Journal
of Pubhc Economics
Competitive economies Constrained
48 (1992)
361-375.
North-Holland
tax theory inefficiency
in open
and a Pigovian
remedy
R. Krelove*
Received February
19XY. revised version received hlarch
IYY I
In an economy wth multiple governments. each is constrained to raise revenue for public expenditures ustnp dastortwnary tares on a directly mobile tax base. A povcrnment is said to bc competitive if the IOLII CO~I of IIS decisions, including the excess hurden. is perceived to be mternalired. The competitive euullibrium allocations are not constrained eflicient in wncral: there is another ce~ ,;f dlxtortickry t;lnes and associated public expenditures for which alI individuals in the wrnomy are better OIT. II is shown that the source of the Llilure can be intcrpretcd as a m~s~np market. and the l’orm of the hesl decentralwcd remedy is derived.
1. Introduction In
this
paper
economics straincd t3xcs *
arc to
on
intcrtanporal firms
within
costs to
(and
bc
I invcstigatc linkd
raise
rcvcnuc
;I directly moclcl its
bcnclits) that
an economy
trade for
mohilc whcrc
borders.
intcrnalizcd.
conditions,
by
in public tax
govcrnmcnts
arc
taxes
is said
govcrnmcnts whcrc
employing
Specifically
including
compctitivc
goods,
cxpcnditurcs
base.
A govcrnmcnt
multiple
and
each jurisdiction
of its decisions. The
with
factors
net-of-tax
price
;I
simple by
if the total
the cxccss burden, rcquircs,
con-
cmploycd
to bc competitive
assumption
is
distortionary
I consider the capital
whose
each
is pcrccivcd among
tukcrs
for
other traded
C‘r~rrespo~nlo~~,~, IO: R. Krelove. Smlon Fraser University, Burnahy. I&C. VSA IS6. Canxlx *I am grateful to two anonymous referees , ~1s well as seminar participants ;II the University of Toronto and Quwn’s University at Kingston for helpful comments and suggestions. An e:Irlicr version ws presented ;II the North American Summer Meetings of the Econometrw Society and appeared as University of Toronto Discussion Pap no. 881X. Wildasin (IYXY) has independently investigated the Jcs~gn of mterventions in a related model; he amrlyses the ekes of 3 subsidy tu 13x rate incrs;tses (abstracting from the issue of tin;mcing the subsidy program). Such il subsidy is not the bcs~ intervention in the tarpang sense. The views in this paper are mine. They do not neccswrily reflect the ofliwl position\ of the Intsrncltwnal Monetary Fund. 0047 -2727,YZ SM.00
I’
IYYZ --lilscvier
Science Publishers I$.V. All rights reserved
commodities.’ In this context 1 mean to show two things. After the model and the equilibrium in section 2. I show first in section competitive
equilibria
counter-intuitive
are not constrained
ellicient
in general.’ This
describing 3 that the result
is
to some extent, since there is no obvious marginal incentive
problem. Analogizing to the fundamental theorem of welfare economics. the assumption that the burden of a tax, including the excess burden. is internalized
by a jurisdiction
taking
world
prices as fixed
appears to be
exactly what is needed to provide the correct marginal incentive to each government to make the appropriate second-best tradeoffs. This intuition breaks down. however, because governments’ decisions together affect world prices, and these prices, through alter the possibilities government
budgets.
their effect on private maximizing
for transferring Competitive
behavior.
resources between private budgets and communities
ignore
these
additional
transfer possibilities in their decisions. One way to intcrprct the failure is that traded goods prices do not provide :I sufficient competitive
set of signals to coordinate the decisions of independent govcrnmcnts. and the second thing I do is ask what would constitute ;I just-sufkicnt set of signals. This question is taken up in section 4. where it is shown that at ~1constrained eflkicnt allocntion :L tcrm cmcrgcs that
can
be intcrprctcd as the shadow value of (traded) capital ;IS tax base to
the economy.
