Accepted Manuscript Financial protection of households against health shocks in Greece during the economic crisis Athanasios E. Chantzaras, John N. Yfantopoulos PII:
S0277-9536(18)30332-0
DOI:
10.1016/j.socscimed.2018.06.024
Reference:
SSM 11811
To appear in:
Social Science & Medicine
Received Date: 28 November 2017 Revised Date:
13 May 2018
Accepted Date: 20 June 2018
Please cite this article as: Chantzaras, A.E., Yfantopoulos, J.N., Financial protection of households against health shocks in Greece during the economic crisis, Social Science & Medicine (2018), doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2018.06.024. This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Cover page
Financial protection of households against health shocks in Greece during the
Athanasios E. Chantzarasa, John N. Yfantopoulosb a
and Kapodistrian University Athens, Greece, email:
SC
School of Economics and Political Sciences, National of Athens, 6 Themistokleous Street, 106 78
[email protected]. b School of Economics and Political Sciences, National of Athens, 6 Themistokleous Street, 106 78
[email protected].
RI PT
economic crisis
M AN U
and Kapodistrian University Athens, Greece, email:
Corresponding author: Chantzaras Athanasios, Research Associate, School of Economics and Political Sciences, National and Kapodistrian University of Athens, 6 Themistokleous Street, 106 78 Athens, Greece, email:
[email protected], tel: +30
AC C
EP
TE D
6938639268.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Abstract Background: Harsh funding cutbacks along with measures shifting cost to patients have been implemented in the Greek health system in recent years. Our objective was
of-pocket payments (OOPP) during the economic crisis.
RI PT
to investigate the evolution of financial protection of Greek households against out-
Methods: National representative data of 33,091 households were derived from the
SC
Household Budget Surveys for the period 2008-2015. Financial protection was assessed by applying the approaches of catastrophic (CHE) and impoverishing OOPP.
M AN U
The determinants of CHE and impoverishment were examined using multivariate logistic regressions.
Results: OOPP dropped by 23.5% in real values between 2008 and 2015, though their share in households’ budget rose from 6.9% to 7.8%, with an increasing trend since
TE D
2012. These outcomes were driven by significant increases in medical products (20.2%) and inpatient (63%) OOPP, while outpatient expenses decreased considerably (-62%). Both incidence and overshoot of CHE were significantly
EP
exacerbated. The additional burden was distributed progressively, hence, financial risk inequalities decreased. Food poverty increased, but its incidence still remains at
AC C
very low levels. Both incidence and intensity of relative poverty increased considerably in real terms. The poverty impact of OOPP is exacerbating following 2012, and 1.9% of individuals were impoverished due to OOPP in 2015. Households of higher size, lower expenditure quintile, in urban areas, without disabled, elderly or young children members, and with younger or retired, better-educated breadwinners were significantly less vulnerable to CHE. Households in the lower-middle expenditure quintile, in rural regions and with elderly members were facing higher
1
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT risk, while wealthier families exhibited considerable lower likelihood of impoverishment. Conclusions: The expansion of reliance of healthcare funding on OOPP has increased the financial risk and hardship of Greek households, which may disrupt their living
recognise the different social protection needs of households.
SC
Keywords:
RI PT
conditions and create barriers to healthcare access. Cost-sharing policies should
M AN U
Financial fairness, equity, healthcare financing, catastrophic health expenditure,
AC C
EP
TE D
poverty, impoverishment, out-of-pocket payment, Greece
2
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 1. Introduction The prolonged economic crisis has taken its toll on the Greek society as a whole, as many social indicators, such as GDP, unemployment, poverty and inequality have deteriorated (see Figure 1). This is exactly the type of emergency that the welfare
RI PT
state is designed to weather (Castles, 2010), however, the deep budget cuts have stripped the system off its capacity to respond to these crucial social challenges. The Greek health system has been in the spotlight of the economic adjustment
SC
programmes, with several structural reforms and harsh funding cutbacks implemented during the recent years (Karanikolos & Kentikelenis, 2016; Karanikolos et al., 2013).
M AN U
These drastic healthcare spending curtailment from the Greek government can only force citizens to fill the healthcare system’s funding void from their own pockets. A health system’s financing arrangements is a key driver of population health and well-being (Yardim et al., 2010). Financial protection in healthcare has long been
TE D
recognised as a major policy goal, since it relates to the broader issue of access to adequate and quality healthcare and equity in health status (Marmot, 2007). The abrupt character of ill-health (health shocks) may induce the allocation of large
EP
portions of household financial resources (budget shocks) to the purchase of health
AC C
goods and services, thus disrupting their living conditions or even forcing them into poverty or deepening the poverty they have already been experiencing (Wagstaff, 2007). The reliance on out-of-pocket payments (OOPP) for healthcare induces considerable financial strain in households. In 2010, approximately 150 million people worldwide sustained financial catastrophe, and 100 million people were pushed below the poverty line due to unavoidable OOPP (WHO, 2013). Even further, relatively high OOPP may create access barriers for some poor individuals preventing them from seeking necessary treatment (Xu et al., 2007). Consequently, it is justified 3
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT to argue that in a fair and equitable health system, households should not be forced to more medical spending than that which exceeds a certain share of their budget, and financial risks must be shared equally within the society (Wagstaff, 2007; Xu et al., 2003a).
RI PT
The main purpose of this study was to investigate the evolution of financial protection of households against OOPP in the Greek health system during the economic crisis by applying the approaches of catastrophic and impoverishing OOPP. Furthermore, we
SC
sought to provide an initial examination of the vulnerability of households to financial
M AN U
risk and hardship due to OOPP. 2. Short overview of the Greek health system
In general, the Greek health system is among the most privatised in the European Union (EU), and OOPP have been the dominant form of private health expenses (Yfantopoulos, 2008). Even before the crisis, the Greek health system was suffering
TE D
from a series of inefficiencies (Economou, 2010): high degree of centralisation, ineffective managerial structures, lack of planning and coordination, uneven and
EP
inefficient allocation of human and economic resources, fragmentation of care and absence of a referral and gatekeeping system, inequalities in access to services due to
AC C
diverse benefit packages provided by multiple insurance funds, regressive funding mechanisms attributable to high private financing in the form of formal and informal payments, widespread tax and social security contribution evasion and excessive indirect taxation, anachronistic reimbursement system not related to performance, and lack of a health technology assessment system. These structural problems in conjunction with the amassed financial pressures and the failure to contain health expenditure growth during the previous decade placed the health sector at the center of the reform agenda of the economic adjustment programmes. Overall, current total 4
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT health expenditure dropped by 34.5% between 2009 and 2015 (Eurostat, 2017) (see Table S1 in online Appendix). This was mainly driven by cuts in public health spending (-43.5%), and particularly in social security funding (-54.3%). Since private health expenditure decreased by a smaller rate (-18.1%), its share of total health
RI PT
spending was enlarged.
The health system in Greece is a mixture of public integrated, public contract and public reimbursement systems (Economou, 2010), where the tax-funded Beveridge-
SC
type national health system (ESY), introduced in the early 1980s, goes hand in hand with a Bismarckian insurance fund structure (Yfantopoulos et al., 2016). In 2011, the
M AN U
majority of social insurance funds were unified under the umbrella of the National Organization for the Provision of Health Services (EOPYY), which now covers over 98% of the insured population (Karakolias & Polyzos, 2014). EOPYY purchases primary and secondary healthcare services for its insured members from both public
TE D
and private healthcare suppliers. Another important reform concerned the reorganisation of primary healthcare (2014), which was moved from the jurisdiction of EOPYY to the ESY structure and the newly established National Primary Health
EP
Care Network (PEDY) (Economou et al., 2015). Major cost-containment measures
AC C
included (Economou, 2015): cuts to public healthcare personnel salaries and replacement restrictions (2010), changes in procurement of health supplies (2010), mandatory e-prescription for all medical activities (2012), enhanced budgetary and operational monitoring and auditing of healthcare spending (2012) and establishment of a Diagnosis-Related Group (DRG) hospital payment system (2013). Furthermore, a series of horizontal cuts resulted in reductions in insurance coverage. Some expensive examinations were no longer reimbursed by the common benefits basket, and entitlement restrictions were also introduced in other cases (Economou, 2015). User
5
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT charges for treatment and clinical tests in private clinics and laboratories contracted with EOPYY were increased, and exemptions were removed for some groups (e.g. chronically-ill people) (European Commission & Economic Policy Committee, 2016). Regarding ambulatory care, the fixed fee for outpatient care in public hospitals was
RI PT
increased from 3 to 5 euros between 2010 and 2015, when it was abolished altogether. In 2010, a mandatory all-day functioning of public hospitals was enacted, with the afternoon outpatient surgeries of public hospitals providing medical services to
SC
patients on a consultation fee ranging between 30 and 90 euros depending on physicians’ grades; a horizontal reduction of 20% was implemented on all fees in
M AN U
2013 (Economou, 2015; European Commission & Economic Policy Committee, 2016).
The curtailment of pharmaceutical expenditure was set as a priority by the economic adjustment programmes. On average, the annual growth rate of pharmaceutical
TE D
expenditure was higher than that of GDP in Greece during the 1990’s and early 2000’s; their share of GDP was doubled from 0.9% to 1.8% between 1990 and 2004, while their share of current health expenditure increased from 14.9% to 23% in the
EP
same period (OECD, 2018). In 2009, Greece was associated with the highest share of
AC C
(outpatient) pharmaceutical expenditure in GDP (2.6%) among all OECD countries, which was mainly financed through public schemes (78.1% of drug spending) (OECD, 2018). A recent qualitative study of the legislation revealed that 82.6% of the measures in the pharmaceutical sector were cost-containment efforts, and 59.8% of them reallocated cost to consumers (Yfantopoulos et al., 2017). As a result of the adoption of the undermentioned measures, the share of drug expenses in GDP dropped to 2.2% in 2015, and the public funding was restricted to 51.7% of pharmaceutical payments (OECD, 2018). 6
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT The introduction of a negative list for medicines (2011) withdrew the reimbursement status from many drugs, and significant increases in cost-sharing rates for several chronic diseases took place between 2012 and 2013 (Siskou et al., 2014). A new reimbursement system was established in 2012 based on an internal reference price
RI PT
system; in cases where the retail price was higher than the reimbursement price, besides the statutory cost-sharing rates, patients had to cover the full price difference. Also, a fixed fee of €1 per prescription paid as co-payment by patients has been
SC
imposed since 2014 (Gouvalas et al., 2016; Siskou et al., 2014). Other major costcontainment measures in the pharmaceutical sector included: reduction in VAT for
M AN U
medicines (2011), a new pricing system based on the average price of the three lowest-priced markets in the EU (2011), reductions in the profit margins of pharmacies and wholesalers (2011-2015), automatic rebates on private pharmacies (2011) and clawbacks on pharmaceutical companies (2012), compulsory prescription
TE D
guidelines/protocols and prescription by active substance (2012), incentives and obligations to promote generics (2012), detailed monitoring on prescription patterns and pharmaceutical expenditure (2012), and spending cap and prescribing ceilings on
EP
physicians (2014) (Economou et al., 2015; European Commission & Economic Policy
AC C
Committee, 2016).
In general, the introduction of or the increase in existent user fees or contributions and the restriction of entitlements entail additional economic burden for all healthcare users of public healthcare services, since they are not conditional on means-testing in Greece. However, households with more available resources are better equipped to absorb this extra direct cost without being exposed to higher financial risk or hardship. Some other measures designed to control demand, such as prescribing ceilings and spending limits may also be felt heavier among the economically weaker
7
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT groups, as consumers could be compelled to use non-reimbursable services or to turn to the private sector. On the other hand, some price reductions that have been implemented on pharmaceuticals (or abolition of fees) alleviate the financial burden of ill-health, presumably relatively more in poorer households than in richer ones. It is
RI PT
not possible to discern the independent effect of each of the abovementioned reforms since they were implemented during a relatively short period. Therefore, the following analysis should be largely interpreted as the combined effect of the policy
SC
changes and the economic implications of the crisis. Nevertheless, the time of enactment of these reforms is important, hence, a figure is provided to function as a
(Figure 1). 3. Materials and Methods 3.1. Data source
M AN U
(simplified) timeline of the major reforms implemented between 2008 and 2015
TE D
This study utilised the microdata collected by the Greek Household Budget Surveys (HBS) for the years 2008-2015, which were provided by the Hellenic Statistical
EP
Authority. The HBS is a cross-sectional survey comprising nationally representative data covering all non-institutional households in the country, and it is carried out with
AC C
a two-stage stratified sampling. Our overall sample consisted of 33,091 households and their 81,649 members. In the Greek HBS, household consumption expenditure encompasses both monetary and non-monetary payments on all goods and services as well as the monetary value of the consumption of household’s own production during the reference period. OOPP is an expense incurred directly by a household in return for a healthcare service net of any insurance reimbursement. In the case of HBS, its main contributors are expenses for a) medical products, appliances and equipment, b) out-patient and c) hospital services. Pharmaceutical expenditure is the largest 8
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT component of medical products (82.4-91.4%, depending on the year; see also Table S2 in online Appendix), and it involves outpatient drug expenses incurred by patients, hence it doesn’t capture hospital pharmaceutical spending. 3.2. Statistical analysis
RI PT
The extent of the protection of households against the financial implications of illhealth is explored through the approaches of catastrophic health expenditures (CHE) and impoverishment as a result of OOPP (O'Donnell et al., 2008; Wagstaff &
SC
Doorslaer, 2003; Xu & World Health Organization/Department of Health System
Health
Organization
(WHO)
M AN U
Financing, 2005). Our analysis followed the methodological framework of the World (Xu
et
al.,
2003a;
Xu
&
World
Health
Organization/Department of Health System Financing, 2005) and O'Donnell et al. (2008). These approaches describe two different dimensions. While better-off households may incur large CHE without ever being impoverished or experiencing
TE D
any hardship, households living on the verge of poverty may become poor with even a small amount of health payments that may not be declared as catastrophic in relation
EP
to their share of household resources (Xu et al., 2003a). All expenditures were deflated (2015=100) with the price index obtained from
AC C
Eurostat (2017) and were equivalised considering the economy scale of household consumption (Xu et al., 2003a). The complex sample design was also incorporated into our analyses. 3.2.1. CHE
A CHE occurs if OOPP surpasses a predefined threshold share (zcat) of household’s standard of living (O'Donnell et al., 2008; Xu et al., 2003a). The value of zcat denotes the point at which greater medical spending may be at the expense of other basic necessities. However, there is no consensus among previous studies regarding the 9
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT level of this threshold. We opted to use a range of thresholds (10%, 20%, 30%, 40%) to improve the robustness of our findings, and let the readers choose where to ascribe more weight. This study adopts a definition of CHE in relation to household capacity to pay (CTP).
