+c niissl)facificat ioli iii 0111‘ im~lf~l that is not part icrilar to tarp-zone rcgirilf~s. II

Summary Parametric

tests

for nonlinearities

one hand, nonlinearities

leave us with a mixed verdict.

of the type implied by target-zone

On the

models seem to

be statistically significant in-sample. The hypothesis that nonlinearities do not exist in conditional means of exchange rates can easily be rejected in a robust fashion. However, these nonlinearities arise in a model which is usually rejected on other statistical criteria. In any case, the economic meaning of these terms is far from clear. Although the signs of the coefficients correspond to target-zone nonlinearities, the fact that these nonlinear terms are often significant during regimes of floating rates seems to bolster the notion that the nonlinear terms do not represent t,arget-zone effects. To study this issue further, we now turn to a forecasting methodology. VIII.

Forecasting

with

linear

and

nonlinear

models

In this section of the paper, we compare the forecasting ability of linear exchange-rate models with models that have additional nonlinear terms implied by the target-zone litera.ture. We find that the presence of additional nonlinear terms does not produce better “ex post” forecasts than those of linear models. This result, combined with the in-sample analysis of the previous section mirrors the results of Diebold and Nason (1990). Our baseline forecasting experiment proceeds as follows. Consider a given country (say, Belgium) and a given EMS regime (say, the period before the first realignment, from March 1979 through September 1979). Using the first thirty observations, we estimate the drift term for fundamentals by regressing the first-difference of exchange-rate fundamentals on a constant. This provides us with estimates of g2 and 7. Given these estimates and our choice of cr, we can solve for i1 and i2; hence, we can generate the two nonlinear terms, e.r~(i1.f~) and esp(X2fi). A We then run two regressions: (1) (the linear model)

et = 7r7)+ 7rIft + 21:; and (2) (the non-linear model) e, = & + $lft + 42e~p(ilft) + &erp(i2ft) + ~1”“. We then generate forecast errors by substituting in the actual future values of the regressors to generate

a forecast;_ thus, the one-step

nonlinear

forecast

error is given by

%“” =: et+1 - [do + $lft+l + &e3-p(ilft+l) + dw~p(hft+~)l. We then add an observation to the initial set of (30) o b servations and repeat the procedure until we arrive at the week before the next EMS realignment. The functional form of our forecasting equakion is suggested by equation (6), but we allow Al and A2 to be time dependent free parameters, unconstrained (as always) by assumptions about zone size or credibility. The square roots of the mean squared forecast errors (RMSEs) from linear and nonlinear models (computed with cy = .l) are presented in a graphical format in Figure 13; this portrays the ratio of the linear to nonlinear RMSE

for the

six different

is little

evidence

EMS

or floating

RMSEs

countries

that

currencies.

are typically

and

nonlinear

thirteen

models

different

EMS

regimes.

There

for either t,he ratios of linear to nonlinear

provide

In particular,

superior

forecasts

around one; there is no evidence that they tend to vary

systematically over time. or that they tend t,o be larger for countries with credible reputations like the Netherlands. We have checked the sensitivit,y of these results extensively. Figure 14 is the analogue

to Figure

13 but with 0 set. t,o unity.4g

A number

of other

perturbations are contained in t,he working-paper version, including: analysis of mean avera.ge errors; rolling regression techniques; the imposition of r1 = & = 1; 20-step ahead forecasts. The finding that linear models seem to forecast EMS exchange rat.es as well a.s nonlinear models appears t,o be robust to our sensit.ivit,v chccks.SO~s’

Summary It is well-known that sophisticated exchange-rate models that appear to be satisfactory on the ba.sis of in-sample criteria often do not forecast out-ofsample data better than extremely naive alternati.ves.52 In this section, we have shown that non1inea.r models do not forecast bet,ter than simpler, linear models; this finding appea.rs to be robust. We have used three different techniques to examine the nature of the relationship between exchange rat,es and fundamentals; none has yielded compelling evidence of nonlinearity, at least of the sort implied by target-zone models. There arc three pot,ential reasons for this finding: (1) mismeasurement of cr; (2) violations of uncovered interest, parity; or (3) an invalid theoretical model. Two argumeIlt,s discredit, the first explanation: low point 4gChoosing mate

(Y to maximize

“Linear

and

nonlinear

Woods

data.

around

20% smaller

the %

For

“‘One can estimated

NL

the forecast.

error

ratios

represenk

yet another

way

RMSEs

the

t.o cst,i-

n.