is then argued that the best remedy that prcsorvcs the involves pricing govcrnmcnts net ‘consumption’ of the tas base. With lhis remedy thcrc arises ;I corrcspondcncc ~C~WL'CII antI not (ncccssarconipctitivc equilibria ;IIKI constrained cfkicnt :Illoc;itions. dc~cntrali/ation
It
of decisions
ily) with full efficiency: there remains the cfficicncy loss that is ;I consequence of the fact that revenue must be raised with distortionary
taxes. hvc been conccrncd with Many rcscarchcrs’ in local public finance characterizing oulc0nics in environments where jurisdictions tax mobile commodities. The prcscnt paper represents a11 improvement over these results clearly
in several respects. k’irst. the compctitivc case has not itlwitys been where distinguished from various noncompetitive environments
governments
have opportunities
to mulct
lhs
foreigner,
with the result
that
‘An alloca[ion arwciatcd with ;L WI of (di\rortion;lry) I:II ralrs is non constrainsd eflicien~ if thcrc cxisrs anolher WI of pax r;Iks and aswciakd ullocrwn under which all individuals arc hctrcr off. ‘For cxxmplc. Gordon ( 19X.1). 0a1cs and Schwab ( IYX)o. Srarrell (19X0). WildaGn (IYXY). Wilson ( IYM). and %drow and M~csAowsk~ ( I9Xb).
sources
of failure
common
in
leading
to
failure.5,b
an
been confounded.’
literature
obscure
incomplete
Third,
environments
2. The
have
the
the
understanding
problem
There
are
J
I~j(_u,j..~2j.,~j).
j.
Each
nature
assumptions
of
and
of interventions
the
problem,
extent
of
for
the
competitive
systematically.
are
1,
in
first
price of savings,
amount
kj in
marginal
product Assume
Communities good to
in
that
I in cxh producer
comtnunity
provide
Then
the consumer mcjhility produced
from
I and
function
xii.
or
lend
in community
l;(kj)
in
that
the
the
it
at
second
period.
and diminishing.
marginal
an
j borrow
product
an The
J’;
costless
mobility
the
of
capital
producer
price
and
of
of
the
the
private
lirm hohitvior in j is charoctsrizctl by the l,/;(k) --q/i!. cxh j. whcrc q, is the known, in j. I.ot n,(q,) = IllilXk (/i(k)
tlcnotc
-q,ki
in ,j. is ;I govcrnmcnt
public
good.
in period producer
price of capital
assumption. 1 when
labeled
utility
Then
there the
the
economy,
jrcro.
the
price of capital
can commit
community.
periods.
firms
,/‘;. is positive, and
NorIn;Ilix
value of prolit
community to
by
period.
pilraIllclriC
cxh
the
oj; for simplicity
intertemporal
consumption
output
approaches
period.
k 10 maririiix
rcvcnuc
for
denoted
link4
each
the
r. Private
j;(O) =0
input
choice of
the Inxsiniizcd
period
denoted
of capital.
;Irc
good and two
by
I to produce
also
Iarpc as the capital private
is one private
in
population,
in its arguments. The resident of j can either use his
the
period
communities)
has a fixed
representable
after-tax
each j.
(equivalently.
community
increasing
endowment
period
aspects
the
of the design
jurisdictions
indexed
Preferences
In
of
has not yet been addressed
assume II~= I. all j. There
good
simplifying
important
model and the competitive tas equilibrium
usually _. 7
Second,
some
It
that
I to ;I unit
price
Icvics
is ilSSllIllCd
in j is given
across
communities
If f, is the t:Ix rate, the community
the capital
input
of domestic
the private
consumplion
good
taxes
and
simplicity
tax, I,. on capital
of capital
is cclu;Ili/.cd
for
firms
raises
is k,. The
in period
uses
the
that
the
input
in the
by q, = r + tj.
as
because of the rcvcnuc public
r,k,
in
good
is
2 at a constant.
unit,
364
marginal
rate of transformation;
community
j’s
budget constraint
given by the inequality gjsr,kj+ ~~~ where T, is a lump-sum community j (which equals zero at the equilibrium). Each
community
is
assumed
to
be competitive.
in
is then
transfer
the sense that
perceives that the total costs and benefits of its decisions are internalized.
to it To
make this operational, I make three assumptions. First, each community takes the global consumer price of capital, r, as fixed. independent of its own actions. Thus elastic supply
the community believes that private firms face a perfectly of capital at the prevailing net-of-tax return. Second. the
community government is benevolent in this its objective is the maximization of the level of utility of its residents. Third, since it is supposed that the government takes account of the effect of its decisions on n,(.), it is assumed that this surplus accrues entirely to the domestic residents. There are several equivalent
institutional
structures
to rationalize
this
last
assumption;
for
example, it can be assumed that the domestic firms are owned internally. Equivalently. it can be assumed that there is some fixed factor in each community.
owned by the resident. that is the recipient of the surplus.’