RI PT
A household’s CTP is given by its effective income (total consumption expenditure) net of basic subsistence needs. Subsistence expenditure was approximated on the basis of the share of total expenditure spent on food (Xu & World Health
SC
Organization/Department of Health System Financing, 2005). As suggested by O'Donnell et al. (2008), we defined an indicator E, which equals 1 if the share of
M AN U
OOPP in the CTP of the ith household is equal to or larger than the predefined threshold zcat. Then an estimate of headcount (H) is: =
1
20%, 30% and 40%.
TE D
Where N is the sample size and zcat are the specific thresholds explored, i.e. 10%,
EP
Let Oi be the catastrophic overshoot, i.e. the percentage points by which household
AC C
spending on health exceeds the threshold zcat as: =
(
−
)
Then the overshoot, i.e. the average excess of health payment budget share in the whole sample, is:
=
1
10
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT The incidence (H) and intensity (O) of CHE are related through the mean positive overshoot (MPO), which expresses the average excess of health payment budget share of those households with CHE, i.e. the intensity of excess, and it is defined as:
RI PT
=
The above measures are insensitive to the distribution of CHE. To account for the differential opportunity cost of health spending between the poor and the rich,
=
(1 −
)
M AN U
overshoot measures as follows:
SC
Wagstaff and Doorslaer (2003) introduced the rank-weighted headcount and
Where Hw is the weighted headcount and CE is the concentration index for Ei, and =
(1 −
!
)
TE D
Where Ow is the weighted overshoot and CE is the concentration index for Oi. The concentration index is a measure of socioeconomic inequality, and can be defined as (O'Donnell et al., 2008):
EP
2#
%$ℎ = ( + *+ + ,-$ '
AC C
Where σ2 is the variance of the fractional rank (r) of household i in the equivalised expenditure distribution, hi is the indication CHE or overshoot for household i, µ is its mean, β is an estimate of the concentration index and ε is an error term. The concentration index is bounded between -1 and +1. If the value is negative, namely the incidence or intensity is more concentrated on poor households, higher weights are ascribed to headcount and overshoot ratios to account for the fact that low-income households are the ones experiencing more catastrophe, and HW or Ow are greater than H and O, respectively. If the value is positive, the incidence or intensity is more 11
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT concentrated on rich households, and the weighted estimates will be lower than the unweighted (Wagstaff & Doorslaer, 2003). The aforementioned measures were further disaggregated with respect to households’ expenditure quintile, and we also calculated quintile ratios (poorest/richest
RI PT
households) and performed χ2 and t-tests of the differences between 2008 and 2015.
Also, we calculated a summary index of the fairness in financial contribution of households, i.e. the Financial Fairness Contribution index (FFCI) (Murray et al.,
SC
2003; Xu & World Health Organization/Department of Health System Financing, 2005):
∑ − ∑
2
M AN U
.. / = 1 −
0∑
4
3
2
The FFCI compares the distribution of OOPP to a norm reference level, where
TE D
households contribute the same share of their CTP (principle of equal burden), and it corresponds to the ratio of total OOPP to total CTP of households. Therefore, this is a measure of departure from proportionality. The index ranges between 0 (maximum
EP
departure from proportionality or inequality) and 1 (minimum departure from proportionality or inequality). Deviations from perfect financial fairness can be
AC C
decomposed into a vertical (households with different CTP contribute different proportions of their CTP) and a horizontal (households with similar CTP pay different proportions of their CTP) effect. However, a limitation of this index is that it reflects both vertical and horizontal equity, without distinguishing between them, though the two imply quite different policy implications, as Wagstaff (2002) notices. For instance, not all horizontal discrepancies are inequitable, as they may arise from disparate utilisation levels (partly attributed to differences in illness) or unequal unit
12
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT prices, which may reflect quality differences or fee exemptions. It might be argued that two individuals with similar health problems may decide to allot different portions of their CTP to health services. Furthermore, any departure from proportionality is considered unfair by this index, whether it is progressive or
RI PT
regressive. Nevertheless, the redistributive impact of OOPP on household income is not part of the objectives of this study, which focuses on the financial burden of OOPP based on the equal burden principle (Xu et al., 2003b), though the distribution
SC
of CHE is taken into account by the weighted measures of catastrophe.
M AN U
3.2.2. Impoverishment
Impoverishment is the process whereby a household falls below the poverty line as a result of OOPP (O'Donnell et al., 2008). We used two poverty lines (PL). A food poverty line was calculated based on the subsistence expenditure per (equivalent) capita in 2008 (anchored), following the methodology proposed by WHO (Xu &
TE D
World Health Organization/Department of Health System Financing, 2005), and it was estimated at 2,620.64 euros. A relative poverty line was estimated as the 60% of the median per capita consumption expenditure in 2008 (anchored), a definition that
EP
has been historically used in the EU to identify people at-risk-of-poverty and it is part
AC C
of the Europe 2020 Strategy (Bradshaw & Mayhew, 2011); it was calculated at 9,365.99 euros (pre-payment poverty line). In the case of relative poverty lines, an amount should be subtracted from the estimated (pre-payment) poverty line to arrive at the post-payment poverty line, as the pre-payment poverty line indirectly allows for resources required to cover healthcare needs. A partial solution is to deduct from the poverty line the average health spending of households with total expenditure in the region of the poverty line (O'Donnell et al., 2008; Wagstaff & Doorslaer, 2003). Therefore, the post-payment relative poverty line was set at 9,057.35 euros. 13
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT As suggested by O'Donnell et al. (2008), the poverty impact of OOPP can be measured by adjusting indicators from the general poverty literature to the concept of impoverishment due to OOPP, namely to compare poverty estimates before and after OOPP.
gross health payments individual headcount ratio is:
8$699
=
∑
:; ∑ :
8$699
= 1 if xi < PL and is 0 otherwise, si is the household size and N is the
SC
Where ;
8$699 567
RI PT
Let xi be the equivalised total expenditure of household ith. Then, an estimate of the
given by replacing ;
8$699
M AN U
number of households in the sample. The net of health payments headcount
<= 567
is
with ;<= = 1 if xi – OOPPi < PL (and 0 otherwise). The
poverty headcount refers to the proportion of individuals living below the poverty line.
8$699
( ? − @ ), then the mean gap in currency units is:
EP
;
TE D
Let the gross health payments individual-level poverty gap given by: > 8$699 = A 8$699 =
∑ : > 8$699 ∑ :
AC C
The poverty gap expresses the mean expenditure shortfall of poor individuals from the poverty line in reference to the total population. The net of health payments poverty gap A <= is calculated by replacing >
8$699
with ><= = ;<= ( ? − (@ −
)).
To enable comparisons across countries with different poverty lines and currency units, the poverty gap can be normalised as: A 8$699 =
14
A 8$699 ?
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT The post-payment normalised gap
A <= .
A <= can be defined by replacing A 8$699 with
The intensity of poverty for poor individuals alone can be estimated with the mean
positive poverty gap (MPG); the MPG can be normalised on the poverty line (NMPG)
RI PT
as well.
The poverty impact of OOPP is simply defined as the difference between the relevant pre–and post–payment measures, e.g. the impoverishing headcount is given by −
8$699 567 ,
<= and the impoverishing gap by / C = A567 − A567 .
SC
3.2.3.
<= 567
Vulnerability
8$699
M AN U
/B =
Furthermore, we explored the determinants of a) catastrophic and b) impoverishing (relative poverty) health payments employing binary logistic regression analysis. The study specifies a logistic regression model of the form:
(F) ) = GH + GI JI 1 − (F)
TE D
ln (
Where P(y) is the probability of a household sustaining catastrophe due to OOPP, bo
EP
is a constant, X is a vector of k independent variables and bk is the vector of the coefficients. Analogously is specified the model with impoverishment as the
AC C
dependent variable. Following previous studies (Abu-Zaineh et al., 2013; Buigut et al., 2015; Kronenberg & Barros, 2014; Özgen Narcı et al., 2015; Van Minh et al., 2013; Yardim et al., 2010), we assumed that the odds for each model were driven by a set of household characteristics, i.e. household size, region and urbanicity, insurance (social and private) status of household, socioeconomic group (equivalent total expenditure quintiles), presence of at least one senior (≥65 years), junior (children under 5) and unable to work member in the household, as well as some features of the household head, namely age, gender, education level and economic activity status. As 15
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT no health variables were available, incapacity to work was considered a proxy for disability (Kronenberg & Barros, 2014). These independent variables were identified in the literature, and no specific hypotheses regarding their effect were tested, hence, all explanatory variables were entered simultaneously into the Logit models.
RI PT
However, it was expected that factors associated with greater health needs (e.g. higher age, presence of seniors, children and disabled members) would increase the likelihood of households being exposed to financial risk, more so in the case of conditions
(Abegunde
&
Stanciole,
2008).
Furthermore,
higher
SC
chronic
socioeconomic status (e.g. consumption, education) and risk pooling mechanisms
M AN U
(social and private insurance, higher household size) could act protectively against financial risk in situations of ill-health, while the relationship between the socioeconomic determinants and health is also well-established (Marmot, 2007). The above model was calculated separately for 2008 and 2015 for both catastrophe and
TE D
impoverishment. We tested the equality of the coefficients between 2008 and 2015 with the Wald test, after combining the estimates of the two years for each model with the command suest of STATA. Results are reported as odds ratios (ORs).
EP
Statistical significance was set at α = 0.05 for all of examinations, but other levels are
AC C
reported as well. The statistical analysis was conducted with SPSS v.24 and STATA v.14.
4. Results 4.1. CHE
The descriptive statistics of the weighted data can be found in Table S3 in the online Appendix. Table 1 presents the evolution of expenditures across the period of 20082015. Equivalised total consumption demonstrates a constant downward trend up until 2014, while in 2015 a slight increase is observed, registering an overall reduction of 16
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 35.7% in the period examined. OOPP are decreasing during the first years of the crisis, but from 2012 onwards a steady increase is observed (23.5% overall reduction). As far as the main components are concerned, medical products and inpatient care increased by 20.2% and 63%, respectively, while outpatient expenses showed a
RI PT
significant reduction of 62%. Pharmaceutical spending, which is the major driver of expenses in medical products, is gradually rising starting 2012. Households’ CTP registered a huge decline of 42.4%, reflecting the substantial downward course of
SC
total consumption. The aforementioned changes resulted in the rise of the average OOPP share of households’ CTP from 6.9% to 7.8%. Disaggregating these estimates
M AN U
by expenditure quintiles revealed that OOPP of the poorest households decreased by 13.8% during the crisis, which ensued from the reduction of outpatient (-44%) and medical products (-4.3%) expenses (see Table S4 in online appendix); inpatient payments rose significantly in relative terms (116.9%), however their relative
TE D
importance was quite small in the poorest strata (15.5% of OOPP in 2015). All the other quintiles were associated with increases in OOPP, which appear to be higher in wealthier households (45% overall rise in the fifth quintile); these are driven by the
EP
upward trend primarily in inpatient outlays, which significantly expanded their share
AC C
in all groups, and to a much lesser extent in medical products. An upsurge in the incidence of CHE is recorded for all thresholds in 2015 compared with 2008 (Tables 2-5). Α de-escalation was occurring until 2011, which was followed by a stronger opposite trend, while a halt is observed in 2015 for the 40% level. The increase in the incidence of CHE has been mainly absorbed by households in the middle expenditure quintiles at the lower thresholds, while the richest households are getting more exposure to financial risk at the higher thresholds (see Tables S5-8 in online Appendix) The poorest households are associated with a relative decrease for all
17
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT thresholds since the onset of the crisis, though an ascending trend is apparent as of 2012. Nevertheless, the incidence of CHE was generally more concentrated in poorer households, as it is shown by the persistently negative values of CIs and the higher than one values of the quintile ratios, more so when applying the 10-30% thresholds.
RI PT
In general, inequality in the incidence of CHE fluctuated over time, however, it appears to be significantly decreasing in the recent years. Hence, whereas the estimates of the weighted headcounts, which incorporates the inequality impact, were
SC
higher than the unweighted measures, their overall increase was smaller during the crisis.