1 VZ,f

iidN(0, $J(T -

produce

t,han

linear

=

l8.l

+

11;““.

a test

2).5/(

1 -

Assuming

of the

$2)

between

the

RMSE

“Meese forecast extend

and better

this

equal

nonlinear

models

produce

null

s where

~1 and

for

Bretton

RMSEs

that

are

models

t,hat

E( ~1, ~2) = 0 and

hypothesis 7’ is the

~12. Under

as Student’s t with T - 2 degrees null hypothesis of equal variances from

approximately

data,

rigorously t,est the hypot,hesis of equality of forecast linear and nonlinear forecast, errors U: and upL,

W),

correlation

models

t,he gold-standard

~111 = ~22 number

can

There

of errors

and

Such

this

standard

are also many

the

vector

be computed

the null hypothesis,

of freedom.

that

error variances. Denotc and define I)~,~ = u,” -

4) is the test tests

reject.ions,

(u;“, u;““)

from

estimated

statistic often

t(T

is

- 2) = sample

is distributed

do not

a$ might

reject

the

be expected

bar-chart,s. Rogoff than

finding

(1983)

a random

showed walk;

t,o nonparametric

t,hat, linear Diebold

and

t.erhniqurs.

structural Nason

(1990)

exchange-rate and

Meese

models and

Rose

do not (1991)

1.04762

6

8

10

12

Japan Comparisons

2

4

4

5 6

6

UK

5

6

7

7

8

8

8

9

9

10

10

10

11

11

12

12

12

13

13

6

4

5

6

7

2

4

5

USA

3

I arat

6

7

Netherlands

2

1 hrat

4

France

2

1 frat

by EMS Regime: Alpha=.1

3

4

Italy

3

I brat

2

2

Denmark

1 drat

Figure 13: Forecast Comparison of Target Zone Models

RMSE

01 Dniii 3 5 7 9 1113 2 4 6 8 10 12

I Jrat

Ireland

1 erat

Ratlo of Linear to Non-linear RMSEs from l-step ahead Forecasts Horizontal Line marks equality of linear and no+llnear RMSEs

8

8

8

9

9

10

10

10

11

11

12

12

12

13

13

?atlo ,+I 3r ;

ni L-lrear

1

2

Japan

4

6

Ireland :Pdt

1 rrat

873 !1 t 3 1 L 1 P e I erat

tc Non

8

8

Figure

10

10

,Ta r r\ s

14: Fortcast

12

12

Comparison

Italy

1 lrat

;&lark:

I firat

6

10

12

1 hrat

6

Netherlands

1 ; Cl?.7 “1

4

France

2

I frat

Forecasts 4MSEs

of Target Zone Models

8

ilnear HMSEs frorr l-steD ahead ?q,all:!: c+ jlnear- and no?-:;rear

8

10

12

estimates

of (Y (lower (Y estimates

lead to more linear relationships);

fact that many of our results are insensitive

and the

to choice of cr. The short time

horizon leads us to believe that any risk premium

(which would violate

un-

covered interest parity) would be too small t,o account for our results. We are, therefore, attracted to the conclusion that the theory is not useful in modelling the data. Nevertheless, to confirm our doubts we now use techniques that do not rely on our mea.sure of exchange-rate fundamentals.

IX.

Other

implications

of target-zone

models

The empirical work that we have pursued so far has depended on our measure of exchange-rate fundamentals. If this measure is flawed, our empirical work will also be faulty. For this reason, we now turn to tests of target-zones that do not depend on fundamentals. Target-zone models have a variety of implications that can be examined without a measured exchange-rate fundamental (Bertola and Caballero and Smith and Spencer (1990)), given a (1990b), Svensson (1990a,b,c,d), For instance, as noted in Section II, the specific process for interventions. interest differential in a credible target-zone is expected to be declining in the deviation of the exchange rate from its central parity; the exchange rate should spend most of its time near the boundaries; and exchange-rate volatility should be greatest in the middle of the band. In this section, we examine some of these other aspects of the data. Some of these implications are dependent on specific assumptions concerning the nature of the intervention Any test of these implications would also test these tenuous asprocess. sumptions. Therefore, we simply present the data and supply some guidance as to the predictions of various t,heories.