Private consumer private consumption
behavior in j is dcscribcd by the choice of lcvcls of in the bud@ sot to maximize utility, given prices and
govcrnmcnt choices.’ Dcnotc the maximized
lcvcl of utility
by v,(I,.,~,: r. HI,);
that is. (ir,(.\.,,sL,,~,):r.~,
r~,(lj,g,;r,rti,)~rll;Ix
+.~,~r!‘j+rr,(r+f,)+ttl,).
(1)
I I.I 1 whcrc ni, rcprcscnts period-_7 lunlp-SUIII out
the analysis).
Let
period- I consumption function. With thcsc equilibrium
s,,(r,
incomc (which equals zero throughfunction for rcproscnt the demand Ict s,(.) -r’j-.\:,,( .) rcprcscnt j’s saving
.qi, I,, m,)
in j, and assumptions
wc arc
in
a position
Ik/i’riifioti.
A
rcprcscnling
cottfpditii~c
an allocation
C,SIj+Cjkj=Cj).‘j;
and, for each j, (b) (r,,,
dsfinc
the
rus c*c/lri/ihriirrtl (CTli) is a list (.u, j, x2, kj. s,), for the cconoiny, a list of capital tax rates (r,),,
and a price r, such that (a)
to
concept, called a campctitivc tax equilibrium.
.x2,) solves max,,~,x, ( ~c,(.u,,.u,;~,):r.u,+s~$r?.,+n,(r+r,)+rri~);
365
(c) (rj.gj) solves max t.p rj( t. g; r, mj) subject (i) gstkj+sj
to
and
(ii) kj solves max, (f,(k)-(r+t)ki. Capital market equilibrium is imposed implicitly through condition (a) of the definition. It is an implication of the conditions (b) and (c) that material balance in (produced) second-period consumption is satisfied. and so does not need to be entered explicitly. Note that each community takes r as parametric in its program given by condition (c).~ Consider the choice problem for some community j. Associate the multiplier ~~20 with constraint (i) above. Assuming enough differentiability and that the community’s conditions
problem is sufficiently
are given by the constraints
tj=$/‘;
well behaved, the first-order
and by”
( 1 “ri_i’j
,
i'j
whcrc urj rcprcscrits the maryinal utility of second-period consumption (irzj= I’,~ and tfUj= 11~~). The term i.J14~, is j’s pcrccivcd social marginal utility of govcrnmcnt rcvcnuc. norm:l~iizcd by the social marginal utility of private incomc. Obviously 7j/~~tjg I always at the CTE. From (3). ;),/u2,> I for positive tax rates. [Then from (2) the marginal rate of substitution bctwccn the public pooJ and period-2 consumption is greater than the marginal rate of tr;lnsk)rmatiorl (which cclu;~ls I).] A ncccssary and suflicicnt condition for ~hc constrained
incff&ncy
result
of the next section
is that
this
strict
incqu;tlity holds for some j at the CTE, i.c. that the pcrceivcd marginal dcadwcight loss of the capital tax, (yj- uzj)/uzj as usually dctincd, is positive. That this is ;I gcncral characteristic of the equilibrium follows from the rcstrictcd possibilities in the model for transferring resources bctwccn the private
budget constraint
and
the govsrnmcnt
bud@”
It
is assumed
“It is being assumrd that the community has good knowltxlg:e of prefercnccs to bc used for some decisions but not fur othrrs; in parlicular the knowledge of prcfcrenccs is nol used IO levy (oprimal) lump-sum I;WS. This is 3 standard assumption in optimal IU theory. often juslilicd by the clssumption rh;:! Ihe govcrnmcnt may hare god information concerning the distribution of IASICS and endowments but cannot dcnrify the characteristics of a particular individual’. “‘NOW that the j tirms’ upid demand function has slope tX,/Cr,= I//;. ’ 'l'osi~ivc public goods provision (positive 13x rates) will bc ;L characwristic of the CTII for il larpc SCI of prrferences. One contrary cast arise when period-2 consumption and the public good arc perfec! substiiutcs for all individu:lls [so utility in j is given by, say. u,( ‘) =h,( t,,J + rz, +,g,. with /I,(.) mucasing and coruve].
throughout
that a CTE
exists, that the equilibrium
ized by (2) and (3). and that the equilibrium
choices can be character-
world price of capital is positive
and locally unique and varies smoothly (with not all derivatives zero) in government decisions in a neighborhood of the CTE.” It is said that the tax structure is incomplrtr if yji tlZi > I for some j at the equilibrium.