M AN U
Concerning the average intensity of CHE, mean overshoot was higher in 2015 in relation to 2008 at the 10-30% levels, while the estimate was found equal at the highest threshold. A downward trend was noted between 2009 and 2011, which was succeeded by a reverse course from 2012 onwards for all levels, albeit the break in the
TE D
trend was delayed for a couple of years for the 40% threshold. The poorest households were again associated with an overall decrease, and the main bulk of the escalation was rested on the shoulders of the higher expenditure quintiles, (see Tables
EP
S5-8 in online Appendix). Economically disadvantaged households were typically
AC C
associated with a higher mean overshoot in the first years of the crisis, which implies that they were not only more likely to exceed the CHE thresholds, but they also spent more above the threshold relative to the better-off. However, a considerable reduction in inequality is discernible over the course of the period, especially at the highest thresholds, as the signs have even been reversed, implying that overshoot is now burdening more the wealthier strata. This is mirrored in the lower estimates of the weighted overshoot in relation to the unweighted measure, which, consequently,
18
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT registered a decrease between 2008 and 2015, with the exception of the lowest threshold. The abovementioned results of overshoot are driven by changes in the headcount as well as in the mean positive overshoot measure, which expresses the average
RI PT
overshoot only for households whose OOPP exceeded the pre-specified budget threshold, i.e. the intensity of financial risk. We notice an overall decrease in the mean values for almost all thresholds between 2008 and 2015. This was mainly the outcome
SC
of a large decline occurring in 2015, which followed a significant rise in the previous
M AN U
year. Inequality was also found to fluctuate, being quite small in most instances. Table 6 presents the evolution of FFCI between 2008 and 2015. The FFCI showed a gradual improvement up until 2012, while afterwards the trend was reversed indicating an aggravation of the inequality in the OOPP burden. In 2015, we again notice an increase in the index.
TE D
4.2.Poverty and impoverishment
When using the subsistence poverty line, pre– and post–payment poverty headcounts
EP
were estimated at only 0.62% and 0.68% of the population, respectively, in 2015, recording a small gradual increase in absolute terms since 2008 (Table 7). The share
AC C
of people impoverished due to OOPP was about the same in 2015 compared with 2008 (0.05% vs. 0.06%, respectively), but it varied in the interim period, probably exhibiting an upward trend from 2012 onwards. As the poverty line was quite low, the normalised gross and net health spending poverty gaps were negligible, which also applies to the poverty impact of OOPP. The normalised mean positive poverty gap, which measures the mean poverty gap only for individuals being below the poverty line (as a share of the poverty line), exhibited a considerable increase in 2015, albeit it varied significantly in the previous years, as was also the case with the respective 19
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT impact of OOPP. Finally, concerning the contributors of total poverty gap, we cannot discern a clear trend, as the magnitude fluctuated over time. As far as the relative poverty is concerned, 47.1% and 49% of the sample were living in poverty before and after OOPP, respectively, in 2015, exhibiting a gradual increase
RI PT
since the onset of the crisis, which accumulated to an overall growth of 240.92% and 230.9%, respectively, in the estimates. The share of people impoverished as a result of health spending decreased between 2010 and 2011, but a significant ascending trend
SC
is noticed from 2012 onwards. The overall impoverishment impact was 1.88% in 2015, i.e. it was larger by 90.5% in relation to the beginning of the crisis. The
M AN U
magnitude would have been even greater, but a significant share of the people pushed below the poverty line was matched by those leaving it, as a result of the lower postpayment poverty line that was applied. The normalised poverty gap gradually increased over time, and it reached 12.8% and 13.4% of the pre– and post-payment
TE D
poverty lines in 2015, recording a rise of 318.4% and 263.6%, respectively, since 2008. The respective impact of OOPP showed a downward trend between 2010 and 2012, which was reversed in the following years, resulting in a net 61.2% growth at
EP
the end of the period relative to its onset. The mean distance of poor people from the
AC C
poverty lines is gradually expanding between 2010 and 2014, while a small decline is observed in 2015, reaching the levels of 27.2% and 27.4% of the pre– and post– payment poverty lines, respectively, at the end of the period. On the other hand, the impact of health spending on the intensity of poverty fluctuated over time, though it appears to be increasing starting 2012. Finally, the overall poverty impact of health spending also appears to escalate as of 2012, as we can discern from the descending tendency in the contribution of pre-payment poverty gap to the overall poverty magnitude.
20
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 4.3.Vulnerability Table 8 displays the results concerning the determinants of households incurring CHE at the 40% threshold (see Table S9 in online Appendix for the other levels). The region of household did not affect, ceteris paribus, the likelihood of CHE
RI PT
significantly in almost all cases. However, it is noteworthy that numerically the ORs were reversed in 2015, i.e. families residing in Attica had on average higher chances of catastrophe in relation to the other regions. On the other hand, more densely
SC
populated areas appear to be associated with lower financial risk, with the effect
M AN U
achieving statistical significance at the lower thresholds.
Larger households were less likely to sustain financial catastrophe due to health spending in both years, though it appears that the protective effect is losing weight in 2015, at the lower thresholds in particular, as it is rendered insignificant. Having an elderly in the household was associated with significantly higher likelihood of CHE in
TE D
2015, and the change in the effect established statistical significance; a similar result is observed concerning the age of the household head. The presence of juniors was also linked with higher risk of CHE, though it was found more moderate in 2015.
EP
Female-headed households had lower chances of financial risk with respect to men,
AC C
but the ORs were not significant. Higher education level of the breadwinner operates as an important protective mechanism against catastrophe, regardless the threshold and the year of the estimation. It appears that its shielding action was enhanced in 2015, though the change in its effect was not significant. Notably, concerning the economic activity of household heads, the ORs were reversed in 2015, as employed household heads were now associated with higher likelihood of financial risk compared with the other statuses. However, the coefficients (and their change) did not generally establish 21
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT statistical significance in 2015, with the exception of the pensioners at the highest threshold. Households of higher expenditure quintile were found significantly more likely to face catastrophe due to OOPP in 2015. Notably, the difference in the odds was
RI PT
increased from 2008 in most instances, at the lower thresholds in particular.
Social and private insurance didn’t affect significantly the likelihood of CHE. However, notably, all cases of CHE are observed in the partially (7 cases) and fully
SC
(77 cases) socially insured households at the 40% threshold, while just one case of
M AN U
catastrophe is found in the partially and fully privately insured households. Finally, having a disable member was associated with higher odds of catastrophe, with the impact being particularly pronounced at the lower thresholds.
Regarding impoverishment due to OOPP in relative poverty, households belonging to the lower-middle expenditure group, residing in rural areas or with an elderly member
TE D
were, ceteris paribus, significantly linked with higher likelihood of being impoverished in 2015, while richer households presented considerable lower
EP
probability (Table 9). It is also worth noting that household heads with postsecondary (non-tertiary) education level, older or unemployed were also facing lower
AC C
odds of catastrophe. Comparing the changes in the effects between 2008 and 2015, only the reversal of the odds of lower education levels established statistical significance.
5. Discussion
To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study exploring the progression of change in financial protection of Greek households against OOPP during the economic crisis. In general, the catastrophic character of OOPP was considerably exacerbated in terms of both incidence and average intensity (overshoot), and there is 22
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT indication that the impact will continue to aggravate. This was particularly evident in the lower thresholds, where the increase in the headcount was 31.8% and 22.8% for the 10% and 20% thresholds, respectively, in relative terms during the crisis, while at the higher levels the rise was more moderate. In 2015, 1.2% of the households in the
RI PT
sample were exposed to financial risk due to OOPP at the 40% threshold. This implies that about 110,000 individuals in the general population in Greece were living in households spending more than 40% of their CTP to OOPP, at the possible expense of
SC
other basic necessities. This growth was mainly driven by the new cost-shifting policies adopted from 2010 and later, as the contraction of households’ CTP has been
M AN U
slowing down following 2012 (see Figure 1 & Table 1). However, it appears that the additional burden has been distributed somewhat progressively, as it is indicated by the decreasing estimates of (relative) inequality indices, which have even been reversed at the highest CTP thresholds, implying a higher burden for the wealthier
TE D
strata. Overall, it can be deduced that (both relative and absolute) inequalities in financial risk have been mitigated in the recent years. This is also reflected in the estimates of FFCI, which focuses on inequalities in the budget shares allocated to
EP
OOPP, as the decrease observed in the years 2013-2014 is succeeded by an
AC C
improvement in 2015.
Food poverty has increased significantly in relative terms since the onset of the crisis, but its incidence still remains at very low levels, indicating that the vast majority of people were able to cover their basic food needs. The intensity of food poverty fluctuated over time, and we cannot safely assume its overall trend, though a substantial increase was recorded at the end of the period. The findings concerning the anchored relative poverty are less ambiguous. The incidence of relative poverty recorded a significant growth of more than 230%, reaching the substantial levels of
23
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 47.1% and 49% regarding the pre– and post–payment headcounts, respectively in 2015; the mean distance from the poverty line increased by about 20% in the same period. Furthermore, both the incidence and intensity were associated with a considerable rise following 2012, which probably reflects the changes in cost-sharing
RI PT
policies. The overall poverty impact of OOPP also appears to be exacerbating starting 2012. In 2015, 1.9% of the sample was impoverished due to OOPP, which corresponds to over 200,000 people, if we extrapolate to the total population in
SC
Greece.
The aforementioned results were driven by the significant increases in pharmaceutical
M AN U
and inpatient OOPP, while outpatient household expenses decreased considerably. Data from EOPYY showed that the average cost-sharing for pharmaceuticals rose from 13.3% in 2012 to 18% in 2013 (Siskou et al., 2014). Another study in private pharmacies in central Greece indicated an increase in the mean percentage rate of
TE D
patient contributions by 157.8% and in the average patient charge per prescription by 65.2% between 2011 and 2014, despite price reductions in the same period (Gouvalas et al., 2016). Furthermore, current prescribing rules do not appear to effectively
EP
prompt physicians to prescribe generics, and at the same time Greek patients are also
AC C
sceptical concerning the use of generic drugs, though economic incentives do exist (Economou, 2015; Yfantopoulos et al., 2016). Owing to the diachronic lack of credible primary healthcare, the outpatient care in Greece is greatly depended on the private sector, often leading to supplier-induced demand (Siskou et al., 2008). Between 2009 and 2013, visits to public hospital outpatient departments and afternoon surgeries decreased by 8.2% and 26.4%, which could at least partly be attributed to the increases in user charges (Economou, 2015). Patients may decide to delay or refrain from necessary first-contact healthcare 24
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT utilisation due to the double financial burden of the economic crisis and co-payments. It is quite worrisome that the percentage of individuals reporting unmet medical examination needs due to barriers of access has risen from 5.4% to 12.3% between 2008 and 2015 (see Table S10 in online Appendix). Furthermore, demand of
RI PT
emergency services has increased in the recent years, which may be explained by the absence of any co-payments at the point of service, unlike outpatient care (Economou et al., 2014).
SC
Patient admissions to public hospitals have increased since the beginning of the crisis (Economou, 2015). However, the substantial shrinkage of human and material
M AN U
resources and quality deterioration may have forced some insured patients to the private healthcare sector, where private providers have incentives to raise their revenues, and patients face a significant informational disadvantage (Grigorakis et al., 2016). Moreover, EOPYY imposes to private hospitalisations of insured individuals a
TE D
statutory co–insurance rate of 30% or 50% (depending on their former social security carrier) on Greek DRG’s total cost (3054/18.11.2012, Gazette of the Government). The reimbursement policy does not encompass the productive factor labor, which
EP
results in high direct (formal and informal) fees paid by the health users at the point of
AC C
service (Grigorakis et al., 2016). The structural problems within the Greek health system, such as long queues, lack of information management systems, insufficient financial management and accounting processes, limited administrative capacity, lacking monitoring mechanisms, large number of physicians, and a pricing and remuneration policy unrelated to performance have fostered a pervasive culture of informal or under-the-table payments from patients to healthcare professionals in Greece (Economou, 2015). This phenomenon is primarily related to requesting preferential treatment, including bypassing waiting lists or ensuring better quality of
25
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT service and more attention from physicians. There are reports of increased informal payments in the recent years in the presence of expanded demand and scarcer resources in public hospitals, as public health servants may seek to offset lost revenues from the across-the-board salary cuts (Economou, 2015; European
RI PT
Commission, 2017).
It is difficult to compare findings in CHE in view of the extensive methodological heterogeneity. A study using the Greek HBS of 1998-1999 estimated that 2.44% of
SC
households assigned more than 40% of their CTP to healthcare payments, with 67% of them incurring OOPP (Economou et al., 2004), while Murray et al. (2003)
M AN U
calculated the incidence of CHE due to OOPP at 2.17% employing the same data. Furthermore, there is evidence of a significant increase in chronic patients sustaining CHE between 2012-2013, mainly owing to pharmaceutical OOPP (Skroumpelos et al., 2014), while Grigorakis et al. (2016) demonstrated the considerable catastrophic
TE D
impact of inpatient OOPP. Concerning peer countries, the incidence of CHE at 40% of CTP in Greece (0.8%) in 2010 was equal to that of Denmark’s, much lower than in Poland (8.8%), and higher than in Germany (0.4%) (Zawada et al., 2016). For the
EP
same year, the occurrence of CHE in Portugal was smaller than in Greece for all
AC C
thresholds (Quintal & Lopes, 2016), while a similar comparison favoured Turkey for the 20-40% levels (Özgen Narcı et al., 2015). Concerning vulnerability, it was demonstrated that factors affect differently the financial risk and impoverishment due to OOPP. In general, households of higher size, lower expenditure quintile, residing in urban areas, without disabled, elderly or very young children members, and with younger or retired, better-educated breadwinners were, ceteris paribus, significantly less vulnerable to CHE in 2015. Overall, the effects of some determinants strengthen (elderly, education level, 26
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT expenditure quintile, retirement status, household size) at higher thresholds, while others are weakened (disabled, children), which supports the need for exploration of multiple levels. The analysis of CHE is based on the assumption that OOPP are involuntary consumption not contributing to household welfare, which doesn’t hold
RI PT
perfectly (Moreno-Serra et al., 2013). Applying higher thresholds increases the likelihood that health spending exceeding this limit is indeed not discretionary, while it also attaches more weight to those households facing greater burden (Saksena et al.,
SC
2014). Moreover, CHE are driven by different items of OOPP as the threshold
Figure S4 in online appendix).