Exchange-rate

vola,tility

by band position

Figures 15 and 16 are scatter-plots of the absolute value of the daily change in the exchange rate a,gainst the deviation of the exchange rate from its central parity (in percentage

points).

For brevity, we continue

to present results for

Italy and the Netherlands only. The upper and lower exchange-rate bands are marked by vertical lines (at +/-2.25%); a nonparametric smoother is also provided. The graphs are intended to convey a sense of the relationship between the volatility of the exchange rate and its position inside the band. It is not easy to find a clear pattern in the smoothers, either by country or by EMS regime (credible or not). The relationship is occasionally U-shaped (as suggested by Bertola and Caballero (1990b)), but the smoother is just as likely to have an invert.ed Ushape (as implied by Krugman’s (1990) model). 49

Monotonic

or flat smoothers

The evidence of the EMS;

from other

results

Interest-rate Figures

rate

17 and

II, models

should

(1990)),

and Caballero no clear

Woods

exchange-rat,t,

Figures

much

norm

modality).

Despite

paper

Another

hold closely expected

54Svensson

(1900d)

different.ials

data,

we find

imply

interest-rate

also

is also

in Section

that

there

presented derives

widespread

56Algebraically, uncovered where: Etet+r_ is the exchange il(i;)

is the

away

any

return

risk

peaks

rates

appears

indicate

EMS

bi-

credibility.

of the histograms are again

in

conclusions.

credibility in Svensson

point

should

(1990a))

to derive

to graph

the tirne-

to testming the entire

term

we use 2-day

bet,ween

of excess

proposed

(which

parametric

model

11.

for the When

position

has been parity

test. is simply

is little

implications

evidence

interest

as shown

of differences

the

slopes

and

structure

of interest,-

30.day

interest,

of various

rate

maturities

of

smoot,hers. Ieptokurtosis,

although

the

model

pre-

the 0pposit.e int,erest, parity implies rate which is expected

on a domestic

premium,

The

differential:

and gold standard

in Section

target-zone.

pat,tern

II implies

Single

exchange of increasing

Woods

Svrnsson’s

different,ial/exchange-rate

55There

are again

data.54

paper.

in the pattern

uses llncovered

rates.“’

for a credible no clear

percept.ion

target.-zone

exchange

heteroskedasticity

rate

rates.

EMS

of a change

Svensson

negative result,s

53The

of conditional

there

in the

(e.g.,

of Bertola

test>’

in a credible

future

of excha.nge

“tc>st” of t.argc+zone

(199013).

However,

in i.he working

for ot,her

for t,hc Dretton

(nonstatistical)

by Svensson

function

the model

to the interest,-ra,te

and do not I~ad to diffrrent

“simplewt

Svenssonb

slope.

parity.

the interest-

by bnnd position

result,s

indications

over time . ” . Figures the working

arc again

the widespread

we also see no clear

declining rate:

of randomness)

ana.loglles

histograms

(t.hough

to that

interest-rate

imply that

deterministic

opposite

distributions

of 2-day

t,arget-zones

evidence

graphs

19 and 20 provide

to be the

sented

irn 1I I ies the

position

is similar

rate from its central

the exchange

and goltl-st,antla.rd

Exchange-mte

scatter-plot,s

of credible

a g ainst

graphed (and

rates

version.

of the exchange

be a nonlinear

(199Ob)

patterns

Bretton

comparable

the deviat.ion

in Section

differential

of fixed exchange

the figures.“”

by band position

18 provide

against

Krugman

regimes

throughout

are in the working-paper

differential

differentials As noted

arc also apparent

possibly

Elei+k at time

(foreign)

bond

with

a ttllbious

claim

at

.iO

T days

= et[(l + it)/(l + i;)]trls6”) t to prevail at time t+lc; and to mat,urity.