3. Strictly improving perturbations In this section
I examine the effect on utilities
changes in communities’
resulting
from
marginal
decisions around a competitive tax equilibrium.
feasible changes are constrained
The
by private sector budgets and behavior, in
particular by the maximizing behavior of firms and households, and material balance. The goal is to identify the circumstances under which there exists a perturbation that results in a strict Pareto improvement. It is shown that such an improvcmont
exists
in general; thus
the CTE
is not constrained
efficient. Consider a differential change (dt,. d,~,)~ in communities’ decisions around a conipctitivc tax equilibrium, along with changes (drj)j in community govcrnmcnts’ lump-sum incumc. Through private behavior the change inducts a change in the allocation pivcn by (d.~, i, d_~~,.dk,),, and a change in the net-of-tax intcrcst rate. dr. The perturbation is called fcasihlc when it povcrnnicnt budget balance for all j. satisfies 1, T, SO. and maintains allowing for private sector responses. LA !I’(‘, r,, IN,) dcnotc the equilibrium lcvcl of lhc ohjcclivc (utility) in community j. Since the change in taxes and public cxpcnditurc lcvcls is along the budgets starting from the CTli. and the chnngc in private hchavior is along private hudgcts starting
from a consumer
optimum, it follows from the cnvclopc thcorcm that the marginal change has no direct first-order cffccts on utility. so the lirst-order change in utility is given solely by the indirect cffccts, through dr. and through the rcvcnue cffcct from dr,. That
dlij=
is to say. the change in utility
(7/I’ t'r
dr +
in j. JII,, is given by
(‘ddTj. ?Tj
The goal is to find fcasiblc changes that satisfy &cj>O for all j. From the regularity assumption there exists a fcasihlc change yielding dr #O. Then. the lemma below follows directly from cq. (1). using cj risOO, and using (71~j/?s,=;,j (from the envelope thcorcm):
There
LOWFla.
exists
du, > 0, all j. if‘und
7 ;‘, y
only
u />asible
marginal
chungr
from
the
CTE
satisflving
if
f @
(5)
Using the envelope theorem and eqs. (3). the form of a typical elemen ,t in the sum in eq. (5) is given by
(6) at the equilibrium. and where fact that ~I,,,~=II~~ evaluated is saving in j. The first term on the RHS of (6) is the wealth erect of the change in the consumer price of capital. the difference between the change in value of savings and the change in profit income (from the using the sj=(_rj-.~,j)
envelope theorem, c’nj/?r = -k,).
The second term captures the induced effect
on utility through ;I change in tax revenue (and hence public expenditures); this offccf is nonzcro when the tax structure is incomplctc. Summing cqs. (6) over j:
(7)
The sum on (he R tIS of (7) is a non-negative-wcightcd sum (with weights summing to I) of numbers, 11~~/;‘~,;III no larger lhan one and at least one of which is less than one when the tax struclurc is incomplete. Hence the sum is Ihl: expression in brackets is negative. It follows less than one, and immcdia~cly from the lcmm;l that an improvement exists; formally, it has been proved that:
An important role in the failure of the proof is played by (6). in particular by the second term in that expression, which captures how ;L government’s choices afkct utilities through their indirect effect on market-determined variables (here. the equilibrium price of capital) when the tax structure is incomplete. This second term can be interpreted as follows. The fundamental allocation problem in the model is that in each community there arc restricted possibilities for transferring resources across the two budget
constraints.
from
the resident
to the government.
