423
CONSUMPTION OF GROUNDWATER AS A PRIVATE OR A PUBLIC GOOD
J . .PASQUUAL and I . ROCABERT Departament d'Economia A p l i c a d a , U n i v e r s i t a t Autdnoma de B a r c e l o n a , B e l l a t e r r a , Barcelona Spain ABSTRACT
Groundwater c o n s t i t u t e s a r e s o u r c e a s s e t t h a t g e n e r a t e s economic b e n e f i t s . These b e n e f i t s a r e a t t h e same time s u b j e c t t o e x t e r n a l i t i e s of one k i n d o r a n o t h e r . T h i s a r t i c l e examines t h e t r a d e - o f f i n v o l v e d i n u s i n g d e p l e t i v e o r n o n - d e p l e t i v e e x t r a c t i o n p o l i c i e s i n groundwater e x p l o i t a t i o n .
A p e r f e c t system of r e c h a r g e i n n o n - d e p l e t i v e u s e of groundwater means t h a t t h e t o t a l amount o f w a t e r a v a i l a b l e f o r use i s u n a f f e c t e d . R i v a l r y between consumers would n o t e x i s t . T h e r e f o r e , groundwater c o u l d be c o n s i d e r e d t o be a p u b l i c good, as d e s c r i b e d by Samuelson i n 1954. On t h e o t h e r hand, where e x t r a c t i o n i s d e p l e t i v e , i t must then be c o n s i d e r e d a p r i v a t e good. resources allocation t o The problem then l i e s i n t h e o p t i m i s a t i o n of t h e be e x p l o i t e d u s i n g e i t h e r one o f t h e s e two a l t e r n a t i v e s and t o d e t e r m i n e t h e optimum number of consumers f o r each o p t i o n . Once t h e problem has been a n a l y s e d from a P a r e t i a n p o i n t o f view, no i n t e r i o r s o l u t i o n e x i s t s . Maximum s o c i a l w e l f a r e must n e c e s s a r i l y be d e r i v e d from u s i n g e i t h e r one o r t h e o t h e r of t h e two s o l u t i o n s p o s s i b l e .
1 INTRODUCTION From
an
economic
point
of
view, groundwater c o n s t i t u t e s an asset whose
b e n e f i t s - t a n g i b l e and i n t a n g i b l e - are c l o s e l y consumer and
production a c t i v i t i e s .
related to,
and i n f l u e n c e d b y ,
Groundwater is a l s o t h e cause o f , and t h e
r e s u l t o f , e x t e r n a l economies and diseconomies. When e x p l o i t i n g an a q u i f e r , n o t o n l y
s h o u l d economic
agents determine the
s i z e of c a p i t a l investment r e q u i r e d as w e l l as t h e amount o f w a t e r t o
type and
be withdrawn. The i n f l u e n c e of e x t e r n a l i t i e s s h o u l d a l s o be determined i n terms of s o c i a l w e l f a r e i f t h e s e f i g u r e s a r e t o be o p t i m i s e d . The
results
will
property r i g h t s over possible t o
be
influenced
groundwater
by
existinglegislation- i n particular,
resources.
ik our
Moreover,
case,
it i s
d e c i d e whether groundwater i s a p r i v a t e o r a p u b l i c good u s i n g t h e
d e f i n i t i o n given by Samuelson ( 1 9 5 4 ) . Although t h e s i m p l e s t way o f d e f i n i n g
groundwater
is
as
a
pure p r i v a t e
good, t h e f a c t t h a t p r o p e r t y r i g h t s are n o t c l e a r l y d e f i n e d means t h a t problems may a r i s e similar t o t h o s e t h a t e x i s t i n t h e c a s e of p u b l i c goods. Where two o r more u s e r s
have t h e r i g h t t o e x p l o i t t h e same a q u i f e r , n e g a t i v e and r e c i p r o c a l
424 externalities appear ips0 facto. This situation is typical of "common ownership of natural resources", and, as Aguilera
policies to
correct
the
(1987), in
points out
situation, withdrawal
the absence o f
is uneconomical because the
amounts of groundwater withdrawn are excessive. Whether adequate legislation does o r
does not
exist, even
supposing an
ideal situation did exist, groundwater exploitation is always subject to the influence of externalities. The contamination of aquifers and between
health
the relationship
consumption are examples o f positive and negative
and water
externalities affecting groundwater exploitation. According to Bird (1987), differentiating between
a proper
analysis of
transferible
distinction should also be made
and
between
the problem
must involve
non-transferible externalities. A
depletable externalities
-acting as
good- and non-depletable externalities characteristic o f a pure
pure private public good
(Baumol and Oates, 1975).