M AN U
changes, namely inpatient care increases its share of OOPP at higher levels (see
Regarding impoverishment due to OOPP, households belonging to the lower-middle expenditure quintile, located in rural regions and with elderly members were, ceteris paribus, facing higher risk, while wealthier families exhibited considerable lower
TE D
likelihood of financial hardship. The higher vulnerability of the lower-middle group compared with the poorest is reasonable as impoverishment examines the lower-tail of the expenditure distribution and many households were already living in poverty.
EP
Furthermore, it is also worth noting that the economic crisis induced a severe
AC C
downward economic mobility, especially for salaried employees of the middle class, along with significant reductions in social transfers as part of the economic adjustment programmes (Karanikolos et al., 2013). On the other hand, wealthier households being associated with a higher risk of CHE may be misleading concerning the actual situation in financial protection in Greece. This is because it may hide financial barriers to healthcare use for disadvantaged groups, as it was mentioned earlier, or not account for the coping strategies (e.g. selling assets or borrowing) temporarily increasing income and masking the present or long-term financial
27
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT hardship (Van Doorslaer et al., 2007). In this regard, there are studies advocating the use of progressive thresholds, which define catastrophe as a function of a household’s rank in the income distribution (Ataguba, 2012; Kwesiga et al., 2015). Providing universal coverage is a necessary, but not a sufficient condition to prevent
RI PT
catastrophic and impoverishing medical spending. Access to healthcare in Greece is largely dependent upon employment (Karanikolos & Kentikelenis, 2016). A large share of the Greek population is left without healthcare coverage during the crisis, as
SC
unemployment rates have skyrocketed (27.5% in 2013) and many individuals have discontinued contribution payments due to financial difficulties (Economou, 2015).
M AN U
Unemployment has been associated with increased health problems owing to psychological issues, unhealthy behaviour and reduced financial resources to support a healthy living and cope with ill-health (Karanikolos et al., 2013). Until the standardisation of the benefits package, the healthcare coverage of the uninsured was
TE D
different across funds and largely temporary. Only those with very low income holding a poverty booklet were entitled to continued free access to healthcare services (Economou et al., 2015). There are reports of health providers unofficially providing
EP
healthcare to uninsured patients in recent years, though not in a systematic manner
AC C
(European Commission & Economic Policy Committee, 2016), while some municipalities, NGOs and other unofficial networks of health professionals and volunteers provide primary health services free-of-charge, with their role growing with time (Economou, 2015; Karanikolos & Kentikelenis, 2016). The Greek government has adopted some measures to facilitate access to healthcare for uninsured individuals, including a health-voucher programme (September 2013October 2015) to grant access to primary healthcare, which was followed by the provision of universal coverage of primary care for all citizens (February 2014) and 28
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT entitlements to secondary health services (free of charge) as well as pharmaceuticals (same co-payments as the insured) for the uninsured and their families (June 2014). However, these measures were of limited success in terms of access, mainly due to high co-payments for medicines, stigmatizing procedures, bureaucratic barriers,
RI PT
insufficient public information and inadequate implementation by the providers (Economou et al., 2014; Kentikelenis, 2015). More recently (2016), a social bill was enacted addressing some of the shortcomings of the existing scheme, while it also
SC
expanded coverage to refugees and other vulnerable groups (European Commission & Economic Policy Committee, 2016). However, the effectiveness of these policies is
M AN U
yet to be determined.
Expanding insurance coverage does not automatically improve financial protection against ill-health, as the insured, once inside the system, are subject to costs from which their insurance fails to protect them (Wagstaff et al., 2009). Furthermore, the
TE D
underfunded and already overloaded system will be unable to respond to the additional strain arising from the health effects of the crisis. Evidence is already accruing concerning the deterioration of population health in Greece primarily in the
EP
form of worsening general health, increased psychological problems and suicide
AC C
attempts, while budget cuts in prevention and treatment programmes have led to the emergence of several public health issues (e.g. HIV outbreak and increase in the incidence of tuberculosis among drug users) (Chantzaras & Yfantopoulos, 2017; Karanikolos & Kentikelenis, 2016; Karanikolos et al., 2013; Kentikelenis et al., 2014). This can only induce further compromises in the quality of service at the expense of all beneficiaries, some of which will be compelled to shift to the private sector, increasing the likelihood of incurring CHE. In other words, this situation may promote a de facto two-tiered health system, where those with sufficient resources
29
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT will be able to afford private healthcare and meet their health needs, while economically weak individuals will access health services from a severely strained public system (Economou, 2015). The aforementioned situation is already evident in our estimates of inpatient out-of-
RI PT
pocket spending, as it has more than quadrupled in the richest expenditure quintile (from €368.31 to €1690.12 between 2008 and 2015) during the crisis, while in the
€33.55 to €72.78 see Table S4 in online appendix).
SC
poorest the increase is more moderate in both absolute and relative terms (from
M AN U
It is expected even in countries with advanced welfare states that households should contribute financially to their healthcare at least to some extent, as it’s a way of demand and cost restraining (Kronenberg & Barros, 2014; Yardim et al., 2010). It is the over-reliance on OOPP that puts at risk households’ standard of living, while it also restricts access to adequate healthcare for the poor (Van Doorslaer et al., 2007;
TE D
Wagstaff, 2007). OOPP is a quite regressive way to finance healthcare, as it increases the financial risk and barriers of healthcare access especially for the most vulnerable groups, such as lower socioeconomic status families, especially in the presence of
EP
senior, chronically ill and not employed members as well as undocumented migrants
AC C
and homeless people (Karanikolos & Kentikelenis, 2016). Some recent measures are certainly in the right direction and will enhance both the access and the resilience of economically disadvantaged households to the economic shocks of ill-health. However, typically, social legislation doesn’t take into consideration the significant financial effect of involuntary health payments. Hence, there are substantial numbers of people (hidden poor), in the lower-middle incomes particularly, barely failing to meet the preconditions of the respective provisions. Cost-sharing policies should, therefore, recognise the different social protection needs of households in the current 30
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT economic predicament. In this context, converting the employment contributionsbased social insurance scheme to a tax-based one, especially in the presence of persistently high unemployment rates, could be a more progressive financing strategy (Grigorakis et al., 2016).
RI PT
As Thomson et al. (2015) point out, in the face of fiscal pressures in the health sector, policymakers may adopt strategies to enhance efficiency, to cut spending and restrict coverage, and to mobilise additional revenue. Initial policy responses in Greece were
SC
mainly based on easily implemented funding cuts and cost-shifting strategies, neglecting much needed, but politically troublesome to enforce, policy changes to
M AN U
improve the efficiency of the health system. The citizen/patient side and the equitable provision of high-quality health services was largely ignored (Economou et al., 2015). Focus on spending cuts may result in implicit or explicit rationing of healthcare resources, with adverse effects on healthcare access, financial protection and public
TE D
satisfaction, and even larger inefficiencies and an unintended health impact in the longer term (Thomson et al., 2015). The allocation of financial resources to the public healthcare system to improve the quality of provided services would certainly benefit
EP
the access of the worse-off groups in particular. However, caught between Scylla and
AC C
Charybdis, Greek government’s only viable policy path is to prioritise the enhancement of the health system’s efficiency, while also implementing strategies that insulate the most vulnerable groups from the financial risks of health shocks. Some general approaches to promote efficiency in the Greek setting could be the implementation of health technology assessment (HTA), addressing the fragmentation in pooling, purchasing and service delivery, cost-reducing substitution, reducing waste, improving efficiency and quality in service delivery, restricting induced demand and combating corruption (Thomson et al., 2015). The importance of HTA
31
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT should be highlighted, as its enactment may discard less cost-effective medical technologies, which will serve the financial protection of the most vulnerable groups in particular (Łuczak & García-Gómez, 2012); HTA of reimbursed drugs was instituted in Greece in mid-January 2018, however it is still not operational (May
RI PT
2018).
Moreover, the Greek DRG’s pricing and reimbursement system needs to be revised to reflect the higher international price levels, which may reduce the direct OOPP of
SC
health consumers (Grigorakis et al., 2016). This might lead to increased social security contributions, nevertheless, the enhanced risk pooling will serve the financial
M AN U
protection of the deprived population against health shocks. Finally, implementing policies that better encourage the prescription and dispense of generics will lessen the financial burden related to co-payments for citizens.
There were some limitations in our study. First, we used cross-sectional data, which
TE D
cannot detect the specific welfare changes following ill-health (Wagstaff, 2007). It is difficult to identify the coping mechanisms of the households incurring CHE, and whether medical expenses were financed through sacrificing current consumption or
EP
through drawing on savings, the sale of assets or credit, borrowing or through
AC C
transfers from social networks (Van Doorslaer et al., 2007). Second, households afflicted with health shocks that could not afford the treatment and did not proceed in the necessary purchase of medical care were not considered in the analysis (O'Donnell et al., 2008). Third, this approach doesn’t distinct between types of medical care purchased, namely whether it corresponded to actual health needs as well its quality (Van Doorslaer et al., 2007). Fourth, other significant determinants of catastrophic and impoverishing health payments were omitted from the risk analysis, with the most notable being the health status of households’ members. Nevertheless, the framework 32
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT of the WHO which we employed in this study determines financial fairness independently of the healthcare utilisation and health status of the individual (Murray et al., 2000). Fifth, as in all similar studies, it was assumed that reduced resources owing to OOPP has a direct negative impact on household’s welfare. However,
RI PT
medical spending may also increase household health stock and improve future productivity (Séne & Cissé, 2015). 6. Conclusions
SC
In summary, the catastrophic and impoverishing impact of OOPP appears to have
M AN U
been aggravated during the economic crisis, and there is indication that it will continue to exacerbate in the forthcoming years. This is induced by the simultaneous effect of households’ diminishing’ CTP and the increased OOPP burden, which ensued from the recently implemented reforms as part of the economic adjustment programmes. Our study also provided evidence that vulnerability to financial risk
TE D
(CHE) differs from that of financial hardship (impoverishment), and that policy interest regarding families with increased health needs and of lower socioeconomic status should go together with specific considerations for the hidden poor of the
EP
lower-middle economic class. Myopic budget cuts and cost-shifting rather than
AC C
focusing on health system’s efficiency and effectiveness can only worsen barriers of healthcare access and, presumably, morbidity in the Greek population. In turn, this will put more pressure on public healthcare finances in the long-term, not to mention the potential social cost in human lives. Effective social protection policies should promote risk-pooling instead of OOPP. Financial fairness is not only a desired outcome from a normative perspective, but it may also improve healthcare access and, consequently, health outcomes.
33
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT References Abegunde, D.O., Stanciole, A.E., (2008). The economic impact of chronic diseases: how do households respond to shocks? Evidence from Russia. Social Science & Medicine 66 (11), 2296-2307. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socscimed.2008.01.041.
RI PT
Abu-Zaineh, M., Romdhane, H.B., Ventelou, B., Moatti, J.P., Chokri, A., (2013). Appraising financial protection in health: The case of Tunisia. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics 13 (1), 73-93. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-
SC
013-9123-8.
M AN U
Ataguba, J.E.O., (2012). Reassessing catastrophic health-care payments with a Nigerian case study. Health Economics, Policy and Law 7 (3), 309-326. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744133110000356.
Bradshaw, J., Mayhew, E., (2011). The measurement of extreme poverty in the
Inclusion, Brussels.
TE D
European Union. European Commission, DG Employment, Social Affairs and
Buigut, S., Ettarh, R., Amendah, D.D., (2015). Catastrophic health expenditure and its
EP
determinants in Kenya slum communities. International Journal for Equity in Health 14 (1), 46. https://doi.org/10.1186/s12939-015-0168-9.
AC C
Castles, F.G., (2010). Black swans and elephants on the move: the impact of emergencies on the welfare state. Journal of European Social Policy 20 (2), 91-101. https://doi.org/10.1177/0958928709358793. Chantzaras, A., Yfantopoulos, J., (2017). The Effects Of The Economic Crisis On Health Status And Health Inequalities In Greece. Value in Health 20 (9), A510. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2017.08.630.
34
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Economou, C., (2010). Greece: Health system review. Health systems in transition 12 (7),
1-180.
http://www.euro.who.int/__data/assets/pdf_file/0004/130729/e94660.pdf?ua=1. Economou, C., (2015). Barriers and facilitating factors in access to health services in
RI PT
Greece. World Health Organization Regional Office for Europe, Copenhagen.
Economou, C., Kaitelidou, D., Katsikas, D., Siskou, O., Zafiropoulou, M., (2014). Impacts of the economic crisis on access to healthcare services in Greece with a focus
SC
on the vulnerable groups of the population. Social Cohesion and Development 9 (2),
M AN U
99-115. http://www.epeksa.gr/assets/variousFiles/file_1.Economou-Kaitelidou.pdf. Economou, C., Kaitelidou, D., Kentikelenis, A., Maresso, A., Sissouras, A. (2015). The impact of the financial crisis on the health system and health in Greece. In A. Maresso, P. Mladovsky, S. Thomson, A. Sagan, M. Karanikolos, E. Richardson, et al. (Eds.), Economic crisis, health systems and health in Europe: country experience.
TE D
WHO Regional Office for Europe/European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies Copenhagen. pp. 117-161.
EP
Economou, C., Karabli, E., Geitona, M., Kyriopoulos, J. (2004). Fairness of health financing in the Greek health care sector.
Proceedings of the 8th International
AC C
Conference on System Science in Health Care. Geneva: University of Geneva. pp. 411-415.