What
can be called the
‘technology’ of the transfer possibilities depends on r, through its effect on private maximizing behavior. A change in r affects private behavior in a way that
alters
the marginal
possibilities
available imperfect tax instruments. equal to tj?kj/c’r,
for Using
transferring
resources
with
the
(3). the term can be seen to be
which is the induced tax revenue in j from a change in r.
evaluated at the equilibrium
tax rate. Moreover,
the direction
of the effect is
the same in all communities. so the sum does not vanish [unlike the wealth effects, captured in the first term in (6). the sign of which varies in general across j]. The failure arises because a competitive community ignores the effect of its decisions on the technology of transfer through its effect on world prices. Since the RHS follows
from
improvement. case would
of (7) is negative when the tax structure
eq. (4) The involve
that
any
change that
induces
is incomplete.. it
a fall
in
r
is
an
type of change that would accomplish this in the normal an increase in tax rates on capital.
However,
income
effects on saving and interactions bctwecn saving and the public good can produce counter-intuitive rtsults. To briefly invcstignte this, total diffcrcntiation of the capital market equilibrium
equation yields the comparative statics
of the modol:
~:urthcrmorc. the change, dgi, is constrained to maintain the j-budget. i.c. d,~,=dr~+(r,/J‘;) dr +(k,+ f,.:j’;) dfj, with ~,rj~O. For simplicity. consider the case whcrc the incomc effect on savings is zero and the public good and substitutes. Then (%/c’f,= saving eomplcments nor arc ncithcr 1/_/‘y& ( I/j‘: - t?s:jCr)] < 0, each j, where ?.s:/i7r dcnotus the (non-nugativc) compensated cfkct on saving. Under these circumstances a uniform increase. dr, in aII tax rates will lower r, resulting in an improvement. Savings and the capital stock fall; hcncc thcrc is ovcrsaving at the CTI:. It can bc shown that total tax rcvcnue rises with the uniform incrcasc in taxes, so that expcnditurc on public services c;ln rise in each community. It is important to note that the indicated change actually increases the aggregate deadweight loss associatcd with the tax system alone (since the gap between every individual’s intertemporal marginal rata of substitution and the marginal product of capital in any community widens); Proposition 1 establishes that this loss is more than offset by an efkiency gain in public good provision. In the special case, prominent in the previous literature, where the supply of savings is fixed, the first-order conditions characterizing the CTE, eqs. (2) and (3). continue to hold. because from any community’s point of view the
size of its tax base is independent of the domestic savings rate. Then eq. (6) continues
to
hold.
without
change.
Eq.
(8)
becomes drxi(
I:fy)
= -
xj(dt,/f;), so that any improvement involves raising taxes on average. Of course in this case a coordinated increase in taxes does not necessarily imply an increase in the excess burden of the tax system.
I close this section with two corollaries to Proposition I. First. an improvement exists satisfying dsj=O. all j. if any only if sj--(;‘j/rrri)kj
4. A Pigovian rrrndy l’hc demonstration of constraioncd incficicncy in the previous section is constructive in that it indicates the information that is nocdcd to idsntify an improving direction. With this information. communities may agree to some change. or in some contexts the changes may bc imposed. In this section I consider the possihilitics for improving intcrvcntions that prcscrvc the dcccntralization
of decisions:
in
particular
the goal is to find
the best
‘-‘Note th;lt since the KtiS trf (7) is nonrero. o utilit;lri:m welfare improvement without translixs alw;~ys exists when Ihe 1;1x structure is incomplete. Ilence the prohlcm arises because the price ch;mgcs have advercc wcdth elTcc~s for some j. In il model with more tradrablcs (in the present model there is onl) one r&live world price), il is more likely mu be ;~ble IO manipul;lte world prices IO engineer benelici:d wealth CITCCIS. so thal it is more likely that an improvemrnr without transfers exists. “‘This assumes th;lt. in the USC where the wealth rlTcct of the price change does not have the s;Lrnc sign for all nont;~ning communities. a trxder dr, IO nontaring community j has utility due for the resident equal tu the siLe or the transfer (IO make it possible IO OITS~I adverse wealth rll~ts. iT any). This complication does not detract from the point beins made here. “The conventional argument is that a community. when it considers raising its tax rate. ignores thal a higher lit\ T;LIC creates a re;II benefit for other communities by incrrasing the sire of their Ian bases as domestic capital migrales in response IO the higher tan rate. The demonstrations have been verb4 and intuitive; the argument can be found in. for example, Gordon (19X3.p. 5X3). Oates and Schwab ( IWX. p, 343). Wildusin (19X9. p, lY6). Wilson (IYX6. p. 303; lYX7. p. 837). and Zodrow and Mieszkowski (I986, p. 369). Starrett (19X8. pp. 187-1Xx) is a tcxlhook treatment of Ihe analogous problem for local sales taxes. whcrc individuals can choose the community of purchase.