On the other hand, an aquifer may be
exploited where
fixed costs
are low
and variable costs high, or, where fixed costs are high and variable costs low. Where fixed costs
are high, groundwater may
be
considered a
public good
(Mueller 1979, and Baumol; Panzar and Willing 1982). It is, therefore, possible to convert a private good into a public good at any one time. Similarly, the withdrawal o f a particular quantity of water by one consumer may reduce
amount of water available f o r the use of other consumers
the total
(depletive extractions). Rivalry between consumers would then exist teristisic of
a private
the total amount
of
-a charac-
good. Alternatively, withdrawals may be made so that
water
available is not
affected
(e.g.
using perfect
recharge methods or non-depletive extraction policies)- a situation which would be characteristic of a
pure public
good. Again, the possibility
of deciding
whether to use groundwater as a private o r a public good arises. Groundwater is therefore a "transformable natural resource" (private f public). The situation, then, is a complex breaking
it
down
into
more
one which
simplified
can
best
be
understood by
forms, each o f which deals with one
relevant aspect of the whole. In this way, the situation can be
better defined
as a result of more detailed analysis. The following article is a study of groundwater as a transformable natural resource which may be used wholly or partially as a pure private good o r a pure public good without legislative restrictions of the optimum allocation of extractions within
available resources
the framework
of a
any kind. The aim is to find
for depletive o r non-depletive
general Paretian model. Similarly, an
effort will be made to optimise the number of consumers f o r each alternative.
425
2. THE MODEL Taking H as
identical individuals having
consumption of a transformable good X well as f o r the consumption of the same Individuals have
definite preferences f o r the
-groundwater- as a public good, Xn, as groundwater X as a private good,
also established preferences over
the
consumption of a
non-transformable pure private good, L. These preferences can be represented by the utility function, h h h h U (Xn, Xm, L ) ; h=l, which we
. .., H
suppose strictly concave and twice continually differentiable. Two
types of individuals are considered. On the one hand, one that consumes X only as a private good, m, whose utility function will be, Um(Xm, L), wM,
O<%H
and another that consumes X as
a collective good, n , whose utility function
will be, u"(Xn,Ln); nE(H-M), H>1. The problem consists of determining which
is the optimun size of each of
these groups -choosing M- and allocating the initial resources of the transformable good between consumption as a private and as a
collective good -choosing
Xm and Xn. Being w the initial resources of groundwater, the feasibility constraint will be, W-MX -X =O. m n This equation reflects that each of the M consumers consumes a quantity X
of X
as a private good, while X
represents that part consumed as a collective
good by the rest of consumers (H-M). With respect to the non-transformable private
good, there
and L resources, T. The individual consumptions L m variables. The associated feasibility constraint is,
exist initial
are additional decision
T-ML -(H-M)L =O The welfare in this
society will
be evaluated by using Bergson's social
welfare function,
L~ ) W = M U ~xm, ( L ~+ (H-M)u"(x~, ) Firstly, we
.
will consider the problem
of attaining
within a planned economy where decision-makers have at variables in
the problem
second-best optimum will be
a first best optimum
their disposal all the
as decision variables.Secondly Various problems of examined when
some of
the control variables are
predetermined.