European Commission, (2017). Updated Study on Corruption in the Healthcare Sector Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg. European Commission, Economic Policy Committee. (2016). Joint Report on Health Care and Long-Term Care Systems & Fiscal Sustainability vol. 2. Economy Institutional Papers Luxembourg.
35
European
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Eurostat,
(2017).
Eurostat
online
database.
http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/lfs/data/database (accessed 08.07.2017). Gouvalas, A., Igoumenidis, M., Theodorou, M., Athanasakis, K., (2016). Cost-sharing rates increase during deep recession: Preliminary data from Greece. International of
Health
Policy
and
Management
http://dx.doi.org/10.15171/ijhpm.2016.62.
5
(12),
687-692.
RI PT
Journal
Grigorakis, N., Floros, C., Tsangari, H., Tsoukatos, E., (2016). Out of pocket
SC
payments and social health insurance for private hospital care: Evidence from Greece.
M AN U
Health Policy 120 (8), 948-959. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2016.06.011. Karakolias, S.E., Polyzos, N.M., (2014). The Newly Established Unified Healthcare Fund (EOPYY): Current Situation and Proposed Structural Changes, towards an Upgraded Model of Primary Health Care, in Greece. Health 6 (9), 809-821. http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/health.2014.69103.
Greece.
TE D
Karanikolos, M., Kentikelenis, A., (2016). Health inequalities after austerity in International
Journal
for
Equity
in
Health
15
(1).
EP
http://dx.doi.org/10.1186/s12939-016-0374-0. Karanikolos, M., Mladovsky, P., Cylus, J., Thomson, S., Basu, S., Stuckler, D., et al.,
AC C
(2013). Financial crisis, austerity, and health in Europe. The Lancet 381 (9874), 13231331. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(13)60102-6. Kentikelenis, A., (2015). Bailouts, austerity and the erosion of health coverage in Southern Europe and Ireland. European Journal of Public Health 25 (3), 365-366. https://doi.org/10.1093/eurpub/ckv055. Kentikelenis, A., Karanikolos, M., Reeves, A., McKee, M., Stuckler, D., (2014). Greece's health crisis: From austerity to denialism. The Lancet 383 (9918), 748-753. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(13)62291-6. 36
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Kronenberg, C., Barros, P.P., (2014). Catastrophic healthcare expenditure - Drivers and
protection:
The
Portuguese
case.
Health
Policy
115
(1),
44-51.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2013.10.001. Kwesiga, B., Zikusooka, C.M., Ataguba, J.E., (2015). Assessing catastrophic and
RI PT
impoverishing effects of health care payments in Uganda. BMC Health Services Research 15 (1), 30. https://doi.org/10.1186/s12913-015-0682-x.
Łuczak, J., García-Gómez, P., (2012). Financial burden of drug expenditures in Health
Policy
105
256-264.
M AN U
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2012.01.004.
(2-3),
SC
Poland.
Marmot, M., (2007). Achieving health equity: from root causes to fair outcomes. The Lancet 370 (9593), 1153-1163. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(07)61385-3. Moreno-Serra, R., Thomson, S., Xu, K. (2013). Measuring and comparing financial protection. In I. Papanicolas, & P.C. Smith (Eds.), Health system performance
TE D
comparison: an agenda for policy, information and research. Open University Press, McGraw-Hill Education, Maidenhead Berkshire, England. pp. 223-254.
EP
Murray, C., Xu, K., Klavus, J., Kawabata, K., Hanvoravongchai, P., Zeramdini, R., et al. (2003). Assessing the distribution of household financial contributions to the
AC C
health system: concepts and empirical application. In C. Murray, & D. Evans (Eds.), Health systems performance assessment: debates, methods and empiricism. World Health Organization, Geneva. pp. 513-531. Murray, C.J., Knaul, F., Musgrove, P., Xu, K., Kawabata, K., (2000). Defining and measuring fairness in financial contribution to the health system. Global Programme on
Evidence
for
Health
Policy.
http://www.who.int/healthinfo/paper24.pdf.
37
Discussion
Paper
Series
24.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT O'Donnell, O., Doorslaer, E.v., Wagstaff, A., Lindelow, M., (2008). Analyzing Health Equity Using Household Survey Data: A Guide to Techniques and Their Implementation. The World Bank, Washington, DC. OECD, (2018). OECD Health Statistics. http://stats.oecd.org/ (accessed 03.01.2018).
RI PT
Özgen Narcı, H., Şahin, İ., Yıldırım, H.H., (2015). Financial catastrophe and poverty impacts of out-of-pocket health payments in Turkey. The European Journal of Health Economics 16, 255-270. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-014-0570-z.
SC
Quintal, C., Lopes, J., (2016). Equity in health care financing in Portugal: Findings
M AN U
from the Household Budget Survey 2010/2011. Health Economics, Policy and Law 11 (3), 233-252. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744133115000419. Saksena, P., Hsu, J., Evans, D.B., (2014). Financial risk protection and universal health coverage: evidence and measurement challenges. PLoS Medicine 11 (9),
TE D
e1001701. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pmed.1001701.
Séne, L.M., Cissé, M., (2015). Catastrophic out-of-pocket payments for health and poverty nexus: evidence from Senegal. International Journal of Health Economics and
EP
Management 15, 307-328. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-015-9170-4. Siskou, O., Kaitelidou, D., Litsa, P., Georgiadou, G., Alexopoulou, H., Paterakis, P.,
AC C
et al., (2014). Investigating the economic impacts of new public pharmaceutical policies in Greece: focusing on price reductions and cost-sharing rates. Value in Health Regional Issues 4, 107-114. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.vhri.2014.07.003. Siskou, O., Kaitelidou, D., Papakonstantinou, V., Liaropoulos, L., (2008). Private health expenditure in the Greek health care system: Where truth ends and the myth begins.
Health
Policy
88
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2008.03.016.
38
(2-3),
282-293.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Skroumpelos, A., Pavi, E., Pasaloglou, S., Kyriopoulos, J., (2014). Catastrophic Health Expenditures and Chronic Condition Patients in Greece. Value in Health 17 (7), A501-A502. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2014.08.1511. Thomson, S., Figueras, J., Evetovits, T., Jowett, M., Mladovsky, P., Maresso, A., et
RI PT
al. (2015). Making sense of health system responses to economic crisis. In S. Thomson, J. Figueras, T. Evetovits, M. Jowett, P. Mladovsky, A. Maresso, et al. (Eds.), Economic Crisis, Health Systems and Health in Europe. Impact and
SC
implications for policy. Open University Press,, Maidenhead, England. pp. 1-16.
M AN U
Van Doorslaer, E., O'Donnell, O., Rannan-Eliya, R.P., Somanathan, A., Adhikari, S.R., Garg, C.C., et al., (2007). Catastrophic payments for health care in Asia. Health economics 16 (11), 1159-1184. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.1209. Van Minh, H., Kim Phuong, N.T., Saksena, P., James, C.D., Xu, K., (2013). Financial burden of household out-of pocket health expenditure in Viet Nam: Findings from the
TE D
National Living Standard Survey 2002-2010. Social Science and Medicine 96, 258263. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socscimed.2012.11.028.
contribution
EP
Wagstaff, A., (2002). Reflections on and alternatives to WHO's fairness of financial index.
Health
economics
11
(2),
103-115.
AC C
https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.685. Wagstaff, A., (2007). The economic consequences of health shocks: evidence from Vietnam.
Journal
of
Health
Economics
26
(1),
82-100.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2006.07.001. Wagstaff, A., Doorslaer, E.v., (2003). Catastrophe and impoverishment in paying for health care: with applications to Vietnam 1993–1998. Health economics 12 (11), 921933. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.776.
39
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Wagstaff, A., Lindelow, M., Jun, G., Ling, X., Juncheng, Q., (2009). Extending health insurance to the rural population: an impact evaluation of China's new cooperative medical
scheme.
Journal
of
Health
Economics
28
(1),
1-19.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2008.10.007.
RI PT
WHO, (2013). The World Health Report 2013. World Health Organization, Luxembourg.
Xu, K., Evans, D.B., Carrin, G., Aguilar-Rivera, A.M., Musgrove, P., Evans, T.,
SC
(2007). Protecting households from catastrophic health spending. Health Affairs 26
M AN U
(4), 972-983. https://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff.26.4.972.
Xu, K., Evans, D.B., Kawabata, K., Zeramdini, R., Klavus, J., Murray, C.J.L., (2003a). Household catastrophic health expenditure: A multicountry analysis. Lancet 362 (9378), 111-117. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(03)13861-5. Xu, K., Klavus, J., Evans, D., Hanvoravongchai, P., Zeramdini, R., Murray, C.
TE D
(2003b). The impact of vertical and horizontal inequality on the fairness in financial contribution index. In C. Murray, & D. Evans (Eds.), Health systems performance
pp. 557-564.
EP
assessment: debates, methods and empiricism. World Health Organization, Geneva.
AC C
Xu, K., World Health Organization/Department of Health System Financing, Expenditure and Resource Allocation, (2005). Distribution of health payments and catastrophic
expenditures
methodology.
FER/EIP
discussion
paper
no
2.
http://www.who.int/iris/handle/10665/69030. Yardim, M.S., Cilingiroglu, N., Yardim, N., (2010). Catastrophic health expenditure and
impoverishment
in
Turkey.
Health
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2009.08.006.
40
Policy
94
(1),
26-33.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Yfantopoulos, J., (2008). Pharmaceutical pricing and reimbursement reforms in Greece.
European
Journal
of
Health
Economics
9
(1),
87-97.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-007-0061-6. Yfantopoulos, J., Chantzaras, A., Constantopoulos, A., (2017). Cost Containment And
The
Memorandums’
Requirements.
Value
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2017.08.622.
in
RI PT
Privatisation Of Pharmaceutical Care In Greece: A Review Of Policy Reforms Under Health
20
(9),
A509.
SC
Yfantopoulos, N., Yfantopoulos, P., Yfantopoulos, J., (2016). Pharmaceutical Policies
M AN U
under Economic Crisis: The Greek case. Journal of Health Policy & Outcomes Research (2), 4-16. http://dx.doi.org/10.7365+/+JHPOR.2016.2.1. Zawada, A., Kolasa, K., Kronborg, C., Rabczenko, D., Rybnik, T., Lauridsen, J.T., et al., (2016). A Comparison of the Burden of Out-of-Pocket Health Payments in
EP
5899.12331.
TE D
Denmark, Germany and Poland. Global Policy. https://doi.org/10.1111/1758-
AC C
Figure 1. Timeline of major reforms in the Greek health system, 2008-2015
Note: GDP, Gross Domestic Product Growth; PUHE, Total public health expenditure per capita at current prices; PRHE, Total private health expenditure per capita at current prices; Poverty, At-risk-of-poverty rate at 60 % of the national median equivalised disposable income (after social transfers); GINI, Gini index; Unempl., unemployment rate. Source of social indicators: Eurostat (2017)
41
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
SC
RI PT
Financial protection of households against health shocks in Greece during the economic crisis
M AN U
Online supplementary Material
AC C
EP
TE D
This Appendix includes information referred to in the full version of the article
1
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
UNIT
Financing schemes
2009
2010
2011
RI PT
Supplementary Table S1 Healthcare expenditure by financing scheme in Greece, 2009-2015
2012
2013
2009-2015 2014
2015
Absolute
Relative
change
change (%)
22,490.9
21,608.7
18,835.7
16,780.9
15,058.5
14,130.9
14,731.9
-7,759.0
-34.5
Total public health expenditure
15,412.2
14,920.9
12,425.3
11,082.8
9,302.9
8,194.7
8,704.5
-6,707.7
-43.5
General government
6,115.4
6,475.4
4,202.3
5,046.5
4,603.1
4,176.5
4,459.5
-1,655.9
-27.1
Social security funds
9,296.8
8,445.4
8,223.1
6,036.3
4,699.8
4,018.2
4,245.0
-5,051.8
-54.3
7,076.6
6,683.7
6,375.6
5,673.7
5,630.9
5,753.6
5,793.8
-1,282.8
-18.1
Private insurance
484.3
605.6
551.8
554.8
509.7
550.7
569.7
85.4
17.6
Household out-of-pocket payments
6,592.3
6,078.0
5,823.8
5,118.9
5,121.2
5,202.9
5,224.1
-1,368.2
-20.8
Rest of the world financing schemes (non-resident)
2.1
4.2
34.8
24.5
124.7
182.6
233.7
231.5
10,869.5
Euro per
Total health expenditure in current prices
2,024.9
1,943.0
1,696.2
1,519.3
1,373.3
1,297.3
1,361.4
-663.5
-32.8
inhabitant
Total public health expenditure
1,387.6
1,341.6
1,118.9
1,003.4
848.4
752.3
804.4
-583.2
-42.0
550.6
582.3
378.4
456.9
419.8
383.4
412.1
-138.5
-25.1
837.0
759.4
740.5
546.5
428.6
368.9
392.3
-444.7
-53.1
637.1
601.0
574.1
513.7
513.5
528.2
535.4
-101.7
-16.0
Social security funds Total private health expenditure
M AN U
TE D
AC C
General government
EP
Total private health expenditure
SC
Total health expenditure in current prices
Million euro
2
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
43.6
54.5
49.7
50.2
46.5
50.6
52.6
9.0
20.7
Household out-of-pocket payments
593.5
546.5
524.4
463.5
467.0
477.7
482.8
-110.8
-18.7
Rest of the world financing schemes (non-resident)
0.2
0.4
3.1
2.2
11.4
16.8
21.6
21.4
11,263.2
Percentage
Total health expenditure in current prices
9.5
9.6
9.1
8.8
8.3
7.9
8.4
-1.1
-11.5
of gross
Total public health expenditure
6.5
6.6
6.0
5.8
5.2
4.6
5.0
-1.5
-23.7
2.0
2.6
2.6
2.4
2.5
0.0
-1.2
SC
RI PT
Private insurance
General government
2.6
2.9
product
Social security funds
3.9
3.7
4.0
3.2
2.6
2.3
2.4
-1.5
-38.1
3.0
3.0
3.1
3.0
3.1
3.2
3.3
0.3
10.4
Private insurance
0.2
0.3
0.3
0.3
0.3
0.3
0.3
0.1
60.0
Household out-of-pocket payments
2.8
2.7
2.8
2.7
2.8
2.9
3.0
0.2
6.8
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1
-
Total public health expenditure
68.5
69.1
66.0
66.0
61.8
58.0
59.1
-9.4
-13.8
27.2
30.0
22.3
30.1
30.6
29.6
30.3
3.1
11.3
41.3
39.1
43.7
36.0
31.2
28.4
28.8
-12.5
-30.3
31.5
30.9
33.9
33.8
37.4
40.7
39.3
7.9
25.0
2.2
2.8
2.9
3.3
3.4
3.9
3.9
1.7
80.0
29.3
28.1
30.9
30.5
34.0
36.8
35.5
6.2
21.0
0.0
0.0
0.2
0.2
0.8
1.3
1.6
1.6
15,800.0
share of
General government
total
Social security funds
current
Total private health expenditure
health
Private insurance
expenditure
Household out-of-pocket payments
(CHE)
TE D
Rest of the world financing schemes (non-resident)
EP
Percentual
Total private health expenditure
AC C
(GDP)
M AN U
domestic
Rest of the world financing schemes (non-resident)
3
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
RI PT
Source: Eurostat, (2017). Eurostat online database. http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/lfs/data/database (accessed 08.07.2017).