1his horizon.

This

assumes

-ID

c 0 A-

rc

51

series of expected exchange-rate

future exchange

rates and see whether they lie within the

bands.

Figure 21 provides time-series plots of the exchange rates expected as of time t to prevail one year in the future. Exchange-rate bands are also presented. With the exception of the Dutch exchange rate, exchange rates expected

to prevail in a year are often outside the bands for prolonged periods

of time,

even for the more recent:

further

inconsistency

credible

twelfth

between the predictions

EMS

regime.

of credible

This is a

target-zone

models

and the EMS data.

Summary Target-zone models have a number of implications that can be examined empirically without relying on a measure of exchange-rate fundamentals. In this section, we examined: int,erest-rate differentials; exchange-rate volatility; exchange-rate distributions; and expected future exchange rates. These auxiliary (albeit informal) t.est.s provide no support for models of credible target-zones and only weak support for models with rea.lignments such as Bertola and Caballero ( 1990h).5’ 37We data

have

conducted

we found

12 (using

that

data

across

the corresponding principle J

EMS

ratio

starting 1. These

regimes

model

replication,

point. of these

Our

and

without

the

olphcr

results

carried

our

values

between

to 12. and

were

generated

.1 and

out

for two

wit,lr and

without.

using

was

long

then

and

daily

generated

from

at a random

of (Y: .I and

which

added

set

the reflection

begins

values

beliefs, noise

actual

to c was around

1). We, therefore,

fdata

data

of invest,igat,or

Using

values

generated

exchange-rate

a grid

result,s.

fundamental

set is 200 observations

we investigat,ecl were

to check

of possible

drift;

data

simulat,ion

sett,ings,

simulations

experiments

of t,he range

in the simulat,ions

in a credible

In a typical

both

simulation

the ratio

range

1. For

from

to the true

.l to

exchange

rate. Regardless that

of the match

instrumental

differentials mates

and

cantly”

less

change

than

unity.

in the

“significant“ ratr

and

rates

(t,he linear

regressions

WC always for the

deviation

replicat.ions

per simulation.

of the mean

value

found opposit,e

generating coefficient

to thr

across 500 replications is grratcr than 2. Without added noise, the forecast.ing exercise vantage 1000.

to the Ratios

fundamental

nonlinear remained

innovations.

model. greater

Ratios than

one

However, disappear

st.andard

always

such

as those

llntil

the

had adding

(the

deviation

of that

to the ex-

was set equal

are based on 500 value of the ratio of such

indicated

a huge 20 were

in the

the

“signifi-

constants

noise

noise

esti-

that

coefficient,s

in Table

volatility

small

found

of the

(15))

interest

: f slope

an e

estimation

(equat,ion signs.

We also

deliver

found

lagged

in numerically

of zero. the

using

f). These in-sample results we mean that the absolute

By %ignificant”

of an est,imated

that rate

a, we always

text

resulted

errors

of t,hese coc‘flicients

to t,he noise

in the

of c on f)

exchange

of the appropriate

the significance

the investigator’s

as instruments,

t,wo standard

Also.

in standard

n and

of n, as proposed

well within

expression

makes

the true

estimation

exchange

were

regressions

integration were

lagged

of cy which

honeymoon

I)ct.ween

variable

noise

coefficient,s

forecasting never was

ad-

less than that

of the

I

_

h

55

-2 N

cc 0

-

I

L

co

X.

Summary

and

Using uncovered

conclusion

interest

parity in a framework

that implicitly

depends on a

flexible-price exchange-rate model, we derived a measure of exchange-rate With the aid of this measure of fundamentals, we tested fundamentals. target-zone models of exchange-rate behavior in a number of ways. Graphical examination of the relationship between exchange-rate levels and fundamentals did not yield strong evidence of economically meaningful and important nonlinearities, certainly not those implied by existing target-zone models. There is little clear evidence of an important “honeymoon effect.” Explicit in-sample parametric tests of the nonlinear terms implied by targetzone models yield the conclusion that nonlinearities are usually statistically significant; however, a number of aspects of these models work poorly inMore importantly, linear sample on both economic and statistical grounds. models forecast out-of-sample data just as well as models with additional non-linear terms. Finally, a number of additional implications of targetzone models that do not depend on our measure of fundamentals have been tested and found not t,o he in accord with the data. For instance, there does not appear to be any particular relationship between exchange-rate and interest-rate volatility, and expected future exchange rates often fall outside the EMS bands. Moreover, few of the relationships between the exchange rate and (a) interest-rate different,ials, (b) exchange-rate volatility, and (c) Sucexchange-rate distributions seem to be in accord with existing theories. cinctly, we have been unable to provide a cha.racterization behavior during managed exchange-rate regimes.