3. THE FIRST-BEST PROBLEM 3.1 General Case The problem to be solved in its singlest version is as follows:
426
s . t . : W-MX -Xn (a0 rl m (H-M ) L
'
T-ML,-
n(3 r2 where X m , X n , Lm, L a r e t h e d e c i s i o n v a r i a b l e s a n d , H , w , T are p a r a m e t e r s .
a problem
This i s
of conditioned
n o n - l i n e a r programming i n which we know
t h a t i f t h e o b j e c t i v e f u n c t i o n as w e l l a s t h e c o n s t r a i n t s ( i n t h e
form 3 ) a r e
concave, t h e problem h a s a maximum ( i n t e r i o r ) . u t i l i t y f u n c t i o n s a r e s t r i c t l y concave, by h y p o t h e s i s i t is e a s y
Since the
t o prove t h a t t h e constraint
for
non-transformable
Conversely, the c o n s t r a i n t convex on ( X
W (.)
objective function the
m' Xn, M ) . i s no
Thus, t h e r e
is a l s o
corresponding
to
i n t e r i o r maximum,
concave. The f e a s i b i l i t y
good ( 3 ) , i s concave as w e l l .
private the
transformable choice is
hence t h e
good
( 2 ) is
limited t o the
s t u d y of two c a n d i d a t e p o i n t s , t h e two corners. These p o i n t s are Wo and W1,
W (M=O,X = O , L = O , ( H - M ) = H , X = w , L =T/H) 0 m m n n W 1( M = H , X = w / H , L m =T/H,(H-M)=O,Xn = O , L n = O )
W
0
measures t h e s o c i a l w e l f a r e when
mable good expression W
t r a n s f o r m a b l e good
resource6 w
all the
of the transfor-
by a l l t h e i n d i v i d u a l s as a p u r e c o l l e c t i v e good. The
a r e consumed measures
(4) (5)
the
social
welfare
when
all
the
resources
a r e consumed by a l l t h e i n d i v i d u a l s as a p u r e p r i v a t e good.
A s a l l t h e i n d i v i d u a l s a r e i d e n t i c a l , we can do w i t h o u t t h e non-transformable
good, L ,
t h e consumption o f
t o e v a l u a t e t h e c a n d i d a t e p o i n t s . The d e c i s i o n
depends e x c l u s i v e l y upon t h e s i g n of D: det m D= U ( w / H ) - U n ( w ) Consequently, a preferred i n
of t h e
(6)
sufficiency condition
t o ensure
that it
i s not s o c i a l l y
any c a s e t o consume as a p r i v a t e good a good t h a t can be consumed
a s a c o l l e c t i v e one, i s ,
U ~ ( X ~ ~ U " )( , X f o r e v e r y
x,\
g i v e n t h a t w/H
~ < Q u ~ ( x ~ ) \ < u ~f o( rx ~e v)e,r y x&c xn
(7)
The r e v e r s e is n o t t r u e . I f t h e p r e f e r e n c e s a r e such t h a t : U ' " ( X ~ ) ~ U " ( X ~ )f o r e v e r y
t h e n n o t h i n g can be preferences. I n
x,axn
s a i d about
order t o
(8) the sign
of D
w i t h o u t knowing
exactly those
o b s e r v e t h e r e s u l t of d i f f e r e n t p r e f e r e n c e s o v e r t h e
consumption of X e i t h e r as a p r i v a t e good o r as a c o l l e c t i v e good, a s i m u l a t i o n was e f f e c t e d , as shown below.
427 b U n ( . ) = ( l / b ) X n + L n ; O
n s . t . : W-MX -Xn ~0
This
problem,
X > O , X > O , MaO. n' f o r t h e same r e a s o n s
as t h o s e e x p l a i n e d e a r l i e r f o r t h e
g e n e r a l c a s e , does n o t have an i n t e r i o r maximum. I n Table I , t h e v a l u e s t a k e n
for
the
social
welfare
function
f o r each
c o r n e r s o l u t i o n a r e shown f o r v a r i o u s v a l u e s of a and d i v e r s e r e l a t i o n s between
a and b. We w i l l suppose t h a t
the
of
value
the
parameters
the initial
of
r e s o u r c e s of t h e t r a n s f o r m a b l e good w and t h e p o p u l a t i o n H i s w=200 H=100.