Supplementary Table S2 Mean pharmaceutical expenditure as a component of total consumption, OOPP and medical products, 2008-2015
Total
Medical
consumption
OOPP
products
2008
19670.77
1085.66
248.52
2009
19274.71
1064.68
2010
16720.26
904.83
2011
14786.40
809.93
2012
13333.39
731.60
2013
12969.27
773.40
TE D
Pharmaceutical
2014
12609.93
805.36
2015
12649.60
Absolute change 2008-2015
-7021.17
Relative (%) change 2008-
-35.69
Share (%) of pharmaceutical expenditure in: Total
Total
Medical
consumption
OOPP
products
221.24
1.12
20.38
89.03
247.94
214.00
1.11
20.10
86.31
249.59
216.06
1.29
23.88
86.57
243.10
200.31
1.35
24.73
82.40
254.97
220.35
1.65
30.12
86.42
295.27
262.54
2.02
33.95
88.92
320.13
286.24
2.27
35.54
89.41
830.72
319.17
291.79
2.31
35.13
91.42
-254.94
70.66
70.55
1.18
14.75
2.40
-23.48
28.43
31.89
105.09
72.36
2.69
EP
M AN U
Total
AC C
Survey year
SC
Equivalised (€) expenditure
4
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Note: OOPP, out-of-pocket payments.
SC
Supplementary Table S3. Descriptive statistics of the sample (weighted), 2008-2015
RI PT
2015
Mean (SE)
M AN U
Variables
Categories 2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
3454
3524
3512
3515
3577
3471
5888
6150
2.67 (0.02)
2.65 (0.02)
2.65 (0.02)
2.65 (0.03)
2.64 (0.03)
2.62 (0.04)
2.58 (0.03)
2.58 (0.03)
Attica
37.08 (0.90)
39.08 (1.95)
41.48 (2.02)
40.57 (2.20)
40.41 (2.15)
38.92 (2.03)
40.25 (1.01)
40.08 (1.52)
Northern Greece
31.97 (0.86)
31.29 (1.86)
30.39 (1.88)
31.42 (2.12)
31.55 (2.07)
30.74 (1.91)
30.31 (1.00)
30.71 (1.40)
Central Greece
21.22 (0.74)
20.35 (1.60)
19.16 (1.55)
18.38 (1.58)
19.06 (1.61)
20.07 (1.58)
19.67 (1.04)
19.57 (1.28)
Aegean islands,
9.73 (0.54)
9.28 (1.12)
8.96 (1.16)
9.63 (1.38)
8.98 (1.17)
10.27 (1.25)
9.77 (0.88)
9.65 (0.87)
Number of
Region
Crete
EP
Household size
AC C
(unweighted)
TE D
households
5
Urban
45.39 (0.93)
71.50 (1.66)
48.01 (2.12)
43.47 (2.26)
42.81 (2.20)
66.00 (1.92)
42.64 (1.54)
42.73 (1.61)
domain
Semi-urban
11.86 (0.60)
11.90 (1.20)
14.10 (1.53)
14.40 (1.71)
14.93 (1.75)
13.05 (1.40)
29.66 (1.60)
29.48 (1.50)
Rural
42.76 (0.91)
16.61 (1.28)
37.90 (1.98)
42.14 (2.26)
42.26 (2.19)
20.95 (1.60)
27.70 (1.39)
27.79 (1.43)
34.17 (0.84)
33.83 (0.92)
33.81 (0.95)
34.82 (1.09)
35.26 (1.04)
36.51 (1.05)
37.20 (0.82)
40.47 (0.86)
12.37 (0.62)
13.86 (0.72)
13.33 (0.73)
13.76 (0.87)
14.48 (0.94)
12.24 (0.70)
13.11 (0.62)
8.91 (0.54)
4.66 (0.39)
3.69 (0.36)
3.09 (0.32)
3.31 (0.36)
3.09 (0.33)
4.00 (0.38)
3.65 (0.31)
3.58 (0.31)
39.06 (0.62)
37.89 (0.68)
37.03 (0.69)
34.72 (0.74)
32.28 (0.70)
32.88 (0.79)
31.53 (0.58)
31.45 (0.58)
3.06 (0.21)
4.73 (0.29)
7.10 (0.37)
10.13 (0.45)
10.83 (0.52)
9.86 (0.37)
9.60 (0.33)
Households with at least one child under 5 Households with at
unable to work Share of employed
Share of unemployed per household Share of retired per household Share of non-
3.84 (0.28)
AC C
per household
TE D
least one member
M AN U
least one elderly
SC
Households with at
RI PT
Population density
EP
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
23.76 (0.60)
24.71 (0.72)
23.78 (0.72)
24.76 (0.79)
25.83 (0.80)
25.43 (0.77)
27.58 (0.64)
27.97 (0.63)
34.12 (0.58)
33.55 (0.62)
34.46 (0.62)
33.42 (0.67)
31.76 (0.61)
30.86 (0.70)
31.03 (0.60)
30.98 (0.54)
6
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
per household
RI PT
economically active
None insured
1.38 (0.22)
1.01 (0.18)
2.47 (0.36)
2.52 (0.34)
4.33 (0.52)
6.33 (0.60)
5.42 (0.41)
4.31 (0.33)
household
Partially insured
7.08 (0.51)
5.52 (0.48)
6.41 (0.52)
8.12 (0.62)
9.99 (0.69)
11.25 (0.75)
10.78 (0.52)
9.82 (0.50)
Fully insured
91.54 (0.54)
93.46 (0.52)
91.11 (0.63)
89.36 (0.69)
85.68 (0.86)
82.42 (0.87)
83.80 (0.66)
85.87 (0.59)
Private insurance per
None insured
90.68 (0.56)
91.17 (0.69)
93.10 (0.61)
94.71 (0.54)
94.60 (0.62)
95.95 (0.49)
97.82 (0.27)
95.92 (0.33)
household
Partially insured
5.54 (0.45)
4.78 (0.50)
3.64 (0.44)
1.96 (0.30)
2.83 (0.47)
2.00 (0.33)
0.95 (0.17)
1.27 (0.17)
Fully insured
3.78 (0.36)
4.05 (0.42)
3.26 (0.38)
3.33 (0.45)
2.57 (0.36)
2.05 (0.33)
1.23 (0.19)
2.80 (0.26)
53.13 (0.31)
54.07 (0.38)
54.08 (0.39)
54.57 (0.42)
54.65 (0.39)
55.20 (0.39)
55.70 (0.32)
57.19 (0.31)
TE D
head (in years)
M AN U
Age of household
SC
Social insurance per
Male
74.75 (0.80)
76.26 (0.77)
75.83 (0.78)
74.96 (0.94)
73.02 (0.99)
70.80 (1.04)
69.28 (0.81)
69.85 (0.79)
head
Female
25.25 (0.80)
23.74 (0.77)
24.17 (0.78)
25.04 (0.94)
26.98 (0.99)
29.20 (1.04)
30.72 (0.81)
30.15 (0.79)
Level of studies
No formal
11.70 (0.55)
11.57 (0.64)
12.37 (0.73)
11.34 (0.71)
12.89 (0.77)
12.73 (0.80)
11.06 (0.57)
11.23 (0.60)
completed by the
education or
household head
below ISCED 1
24.00 (0.91)
26.64 (1.04)
23.37 (1.01)
24.75 (1.00)
23.15 (0.77)
22.14 (0.69)
education (ISCED
AC C
Primary
EP
Sex of household
26.38 (0.79)
28.37 (0.97)
1)
7
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
37.87 (1.01)
42.11 (1.06)
38.75 (1.12)
4.52 (0.41)
3.82 (0.39)
4.35 (0.42)
4.73 (0.46)
19.05 (0.75)
18.36 (0.90)
17.17 (0.89)
Employed
52.60 (0.92)
52.03 (1.01)
Unemployed
2.61 (0.32)
Retired
32.27 (0.83)
Non-economically
12.52 (0.61)
education (ISCED 2 &3) Post-secondary
4)
active
Note: SE, standard error.
5.61 (0.48)
5.29 (0.35)
4.96 (0.33)
19.22 (0.99)
21.29 (0.74)
22.73 (0.80)
51.39 (1.04)
49.13 (1.17)
45.56 (1.16)
42.76 (1.07)
43.72 (0.88)
43.17 (0.90)
3.63 (0.41)
4.54 (0.47)
6.16 (0.52)
9.18 (0.67)
10.69 (0.71)
8.38 (0.46)
8.57 (0.44)
33.59 (0.92)
32.66 (0.97)
33.94 (1.04)
34.92 (1.06)
34.26 (1.00)
36.08 (0.82)
36.77 (0.82)
10.75 (0.61)
11.40 (0.59)
10.77 (0.64)
10.34 (0.63)
12.29 (0.68)
11.82 (0.63)
11.50 (0.54)
TE D
EP
AC C
head
38.94 (0.83)
16.50 (0.99)
5 & 6)
activity of household
39.22 (0.88)
18.54 (0.96)
education (ISCED
Main economic
M AN U
education (ISCED
Tertiary
4.72 (0.47)
37.70 (1.06)
SC
non-tertiary
42.52 (1.19)
RI PT
38.36 (0.91)
Secondary
8
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Main
expenditure quintiles
components
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
SC
Household equivalised
RI PT
Supplementary Table S4. OOPP and components per expenditure quintile, 2008-2015
2013
Change 2008-2015 2014
2015
Relative Absolute (%)
Mean equivalised household expenditure (€)
3
312.16
225.05
248.02
274.48
266.96
-11.84
-4.25
Outpatient
233.27
287.36
201.92
143.92
118.44
139.83
127.61
130.74
-102.53
-43.95
Inpatient
33.55
33.73
31.62
34.78
33.00
62.18
64.31
72.78
39.22
116.90
Total
545.62
633.25
458.58
377.72
354.13
450.03
466.40
470.48
-75.14
-13.77
Medical products
215.28
242.60
223.53
201.94
236.21
300.54
338.94
339.30
124.02
57.61
Outpatient
420.17
396.49
345.14
239.17
292.05
260.24
288.72
246.67
-173.50
-41.29
Inpatient
73.27
111.29
48.79
60.52
113.31
146.33
159.13
182.11
108.84
148.56
Total
708.72
Medical products
235.13
Outpatient Inpatient Total
199.01
202.70
TE D
M AN U
278.80
EP
2
Medical products
750.38
617.46
501.63
641.58
707.11
786.79
768.08
59.36
8.38
222.90
222.37
230.11
273.63
338.83
339.86
385.20
150.07
63.83
AC C
1
637.42
537.61
524.55
473.83
429.95
356.48
355.26
415.52
-221.90
-34.81
121.30
129.94
133.36
241.63
182.84
288.03
283.92
381.49
260.19
214.50
993.85
890.45
880.28
945.56
886.42
983.34
979.04
1182.21
188.36
18.95
9
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
251.74
225.75
238.37
302.73
349.68
372.12
385.34
123.22
47.01
Outpatient
739.18
777.39
591.99
577.03
479.31
522.74
523.47
502.20
-236.98
-32.06
Inpatient
202.40
191.14
281.51
235.49
417.48
438.07
555.98
529.32
326.92
161.52
Total
1203.70
1220.26
1099.26
1050.89
1199.52
1310.50
1451.56
1416.86
213.16
17.71
Medical products
336.82
270.07
418.77
521.27
462.46
398.16
499.61
489.51
152.70
45.34
Outpatient
1271.34
1162.68
1193.88
1495.78
1045.24
1011.46
901.92
687.04
-584.29
-45.96
Inpatient
368.31
508.06
579.59
977.46
1257.57
1284.74
1406.97
1690.12
1321.80
358.88
Total
1976.47
1940.81
2192.24
2994.51
2765.27
2694.36
2808.49
2866.68
890.21
45.04
52.69
57.24
55.11
58.85
56.74
5.64
11.05
RI PT
262.11
SC
5
Medical products
M AN U
4
Share (%) in total OOPP 49.30
Outpatient
42.75
45.38
44.03
38.10
33.44
31.07
27.36
27.79
-14.96
-35.00
Inpatient
6.15
5.33
6.89
9.21
9.32
13.82
13.79
15.47
9.32
151.55
Medical products
30.38
32.33
36.20
40.26
36.82
42.50
43.08
44.18
13.80
45.43
Outpatient
59.29
52.84
55.90
47.68
45.52
36.80
36.70
32.11
-27.17
-45.83
Inpatient 3
Medical products Outpatient Inpatient
49.07
TE D
51.10
EP
2
Medical products
AC C
1
10.34
14.83
7.90
12.06
17.66
20.69
20.23
23.71
13.37
129.35
23.66
25.03
25.26
24.34
30.87
34.46
34.71
32.58
8.92
37.72
64.14
60.37
59.59
50.11
48.50
36.25
36.29
35.15
-28.99
-45.20
12.21
14.59
15.15
25.55
20.63
29.29
29.00
32.27
20.06
164.39
10
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
20.63
20.54
22.68
25.24
26.68
25.64
27.20
5.42
24.89
Outpatient
61.41
63.71
53.85
54.91
39.96
39.89
36.06
35.44
-25.96
-42.28
Inpatient
16.81
15.66
25.61
22.41
34.80
33.43
38.30
37.36
20.54
122.18
Medical products
17.04
13.92
19.10
17.41
16.72
14.78
17.79
17.08
0.03
0.20
Outpatient
64.32
59.91
54.46
49.95
37.80
37.54
32.11
23.97
-40.36
-62.74
Inpatient
18.63
26.18
26.44
32.64
45.48
47.68
50.10
58.96
40.32
216.38
RI PT
21.78
M AN U
5
Medical products
SC
4
EP
TE D
Note: The equivalised expenditure quintiles are anchored to the 2008 expenditure distribution. OOPP, out-of-pocket payments.