intervention in the sense of the minimal dimension decentralize a constrained efficient allocation.
set of signals necessary to
The point of view is that the source of the failure of the CTE identified with a missing market for the mobile tax base. That constrained
eflicient allocation
can be is. at a
a number, ci. emerges which is interpreted
as
the shadow value of capital as tax base. By completing the markets (that is, in our model, by adding an extra signal corresponding to this shadow value in guiding communities’ decisions), a correspondence is established between the competitive equilibrium of this modified economy and the constrained ellicient allocations. Thus, the economist’s standard response to esternalities in competitive private ownership economies carries over to the present context. which contains two novel aspects: first the mode) has competitive governments using distortionary taxes (these distortions are not usefully thought of as standard technological externalities); and second the comparison allocations arc not fully (Pareto) efkient. but only second best. The
strategy of the approach in this section is, first.
to define the set of
constrained cflicicnt allocations prcciscly, and then to characterize those allocations by the first-order conditions for a constrained maximization problem. A modiftcd cconumy is then dclincd whcrc thcrc is a compctitivc for this modified niarkct for the tax base. and a compctitivc equilibrium economy is charactcrizcd by the first-order conditions for each community’s constrained maximk~tivn problem. A comparison of thcsc two sets of firstorder conditions cstablishcs a corrcspondcncc bctwccn the critical points. I begin with scvcral definitions. The economy is as dcfincd in section 2 above. A d~sj~~~r~ for the economy is dcfincd as an allocation (.ulj. _s~,.~~~,k,),, ;I ;I net-of-tax price of capital, r, and a set of
set of capital tax rates (tj),. transfers among community satisfies:‘” (i)
( r,)j.
A design is Jiwsihl~~ if it
Cj.\.I,‘+C,x,5;C,J’,;
(ii) illld,
govcrnmcnts
Cj
Sj~;O;
for each j:
(iii)
(.r,,, s2,) solves niax,,, ~) 1~r,(.u,,.\‘~;,~,):r.~, +~,~‘r)‘,+f[~(~+t~)+~)~~:;
(iv) g,sfjkj+r. (v)
I’ ’.tnd
kj SOIVCS max) ( J;(k)-(r+lj)k);
where n,(.) denotes the maximized value of profit in community j. A feasible design is said to bc ~~n.s~roirtc~cleJki~( if there dots not exist some other fcasiblc
design
whcrc
all
individuals
in
the
economy
arc
strictly
bcttcr
off.
Constrained ditions
efficient
for
function
designs
problem
LV[( u,Jx,
feasibility
SgO
that
will
of
be characterized
choosing
a
[the
(i)Hv).
Thus.
normalized
a constrained
in
there
to
its
numbers
associated
design
the
solves.
first-order
maximize
arguments,
exist
multiplier
efficient
by
design
j, xzi. s~))~]. increasing
constraints
number such
the
along
to
8jz0.
the
with
welfare
subject
(Oj)j,
with
con-
the
the
and
a
constraint
(i)]
the constraints,
for
each j:”
“ri = oj
1 _
(j
c’sj
(9)
c’gj1 ’
l'lj
[
lj = ii -
I;,.f‘;c I - p,,.
(10)
csc 3
=c ( I -
(11)
and
j(‘r
whcro
for
each j.
the (Slutsky) marginal
of income.
than can
hc
wcightcd
marginal
the tax
m;irgin;il
rate.
l;rom ralc
The
or
cvaluatcd
as
the
on eilhcr
an adjustment the
efkct
that Oulpul of
of
the reduction
zero.
value rate
of
substiturion
to
unity)
eq. (IO)
dcpcnds tluc
to
the
concerns.
tax
iIS rates relative
[From
cq.
from
in tht: economy’s
optimal
saving
the the
and the public
good
may
of
taxes;
CC.The
this
sum
along
depart to
cffcct
other
of capital
(I I),
commodity
the
from
rate.
in j
it
to
First.