A s follows
from t h e
Table I , whether o r n o t t h e o p t i o n of
o b s e r v a t i o n of
consuming i t
consuming X as a pure c o l l e c t i v e good w i l l dominate t h e o p t i o n o f
as a
pure p r i v a t e good w i l l depend upon t h e r e l a t i v e s t r e n g t h of t h e p r e f e r e n -
c e s between b o t h t y p e s of consumption. The goodness of each a l t e r n a t i v e cannot
"a p r i o r i "
be e s t a b l i s h e d
but i t
s h o u l d be computed f o r each c a s e , s i n c e i t depends on i n d i v i d u a l p r e f e r e n c e s .
4.
SECOND BEST PROBLEMS
A s we have seen i n t h e above s e c t i o n , t h e f i r s t - b e s t problem h a s a maximum, which is unique b u t i t i s a c o r n e r s o l u t i o n . There
It i s
for this
are closer
are no
interior solutions.
reason t h a t i t i s worth l o o k i n g a t some second b e s t c a s e s t h a t
t o more
r e a l i s t i c situations.
Let u s
v a r i a b l e s of t h e
t a k e some
g e n e r a l c a s e a s predetermined v a l u e s which means t h a t t h e y s h o u l d be c o n s i d e r e d
as a p a r a m e t e r . We w i l l s t u d y two c a s e s i n p a r t i c u l a r . F i r s t l y , when t h e duals, M,
consuming t h e
number of i n d i v i -
good as a p u r e p r i v a t e good i s i n s t i t u t i o n a l l y f i x e d ,
and s e c o n d l y , we w i l l suppose t h a t some o t h e r v a r i a b l e s a r e p r e d e t e r m i n e d . I n t h e f i r s t c a s e , t h e c o n s t r a i n t ( 2 ) , which was convex ( i n t h e form the general
case, w i l l
be transformed
t h e r e w i l l be an i n t e r i o r s o l u t i o n . I f p r i v a t e good
were p r e d e t e r m i n e d ,
a
)
the
the lack
quantity
Xm
as
consumed
a pure
of c o n c a v i t y of t h e c o n s t r a i n t ( 2 )
would p e r s i s t . Moreover, a c o r n e r s o l u t i o n (M=O) i s
not feasible
since i t not
p o s s i b l e t o f u l f i l t h e c o n s t r a i n t ( 2 ) f o r t h i s v a l u e . Furthermore, i f g i v e n X t h e necessary concavity of t h e o b j e c t i v e
function
fails,
the
study
l i m i t e d t o Case 1. Case 1. M g i v e n
I t would be t o s o l v e :
max .W=MUm( Xm,Ln) + ( H-M )Un(Xn,Ln )
in
i n t o a s t r a i g h t l i n e and c o n s e q u e n t l y ,
(9)
n' w i l l be
4 N -
m
TABLE 1
Measure of welfare f o r options W1 (water consumption as a private good) and Wo as a function of the preferences (a,b), being w=200 and H=100
(consumption as a public good)
: a I
1/100
10.069
1/50 1/20 1/15
5.069 2.070 1.571
1/10
1.072
1/7 1/5 l/4 1/3 5/12
772,s 574 475 7 378,l 320,Z 9 4 t
2.135
1.983
1.699
1.551
1.507
1.500
1.487
1.440 1.540 1.754 2.371 3.417
1.452 1.633 1.944 2.828 4.387
1.590
1.858
2.040
2.081
2.168
2.081
2.828
2.828 5.129 9.924
4.388
3.351 5.555 14.030 37.779
3.470 5.829
3.725 6.426
15.052 41.456
17.340
9.924 23.942
429
s.t.: w-MX -X =O r m n 1 T-ML -(H-M)L =O
r
where Xm, Xn, L
are control variables and M. H, w and T are parameters.