2008
AC C
Supplementary Table S5. Changes in the distribution of incidence and intensity of CHE at 10% threshold of CTP, 2008-2015
2009
2010
Change 2008-2015 2011
2012
2013
2014
2015 Absolute
11
Relative (%)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
28.77
23.43
21.66
(1.77)
(1.72)
(1.55)
(1.30)
(1.24)
21.39
23.78
20.00
13.63
21.03
(1.62)
(1.68)
(1.54)
(1.35)
(1.77)
22.11
17.62
19.49
22.16
19.44
(1.70)
(1.64)
(1.59)
(2.03)
19.37
21.75
17.24
(1.67)
(1.85)
(1.88)
16.80
14.23
19.64
(1.55)
(1.53)
(2.13)
Test for linear trend
<0.01
<0.01
Total
22.77
Richest quintile
(0.75) Overshoot
(1.29)
(1.01)
(1.04)
23.20
24.63
26.18
(1.37)
(1.42)
22.53
23.17
28.88
(2.22)
(2.61)
(2.02)
(1.75)
15.79
20.48
21.73
28.02
21.77
(2.25)
(2.68)
(3.05)
(2.50)
(2.33)
29.62
26.90
24.86
32.47
24.12
(3.42)
(3.67)
(4.23)
(2.99)
(2.74)
<0.01
<0.01
0.48
0.08
0.02
0.01
TE D
4
29.79
EP
3
28.23
SC
38.34
(1.80)
M AN U
34.15
2
28.07
AC C
Poorest quintile
RI PT
Headcount
23.71
22.22
20.45
21.48
25.59
27.06
27.95
(0.82)
(0.82)
(0.87)
(0.88)
(0.93)
(0.73)
(0.75)
12
-4.36*
-12.77
4.79*
22.39
6.77*
30.62
2.40
12.39
7.32*
43.57
5.18*
22.75
Poorest quintile
3.32 (0.26)
4.07 (0.28)
2.53 (0.19)
1.94 (0.15)
1.85 (0.14)
2.52 (0.16)
2
2.09 (0.24)
2.32 (0.23)
1.56 (0.17)
0.96 (0.12)
1.66 (0.17)
3
1.90 (0.20)
1.73 (0.23)
1.60 (0.18)
1.92 (0.25)
1.48 (0.21)
4
1.66 (0.21)
1.54 (0.18)
1.33 (0.21)
1.14 (0.21)
1.69 (0.36)
RI PT
Richest quintile
1.41 (0.20)
1.18 (0.20)
1.68 (0.31)
2.92 (0.54)
1.90 (0.38)
Test for linear trend
<0.01
<0.01
<0.01
<0.01
0.66
Total
2.08 (0.10)
2.24 (0.11)
1.86 (0.10)
1.69 (0.10)
9.73 (0.60)
10.60
8.79 (0.49)
EP
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Poorest quintile
(0.52) 9.77 (0.85)
3
8.60 (0.69)
4
8.57 (0.83)
9.76 (0.70)
7.82 (0.58)
AC C
2
2.77 (0.14)
-0.55*
-16.57
2.47 (0.20)
2.32 (0.17)
0.23
11.00
1.93 (0.34)
1.99 (0.23)
2.74 (0.28)
0.84*
44.21
1.78 (0.31)
2.21 (0.29)
2.50 (0.39)
0.84*
50.60
1.93 (0.42)
2.28 (0.35)
2.85 (0.44)
1.44*
102.13
0.18
0.04
0.27
1.75 (0.10)
2.28 (0.11)
2.56 (0.10)
2.65 (0.10)
0.57*
27.40
8.28 (0.43)
8.55 (0.42)
8.97 (0.38)
9.95 (0.35)
9.28 (0.29)
-0.45
-4.62
7.05 (0.64)
7.89 (0.62)
9.52 (0.69)
10.05
8.84 (0.45)
-0.93
-9.52
M AN U
SC
2.21 (0.22)
TE D
Mean positive overshoot
2.81 (0.15)
(0.63)
9.83 (0.91)
8.19 (0.70)
8.66 (0.84)
7.64 (0.78)
8.57 (0.94)
8.59 (0.72)
9.48 (0.74)
0.88
10.23
7.09 (0.55)
7.72 (0.81)
7.24 (0.95)
8.27 (1.44)
8.20 (0.99)
7.89 (0.78)
11.48
2.91
33.96
13
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Richest quintile
8.41 (0.94)
8.28 (1.19)
8.55 (1.25)
9.86 (1.62)
7.06 (1.14)
0.53
0.00
0.68
0.31
0.67
Total
9.13 (0.34)
9.45 (0.33)
8.35 (0.31)
8.25 (0.38)
8.14 (0.30)
7.77 (1.14)
0.70
SC
Test for linear trend
RI PT
(1.47) 11.81
3.40*
40.43
0.34
3.72
(1.33)
0.01
0.11
9.47 (0.27)
9.47 (0.25)
M AN U
8.92 (0.29)
7.01 (0.98)
Note: Standard errors in parentheses.* P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with x2 test for headcount, t-test following a fractional probit regression for overshoot and F-test for concentration index. Linear trend between expenditure quintiles was tested with F-tests following a
TE D
logistic regression for headcounts and a fractional probit regression for overshoot. CTP, capacity to pay; CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
Headcount Poorest quintile
2009
2010
Change 2008-2015 2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
AC C
2008
EP
Supplementary Table S6. Changes in the distribution of incidence and intensity of CHE at 20% threshold of CTP, 2008-2015
12.88
15.44
8.76 (0.81)
6.88 (0.69)
14
7.03 (0.69)
9.76 (0.78)
10.34
10.79
Absolute
Relative (%)
-2.09
-16.23
(1.21)
(1.23)
2
6.89 (0.96)
8.25 (1.06)
5.65 (0.83)
3.42 (0.58)
5.56 (0.81)
3
6.46 (0.96)
5.86 (0.92)
5.25 (0.83)
6.89 (1.22)
6.13 (1.16)
4
7.00 (1.06)
5.62 (0.90)
4.77 (1.15)
4.16 (1.21)
3.88 (1.17)
RI PT
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
(0.64)
Richest quintile
4.71 (0.84)
4.65 (0.85)
5.34 (1.19)
8.31 (1.88)
4.24 (1.42)
(0.66)
8.90 (0.85)
8.86 (0.81)
1.97
28.59
7.36 (1.87)
6.34 (0.98)
9.60 (1.22)
3.14*
48.61
4.94 (1.32)
7.06 (1.30)
8.25 (1.39)
1.25
17.86
6.45 (2.12)
6.28 (1.38)
10.51
5.80*
123.14
2.41*
31.75
M AN U
SC
9.42 (1.20)
(1.74)
<0.01
<0.01
<0.01
<0.01
0.17
0.08
0.01
0.27
Total
7.59 (0.46)
8.24 (0.47)
6.38 (0.42)
5.84 (0.44)
6.11 (0.44)
8.83 (0.59)
9.07 (0.45)
10.00
1.22 (0.16)
1.52 (0.17)
2
0.83 (0.15)
0.80 (0.13)
3
0.62 (0.12)
4
0.58 (0.12)
(0.47)
0.82 (0.10)
0.57 (0.08)
0.54 (0.07)
0.78 (0.09)
0.99 (0.08)
0.88 (0.07)
-0.34*
-27.87
0.42 (0.08)
0.22 (0.05)
0.51 (0.09)
0.74 (0.11)
1.00 (0.13)
0.76 (0.09)
-0.07
-8.43
AC C
Poorest quintile
EP
Overshoot
TE D
Test for linear trend
0.66 (0.14)
0.48 (0.10)
0.60 (0.14)
0.37 (0.09)
0.54 (0.16)
0.63 (0.13)
1.03 (0.17)
0.41*
66.13
0.37 (0.08)
0.34 (0.09)
0.30 (0.10)
0.57 (0.25)
0.45 (0.16)
0.59 (0.17)
1.19 (0.27)
0.61*
105.17
15
Richest quintile
0.49 (0.13)
0.46 (0.13)
0.64 (0.20)
1.25 (0.38)
0.58 (0.24)
0.51 (0.18)
Test for linear trend
<0.01
<0.01
0.00
<0.01
0.69
Total
0.75 (0.06)
0.79 (0.06)
0.58 (0.05)
0.52 (0.06)
0.52 (0.05)
RI PT
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Poorest quintile
9.48 (0.92)
9.83 (0.80)
9.35 (0.78)
8.25 (0.69)
7.70 (0.61)
2
12.00
9.75 (1.01)
7.45 (1.05)
6.46 (1.24)
3
9.62 (1.27)
11.20
9.20 (1.18)
10.35 (1.93)
Test for linear trend
0.33
Total
9.86 (0.57)
6.50 (1.10)
9.99 (1.89)
7.13 (1.23)
EP
Richest quintile
8.33 (1.25)
11.95
7.31 (2.26)
6.04 (0.98)
14.79
0.31
0.70 (0.06)
0.91 (0.06)
0.91 (0.06)
0.16
21.33
9.60 (0.52)
8.17 (0.42)
-1.31
-13.82
11.21
8.60 (0.74)
-3.40*
-28.33
10.74
1.12
11.64
6.11*
73.35
0.46
4.44
-0.75
-7.61
8.02 (0.53) 7.83 (0.82)
7.39 (1.21)
(1.03) 9.93 (1.51)
9.08 (2.01)
8.37 (1.97)
(4.39) 13.71
(2.40)
(3.24)
(3.58)
0.12
0.21
0.07
0.01
9.59 (0.53)
9.03 (0.53)
8.86 (0.69)
8.46 (0.55)
16
132.65
(1.23)
15.09
AC C
4
TE D
(1.53)
8.76 (1.38)
0.65*
0.13
M AN U
(1.31)
9.18 (0.97)
1.14 (0.29)
0.35
SC
Mean positive overshoot
0.80 (0.24)
14.44 (1.87)
7.90 (1.68)
12.72
10.81
(2.95)
(2.19)
0.96
0.47
0.00
7.94 (0.39)
10.03
9.11 (0.37)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
(0.43)
RI PT
Note: Standard errors in parentheses.* P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with x2 test for headcount, t-test following a fractional probit regression for overshoot and F-test for concentration index. Linear trend between expenditure quintiles was tested with F-tests following a
M AN U
SC
logistic regression for headcounts and a fractional probit regression for overshoot. CTP, capacity to pay; CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
2009
2010
2011
Change 2008-2015 2012
2013
2014
2015 Absolute
Relative (%)
EP
2008
TE D
Supplementary Table S7. Changes in the distribution of incidence and intensity of CHE at 30% threshold of CTP, 2008-2015
Poorest quintile
4.73 (0.73)
2
3.62 (0.73)
3
2.37 (0.56)
AC C
Headcount 5.71 (0.73)
3.15 (0.50)
1.95 (0.35)
2.03 (0.35)
2.91 (0.49)
3.72 (0.37)
3.47 (0.38)
-1.26
-26.64
3.53 (0.65)
1.37 (0.39)
0.66 (0.24)
1.93 (0.44)
3.02 (0.63)
3.69 (0.57)
2.58 (0.42)
-1.04
-28.73
2.55 (0.63)
1.85 (0.52)
2.52 (0.78)
0.75 (0.32)
1.80 (0.58)
1.56 (0.48)
4.21 (0.82)
1.84*
77.64
17
2.31 (0.59)
1.06 (0.34)
1.28 (0.53)
0.64 (0.29)
2.35 (0.91)
2.39 (0.97)
Richest quintile
1.81 (0.52)
1.54 (0.50)
2.65 (0.97)
3.70 (1.13)
1.48 (0.72)
Test for linear trend
0.01
<0.01
0.04
0.00
0.25
Total
2.97 (0.28)
2.99 (0.28)
2.18 (0.26)
1.73 (0.25)
1.82 (0.23)
Poorest quintile
0.44 (0.09)
0.53 (0.10)
0.29 (0.06)
0.14 (0.03)
0.14 (0.03)
2
0.32 (0.08)
0.25 (0.07)
0.12 (0.04)
0.07 (0.03)
3
0.22 (0.06)
0.26 (0.08)
0.13 (0.05)
0.18 (0.07)
4
0.20 (0.06)
0.10 (0.05)
0.06 (0.03)
Richest quintile
0.19 (0.08)
0.17 (0.07)
0.28 (0.12)
Test for linear trend
0.12
<0.01
Total
0.27 (0.03)
0.27 (0.04)
9.30 (1.32)
Poorest quintile
4.86 (1.17)
2.55*
110.39
1.45
80.11
2.20 (0.81)
3.26 (0.95)
0.36
0.01
0.16
2.66 (0.30)
3.20 (0.25)
3.46 (0.27)
0.49
16.50
0.19 (0.03)
0.36 (0.04)
0.24 (0.03)
-0.20*
-45.45
0.13 (0.04)
0.18 (0.05)
0.44 (0.08)
0.24 (0.05)
-0.08
-25.00
0.06 (0.03)
0.16 (0.06)
0.24 (0.08)
0.41 (0.10)
0.19
86.36
0.11 (0.07)
0.27 (0.18)
0.15 (0.07)
0.24 (0.11)
0.57 (0.16)
0.37*
185.00
0.68 (0.27)
0.25 (0.15)
0.11 (0.07)
0.38 (0.17)
0.56 (0.21)
0.37
194.74
<0.01
0.21
0.91
0.48
0.01
0.19 (0.03)
0.17 (0.03)
0.15 (0.03)
0.17 (0.02)
0.35 (0.03)
0.30 (0.03)
0.03
11.11
9.20 (1.22)
9.36 (1.11)
7.12 (1.06)
6.92 (0.91)
6.51 (0.67)
9.60 (0.80)
6.98 (0.64)
-2.32
-24.95
SC
1.12 (0.65)
EP
TE D
M AN U
Overshoot
Mean positive overshoot
1.56 (0.57)
AC C
4
RI PT
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
0.01
18
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2
8.97 (1.52)
7.16 (1.38)