of exchange-rate

We conclude that, at an empirical level, there is little advantage apparent in working with nonlinear, rather than linear, models of exchange-rate conditional mea.ns. This result is exactly analogous to the conclusions of Meese and Rose (1991) for flexible exchange-rate regimes. Our results also imply that there is little empirical support, for existing target-zone models of exchange rates. The models that we have dealt with in this paper have a number of restricFor instance, our model incorporates only a. single-state varitive features. able (thereby

ignoring st,icky prices and certain

Our simulations indicate unconditional

counterpart

that

the sample

types of devaluation

distribution

if 200 observations

of the exchange

rate

risk).58

resembles

its

are available.

‘“There is little reason to believe that either sticky prices or devaluation risk can easily reconcile target-zone models with the data. The lack of interest-rate differential variability for floating-rate shocks Further, and

from the

we find

countries goods Dutch it hard

implies

that

a model

with

markets;

however,

it is difficult

Guilder

has been

firmly

to believe

that

fixed

devaluation

sticky

to the

risk could

59

prices

to reconcile

this

must feature

Deutsche

Mark

account

for our

rely

heavily

with since

the early

negative

on data. 1983,

results.

We expect plaining

future

research

our negative

to identify

results.

the importance

of these

factors

in ex.

L.&e%

. “.,

i

t

ar

1 ar ,z!a

1

m

,I ar P

WQ

ar

ar

I



ar

61

“EL:. i

References Andrew, ton,

A.P.,

(1910).

Statistics

for the United States

186?‘-1909.

(Washing-

GPO).

Bertola, G. and Caballero, R., (1990a). Target-zone. Mimeo. Princeton University.

Reserves

Bertola, Mimeo.

Target-zones

G. and Princeton

Caballero, University

R.,

(1990b).

and

Realignments

and

in a

Realignments.

Bertola, G. and Svensson, L.E.O., (1990). Stochastic Devaluation Risk and the Empirical Fit of Target Zone Models. Mimeo. Stockholm University. Canzoneri, M.B. and Diba, B.T., (1990). ropean Community. Mimeo. Georgetown

Currency University.

Diebold, F.X., (1986). Rational Expectations, Models of the Exchange Rate, Proceedings Statistics Section of the American Statistical Diebold, diction?

R.P.

Journal

Random Walks, and Monetary of the Business and Economics Association, 101-106.

P.M., (1983).

and Hodrick,

Occasional

Foreign Exchange Risk University of Virginia.

A Model of Stochastic

R.J.,

Perspectives,

(1990).

On Testing

in a General

Process

Switch-

D. and Mathieson, D.J., Context of the Integration Paper

for Speculative

Bubbles,

(1989). The European of European Financial

Monetary Markets,

No. 66. R.H., (1989a). Exchange NBER WP 2835.

Froot,

M., (1989b).

K.A. and Obstfeld, NBER

Pre-

4: 85-101.

Froot, K.A. and Thaler, Stochastic Regime Shifts,

Prices,

Premium

Rate

51: 537-551.

of Economic

Folkerts-Landau, System in the IMF

On the Mimeo.

R.P. and Garber,

ing, Econometrica, Flood,

in the Eu-

Exchange F.X. and Nason, J.N., (1990). Non-parametric Journal of International Economics, 28: 315-332.

Engel, C., (1990). Equilibrium Model. Flood,

Substitution

WP

I n t rinsic

3091. 63

Rate

Bubbles:

Dynamics

under

The Case of Stock

Froot,

K.A.

and Obstfeld,

nal of Economic

Giavazzi,

Goldfeld, Friedman dam,

4:

F. and Giovannini,

(Cambridge,

A nomalies:

M., (1990).