the elasticity
the savings-share-weighted
(I I) is familiar
base
difkrs
two
system tax
tax
the lax rate in community
on
income
as
rather
(saving);
reasons.
for
saving
the
( 1975)
5 appears
on capital
capital
of
social savings
to Diamond’s
is that
ralc
marginal
direct
by the extra
of
bctwccn
burden
of this
rclatcd
diffcroncc tax
c’sTI~‘r dcnotcs
I/O, is the social
by the social
gcncratcd
closely
The
at the shadow
private
distributional
is not form
los(
bcncfit
(cqi~al
side of I. From
valuation
cxprcssing The
cxccss
in each community
minus
the
/ji is the sum
marginal
or substitutability
roinforcc
(capluring
normalized
shadow
the
term
to j.
CS is the shadow
the
cq. (0)
can lit
and
lcrni
The
term
of income.
of lr;Insformaliori
conlplcmcnrnrity offset
The
as before.
whcrc,
saving.
by S; /j, is thus
utility
inlcrprctctl
economy.
income
rcvcnuc.
IO ,j plus an indirect
of incomc
net social
of r on
effect
of (period-2)
of govcrnmcnl
benefit out
/I, = [I/O, + S c’s,/?rr~~]. and
compensated
utility
wclfarc
[jj),Vj.
,
Lcrm, j cquals
demand
from the
rcvcnue,
substitution
of the /Ii is less tax theory,
the compensated
(5
in j
uniformity)
government when
is (I,,
than
where
supply
I.] now
curve
is
evaluated as if there was a common tax rate equal to d. the shadow value of saving as tax base.‘“.”
I turn
now
constrained
to a consideration
efficient
allocation.
of the possibilities
First.
define the list
for decentralizing of numbers
a
(c;i)j by
cfij=O. The numbers (h,), become part of the data of a modified economy, where hj is interpreted as community i’s endowment of ‘rights to the tax vase’. Each community in the modified economy now has an additional decision, the choice of a quantity of rights to tax base, hi. subject to the constraint that it hold rights at least equal to its capital account surplus, allowing for an adjustment equal to I;,. It is assumed that these rights can be bought and sold at a price. denoted p. An equilibrium for the modified economy differs from a CTE defined in section 2 solely by the presence of this extra ‘market’; formally: Dcjinitifm.
A compt~titirx~
(fij)j is a list (.Y ,,, .~2j.sj. such that:
t0.v
c~fptifihriw
ji)r
rllc rr&j/kf
ccortom~ rdtrfir.c lo
lij. /I~)~.a list of capital tax rates (fj)P and prices (r, p)
(a) ~j.~,j+~jkj~‘cj~*,: (b) CjjljsCjh,; and, for each j. (c) (Y,,. szj) solves max.,, _ll [ ~(,(.~,..\‘,,,~~):f_\‘, +s,~r!.j+nj(r+lj)+“~j); (d) (
.r 5 rk, t I’( I;, - It).
(ii)
hzk,-s,.
(iii)
lij solves maxI, :./;(I,)-(r+f)k).
and
Clearly the (.Y,,, s2,,g,, k,. [,)j equilibrium for the modified p(hj-(k,-s,)).
Condition
to
and r associated with ;I competitive economy is ;I fcasiblc design, with
t;ix T,=
I‘hc term (k,-.sj) is j’s capital account surplus or deficit. (ii) requires that the community hold rights at least as large as its
capital account. Then (fij-/I,) is j’s net trade in rights to the tax base. and p(I;,-11,) is the value of this net trade. An institutional structure consistent with the equilibrium concept is as
R. Kreloce. Competitive
follows.
A central
international
clearing
context,
house (perhaps
a supranational
tax theory
373
a federal government
or, in the
agency) assigns endowments
(t;j)j of
rights to communities. It collects data on supplies and demands (the size of tax bases and savings rates) and attempts to establish an equilibrium price for rights. A community value of its capital rights.”
is then charged or receives a payment
account
surplus after allowance
equal to the
for its endowment
of
In the modified tax equilibrium concept, agents are decentralized with two signals, the prices r and p. Note that the signal p is relevant only to the decisions of the competitive governments; all private agents (households and firms) are decentralized at price r and, at equilibrium, the taxes (c~)~chosen by the communities. Consider the maximization competitive tax equilibrium. constraints
problem for community j in the modified The first-order conditions are given by the
and by: 7
!'~i=;.~ "Zj
1
_,!>j
[
'Sj
1
(12)
a nd
(13)
whcrc yj is j’s pcrccivcd normalized the modified
compctitivc
with cqs. (!I)-( I I) characterizing
What
Proposition
marginal
cquillibrium.