and L
(10)
(11)
2
The first-order conditions of this programme
are necessary and sufficient
for an overall maximum and they are: M(qm-rl)
=
M($m-;2)
= 0
0
(H-M)UXn-rl = 0
0
( H-M)(U"L-r2) =
That is, from (12) and 1=(13), and from (14) and (15):
which coincide with the optimality conditions f o r a pure private good (16) for M consumers and for a pure collective good ( 1 7 ) f o r vely. From (13) and (15) results,
(H-M) consumers, respecti-
Tm=qn.
as that from (16) and (17) it can
so
be written, That is, the utility at the optimum of increase in
the consumption of the
an individual due to
a marginal
good Xm has to be (H-M) times higher than
that corresponding to an individual n due to marginal consumption of X
.
5. CONCLUSIONS Groundwater may be considered to be an asset factors, each
influenced by
a multitude of
in itself of sufficient importance and complexity to justify a
separate analysis. This
article has
examined
the
social desirability of
depletive extraction policies (as a private good) as opposed to non-depletive extraction (as a public good) independent of other relevant aspects. I f it is considered that groundwater may be used wholly
private good
or as
or partially as a
public good, then independent of the social welfare func-
tion, a two-good solution can never be an optimum solution. That is
to
say that, depending upon
individual preferences
for one or
other system, it will either be socially beneficial to use the total amount of water available without depleting resources or to
carry out
it will
be socially beneficial
depletive extraction. Any in-between solution would not be as
socially beneficial. This conclusion is society organised
valid
for nations, as well
as any
in nations even though differing individual preferences may
exit. The analysis has been made from a Paretian point of view in nal vacuum.
an institutio-
430
The conclusions reached are independent of any property rights that may be established. The concession of
property rights must however be in consonance
system is chosen. If not, rivalries will develop between private
with whatever
and social interests
(Turvey 1963) which
could give
rise
to inefficient
allocation.
6. REFERENCES Aguilera Klink (1987). "Los recursos naturales de propiedad comdn:una introducci6n". Revista de Estudios Regionales. En imprenta. Baumol, W.J., and Oates, W.E.,
1975.
Externalities, Public Outlays
and
"The The
theory
of
Environmental Policy:
Quality of Life". Prentice-Hall,
Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Baumol, W.J., Panzar, J.C. and Willig, A . D . ,
1982. "Contestable Markets and the
Theory of Industry Structure". Harcourt Bran Jovanovichs, Inch. N.Y. Bird, P.J.W.N., 1987, "The Transferability and Depletability of Externalities". Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 14, 54-57 Kindleberger, C.P.; 1986. "International Public Goods without International Government", The American Economic Review, 76, 1 : 1-13 King D.,
1984. Fiscal Tiers: "The Economics of Multilevel Government". George
Allen and Unwin (Publishers) Ltd. London. McCormick, E. et al., 1981. Inquiry into
the
"Politicians, Legislation, and
the
Economy: an
Interest-Group Theory of Government". Martinus-Nijhoff,
Boston. Milleron, J.C., 1972. "Theory of Value Journal of Economic Theory, Mueller, D . C . ,
with Public Goods: A
Survey Article",
5: 419-447.
1979. "Public Choice, v.c." Alianza Editorial. Madrid,1984.
Samuelson, P.A.,
1954.
"The Pure Theory
o f Public Expenditure", Review o f
Economics and Statistics, 36: 387-389. Turvey, R., 1963.
"On Divergences between
Social Cost
and
Private Cost",
Economica, NS 30: 309-313. Zodrow, C . R . , Twenty
-
1983. "Local Provison of Public Services: The liebout Model after Five Years". Academic Press Inc. New York. 77877;).