Perspectives,

Exchange,

Jour-

Limiting

A., (1989).

Exchange

Rate Flexibility,

MIT). S.M. and Sichel, D.E., (1990). and F.H. Hahn eds.), Handbook

The

Demand

of Monetary

for Money, (B.M. (Amster-

Economics,

North-Holland).

Harrison, J.M., (1985). B rownian (New York, Springer-Verlag). Hodrick,

R.J.,

and Futures

Kemmerer, Money

E.W.,

(1910).

S easonal

of Economics,

Stochastic

Flow

on the Eficiency

Calculus,

of Forward

Harwood). in the Relative

(Washington,

T ar g e t- zones and Exchange forthcoming.

Lewis, K.K., (1990). 0 cca.sional Interventions Exchange Application, NBER WP 3398. Meese,

and

Variations

in the Un,ited States,

P., (1990).

Journal

Motion

(1987). The Empirical Evidence Foreign Exchange Markets, (Chur,

and Capital

Krugman,

Demand

for

GPO).

Rate

Quarterly

Dynamics,

to Target

Rates

with a Foreign

R.A. and Rogoff,

Seventies: 14:

Foreign

1799192.

I<., (19S3). Empirical Exchange Rate Models of the Economics, Fit Out of Sample ?, Journal of International

Do They

3-24.

Meese, R.A. and Rose, A.K., tial Exchange Rate Estima.tion,

N on 1inear,

(1990).

Am.erican

Meese, R.A. and Rose, A.K., (1991). Linearities in Models of Excha.nge Rate Studies, forthcoming. Myers,

M.G.,

Development,

National many

(1931). (New

Monetary and Fran.ce,

Th.e New

York,

Commission,

Review,

An Empirical Determination,

University (1910).

GPO). 64

Nonessen-

80-2:

Assessment Review

York Mon,ey Market,

Columbia

(Washington,

Nonparametric,

Economic

Volume

192-196. of Non-

of Economic

I: Origins

and

Press).

Statistics

for

Great

Britain,

Ger-

Officer, L.H., (1986). The Effi ciency of the Dollar-Sterling 1890-1908, jJourna1 of Political Economy, 94: 1038-1073. Pesenti, P., (1990). Yale University.

P er f orate

Perron,

T ren d s and

P., (1988).

ries, Journal

of Economic

a.nd Imperforate

R.andom

Dynamics

Pessach, S. and Razin, A., (1990). pirical Investigation, IMF Working Smith, Return

Exchange

Walks

Rate Bands.

in Macroeconomic

& Control, Targeting Paper.

Gold

12-2/S:

Spencer, Monetary

the Exchange

Switching

and the

Testing Mimeo.

in ModQueen’s

in the European

the Dollar-Sterling 96: 882-892.

Svensson, L., (1990a). Th e F oreign Exchange Risk Premium with Devaluation Risk. Mimeo. Stockholm University L., (1990b). University.

The Simplest

Svensson, Stockholm

L., (199Oc). University.

Svensson, L., (1990d). a Target-zone. Mimeo. Tufte,

E.R.,

Graphics

(1983).

Press).

Target-zones

The Term Stockholm

Test of Target-zone

and

Interest

Rate

Structure of Interest University.

The Visual Display

of Q uantitative

Se-

An Em-

(1990). Estimation and and Process Switching.

Spiller, P.T. and Wood, R.O., (19S8). Arbitrage during Gold Standard, 1899-1908, Journal of Political Economy,

Stockholm

Time

Rate:

Rate Dynamics M.G., (1990). N ominal Exchange System. Mimeo. International Monetary Fund.

Svensson,

Mimeo.

297-332.

G.W. and Smith, R.T., (1990). Stochastic process to Gold, 1925, Econ,omic Journal, 100: 164-175.

Smith, G.W. and Spencer? M.G., els of Exchange-R&e Target-zones University.

Standard,

in a Target-zone

Credibility.

Mimeo.

Variability.

Mimeo.

Rate

Differentials

Information,

in

(Cheshire,