utility of govcrnmcnt
A comparison
constrained
rcvcnue at
of eqs. (12) and (13)
efliciency yields:
2 asserts is that the net-of-tax
price of traded capital
incorrectly reflects the social scarcity value of saving to the economy. Thus, traded goods prices, while suffkient to guide the decisions of private agents in the economy, arc not suflicicnt to coordinate the decentralized decisions of govcrnmcnts. They must in addition face the shadow value of tradeablcs as tax base. An attraction of the approach is that an indirect means, the market, may be usad to discover the shadow value of the tax base. Accompanying ‘“The
anulogy IO mclrketablc permits for. say. pollution
is immediate.
this informational
parsimony
principle,
the principle
namely
is the remedy’s consistency that
with
the best remedy for
the trageting
a failure
works directly on the relevant margin. This property is of value for the design of interventions in richer models where communities make decisions on a wider number of issues. some of them with solely domestic content.”
5. Concluding remarks The focus of this paper has been an important
class of multiple-jurisdiction
of spillover effects and of any exercise of monopoly power by governments in world markets. When each jurisdiction must pursue its goals models.
purged
using distortionary instruments. the competitive equilibrium is not constrained efficient in general, even though each perceives that the total costs of its policies are internalized. The example analyzed here strongly suggests that this is a general phcnomsnon; broadly, the result cxtcnds to any economy whcrc the sacond-best instruments in agprogatc dctorminc world prices. An implication of this is that much of normative tax theory. and more gcncrally the theory of optimal policy. dcvclopcd for closctl economics is in fact partial equilibrium theory in multi-country cnvironmcnts, cvcn when govcrnmcnts arc compctitivc. In addition, the nalurc
of the best dcccntralizcd
intervention
for
the
plcasing that this takes a economy has been analyzed. It is intuitively familiar form: the simple atlditivc structure dcrivcs from the fact that wc can assign to tradcablc commodities a shadow value as tax hasc. While thcrc arc
large
gaps, informational
tation that still
and
othcrwisc.
bctwccn concept
need to bc bridged. the analysis
points
and
implcmcn-
the way toward an
intcrvcntion policy potentially applicable to the design of intcrgovcrnmcntal grant schcmcs in fcdcral countries and to lax h~lrmoiiiz~ltioii efforts in the international
context.
Diamond. P.A.. 1975. A many-person Ramsey tax rule. Journal of Pubhc Economics 1. 33C342. DI~II. A., 1987. Strategic aspects of trade policy. in: T.F. Bewley. rd.. Advances tn economic theory: Fifth uorld congress (Cambridge Univewty Press. New York). Gordon. R.H., 1983. An optimal taxatton approach to fiscal federalism. QuarterI! Journal of Economics 98. 567-586. Mintz. J. and H. Tulkens. 1986. Commodity tax competition among member states of a federation: Equilibrium and rfliciencv. Journal of Public Economics 29. 133-172. Oates. W.E. ani R.M. Schwab. 198X.- Economic competttion among jurisdictions: Eficiency rnhancing or disturtwn inducing’! Journal of Public Economics 35. 333-35-I. Starrett. D.A.. 1980. Measuring rxternalltics and second best distortions in the theory of local public goods. Economctrlca JR, 627-642. Starrett. D..4.. 1988. Foundations of public economics (Cambridge tinirersity Press. New York). Wildasin. D.E.. IYSY. Intrrjur~sdictionul capital mobility: Fiscal cxtrrnaltty and a correctl\e subsidy. Journal of Urban Economics 15. 193-212. Wilson. J.D.. IY46, A theory of interregional tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics IY. ?Y6 315. Wilson. J.D.. IY87. Trade. capital mobility and tax competition. Journal of Polittcal Economy 95. X3r ~RS6. Zodrow. G.R. and P. Xliwkowski. 1986. P~gou. tirbout. property t;txation and the undcrprwision of local public goods. Journal of llrhan Economics IY. !.Sfr~-370.