8.63 (1.84)
9.96 (2.32)
6.86 (1.18)
5.95 (0.84)
11.83
9.19 (1.29)
0.22
2.45
9.78 (1.67)
0.37
3.93
15.56
11.65
3.16
37.22
(4.79)
(1.53)
17.47
17.04
6.48
61.36
(5.84)
(4.47)
-0.47
-5.07
3
9.41 (1.71)
10.09
7.30 (1.75)
7.24 (2.06)
7.73 (1.66)
9.10 (2.79)
4.97 (1.37)
17.19
11.43
(7.00)
(5.37)
6.07 (1.94)
11.32
10.41
18.29
17.05
(3.24)
(2.62)
(3.09)
(3.94)
(5.55)
Test for linear trend
0.98
0.61
0.22
0.01
0.18
0.48
<0.01
<0.01
Total
9.27 (0.79)
9.05 (0.78)
8.75 (0.83)
8.02 (0.98)
6.59 (0.53)
11.03
8.80 (0.56)
TE D
10.56
9.92 (1.10)
9.38 (2.37)
(0.67)
EP
Richest quintile
8.49 (1.74)
15.49
(2.91)
M AN U
4
8.71 (2.29)
SC
(2.15)
RI PT
(1.21)
Note: Standard errors in parentheses.* P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with x2 test for headcount, t-test following a
AC C
fractional probit regression for overshoot and F-test for concentration index. Linear trend between expenditure quintiles was tested with F-tests following a logistic regression for headcounts and a fractional probit regression for overshoot. CTP, capacity to pay; CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
19
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
1.59 (0.42)
1.95 (0.45)
1.18 (0.27)
0.54 (0.21)
2
1.10 (0.40)
0.83 (0.31)
0.51 (0.22)
0.36 (0.18)
0.54 (0.23)
3
1.06 (0.36)
1.08 (0.39)
0.37 (0.22)
0.26 (0.19)
4
0.64 (0.32)
0.32 (0.20)
0.14 (0.14)
0.25 (0.18)
Richest quintile
0.76 (0.33)
0.92 (0.38)
1.47 (0.76)
Test for linear trend
0.42
0.03
0.05
Total
1.03 (0.16)
1.05 (0.17)
Poorest quintile
0.14 (0.05)
2
0.11 (0.04)
0.57 (0.16)
2014
Change 2008-2015 2015 Absolute
Relative (%)
1.28 (0.19)
0.88 (0.16)
-0.71
-44.65
0.52 (0.23)
1.77 (0.37)
0.93 (0.24)
-0.17
-15.45
0.21 (0.16)
0.66 (0.34)
1.17 (0.41)
1.44 (0.45)
0.38
35.85
0.81 (0.58)
0.33 (0.33)
1.09 (0.46)
3.11 (1.02)
2.47*
385.94
2.57 (1.00)
0.84 (0.55)
0.84 (0.60)
0.86 (0.43)
2.01 (0.71)
1.25
164.47
<0.01
0.60
0.95
0.54
0.01
0.59 (0.14)
0.49 (0.11)
0.57 (0.11)
1.34 (0.15)
1.19 (0.15)
0.16
15.53
TE D
EP
AC C
Overshoot
0.43 (0.14)
M AN U
Poorest quintile
0.78 (0.15)
2013
SC
Headcount
RI PT
Supplementary Table S8. Changes in the distribution of incidence and intensity of CHE at 40% threshold of CTP, 2008-2015
0.18 (0.06)
0.08 (0.03)
0.02 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.12 (0.02)
0.05 (0.01)
-0.09*
-64.29
0.06 (0.04)
0.04 (0.02)
0.02 (0.01)
0.02 (0.01)
0.02 (0.01)
0.16 (0.04)
0.07 (0.03)
-0.04
-36.36
20
3
0.07 (0.03)
0.08 (0.05)
0.03 (0.02)
0.05 (0.04)
0.01 (0.01)
0.05 (0.03)
4
0.06 (0.03)
0.03 (0.03)
0.01 (0.01)
0.07 (0.05)
0.13 (0.12)
Richest quintile
0.08 (0.05)
0.07 (0.04)
0.11 (0.06)
0.38 (0.18)
0.14 (0.10)
Test for linear trend
0.59
0.14
0.03
<0.01
0.04
RI PT
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Total
0.09 (0.02)
0.09 (0.02)
0.06 (0.01)
0.06 (0.02)
0.04 (0.01)
Poorest quintile
8.67 (2.04)
9.44 (2.01)
7.13 (1.61)
4.50 (1.51)
7.24 (1.62)
2
9.87 (2.71)
7.58 (3.86)
7.32 (1.86)
5.08 (1.80)
3
6.55 (2.12)
7.51 (3.76)
8.94 (2.14)
18.72
10.33 (4.89)
EP
9.87 (4.72)
3.66 (0.00)
AC C
Richest quintile
8.80 (3.42)
7.82 (2.16)
7.60 (4.26)
100.00
0.13
216.67
0.02 (0.01)
0.24 (0.12)
0.29 (0.15)
0.21
262.50
0.78
0.73
<0.01
0.03 (0.01)
0.14 (0.02)
0.09 (0.02)
0.00
0.00
5.05 (1.01)
9.47 (0.97)
5.97 (0.89)
-2.70
-31.14
4.29 (1.47)
4.29 (0.89)
8.96 (1.34)
7.74 (1.95)
-2.13
-21.58
3.70 (2.30)
6.87 (1.76)
9.87 (2.67)
10.04
3.49
53.28
6.06 (1.34)
-2.74
-31.14
27.26
14.25
3.92
37.95
(5.39)
(5.68)
SC
0.19 (0.07)
(2.61)
26.45
16.27
(3.29)
(6.82)
14.90
16.24
(3.78)
(4.15)
21
0.07
0.12 (0.07)
(3.17)
4
0.14 (0.06)
0.01 (0.01)
M AN U
TE D
Mean positive overshoot
0.12 (0.05)
4.09 (0.00)
11.25 (4.17)
1.87 (1.11)
Test for linear trend
0.90
0.97
0.00
<0.01
0.01
0.38
Total
8.75 (1.29)
8.51 (1.36)
7.35 (1.40)
10.67
8.65 (1.88)
RI PT
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
(1.98)
4.83 (0.70)
0.19 10.13
7.68 (1.03)
-1.07
-12.23
(0.85)
SC
Note: Standard errors in parentheses.* P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with x2 test for headcount, t-test following a fractional probit regression for overshoot and F-test for concentration index. Linear trend between expenditure quintiles was tested with F-tests following a
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
logistic regression for headcounts and a fractional probit regression for overshoot. CTP, capacity to pay; CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
22
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Supplementary Figure S1. Evolution of headcount of CHE for various thresholds of
M AN U
SC
RI PT
households’ CTP, 2008-2015
Note: Brackets represent 95% confidence intervals. P-value refers to the mean
TE D
difference between 2008 and 2015, which was tested with x2 test. CTP, capacity to
AC C
EP
pay; CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
23
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Supplementary Figure S2. Evolution of overshoot of CHE for various thresholds of
M AN U
SC
RI PT
households’ CTP, 2008-2015
Note: Brackets represent 95% confidence intervals. P-value refers to the mean
TE D
difference between 2008 and 2015, which was tested with t-test following a fractional
AC C
EP
probit regression. CTP, capacity to pay; CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
24
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Supplementary Figure S3. Evolution of mean positive overshoot of CHE for various
M AN U
SC
RI PT
thresholds of households’ CTP, 2008-2015
TE D
Note: Brackets represent 95% confidence intervals. P-value refers to the mean difference between 2008 and 2015, which was tested with t-test following a fractional
AC C
EP
probit regression. CTP, capacity to pay; CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
25
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
SC
RI PT
Supplementary Figure S4. Evolution of components’ share of OOPP for households with catastrophe, 2008-2015
Note: OOPP, out-of-pocket payments.
26
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
OR (SE) 2008
OR (SE)
Wald test of equality
2015
of
2008
2008
2015
equality ORs p-value
1.116 (0.143)
0.934 (0.098)
0.282
1.109 (0.217)
0.887 (0.132)
0.362
0.908 (0.289)
0.680 (0.165)
0.470
1.144 (0.168)
0.765**
0.044
1.037 (0.225)
0.805 (0.149)
0.376
1.613 (0.507)
0.720 (0.224)
0.068
0.899 (0.171)
0.092
1.812 (0.667)
0.868 (0.253)
0.117
1.222 (0.174)
0.853
1.442 (0.481)
1.292 (0.302)
0.789
(0.103)
Crete
(0.250)
Urbanicity (Urban as ref.) 0.892 (0.140)
0.781* (0.103)
0.002
1.510* (0.365)
EP
1.516**
AC C
Aegean islands,
TE D
Greece
Semi-urban
of
Wald test of
SC M AN U
ref.)
Central Greece
equality
OR (SE)
ORs p-value
Region (Attica as
Northern
Wald test of
2015
ORs p-value
RI PT
Supplementary Table S9. Determinants of CHE of households at 10%, 20% and 30% thresholds, 2008 vs. 2015
1.351***
0.026
1.283 (0.286)
27
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Rural
0.988 (0.119)
1.627***
0.003
0.894 (0.160)
(0.188) 0.881**
(0.230)
0.934 (0.042)
0.395
0.701***
Elderly
in
1.348* (0.208)
household (no as
(0.060) 2.388***
M AN U
(0.045) 0.004
1.276 (0.338)
(0.294)
0.009
2.299***
0.073
0.865 (0.247)
3.085***
2.498***
household (no as
(0.532)
(0.456)
0.989 (0.120)
1.102 (0.102)
0.400
4.691***
2.974***
TE D
Children under 5 in
(1.463)
0.477
AC C
head (males as ref,)
EP
ref.)
Age of household
1.019***
1.029***
head
(0.005)
(0.004)
0.121
0.733* (0.130)
0.045
0.663***
0.957 (0.106)
0.039
3.543***
0.016
(0.092) 0.952 (0.408)
(1.182)
0.252
(0.734)
0.92 (0.113)
1.858** (0.470)
(0.447)
ref.)
Sex of household
0.925 (0.059)
0.051
SC
Household size
1.429**
RI PT
(0.135)
0.292
6.343***
2.776**
0.277
(3.651)
(1.377)
0.562**
0.893 (0.173)
0.168
1.013 (0.010)
0.109
(0.154)
1.032***
1.024***
(0.007)
(0.006)
28
0.373
1.039*** (0.012)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Education
of
RI PT
household head (no formal education as
0.823* (0.092)
0.389
0.735* (0.131)
education
(0.092)
Secondary
0.686**
0.625***
0.638
0.75 (0.158)
education
(0.103)
(0.083)
Post-secondary
1.165 (0.314)
0.86 (0.181)
0.376
Tertiary
0.606***
0.497***
0.424
education
(0.117)
(0.076)
1.46 (0.478)
1.133 (0.180)
0.643* (0.165)
1.001 (0.206)
0.178
0.319
0.8 (0.244)
0.508**
0.285
0.681 (0.332)
EP
0.673 (0.208)
(0.149)
0.868 (0.234)
0.663
0.471 (0.356)
0.626 (0.281)
0.747
0.317***
0.053
0.5 (0.245)
0.301***
0.450
(0.074)
(0.138)
AC C
activity
of household head (Employed as ref.) Unemployed
0.577***
0.700
(0.091)
non-tertiary
Economic
0.799* (0.101)
M AN U
0.710***
TE D
Primary
SC
ref.)
0.486
0.402 (0.335)
29
0.858 (0.263)
0.393
a
1.095 (0.614)
0.871
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Retired
1.522***
0.93 (0.116)
0.014
1.49 (0.391)
0.818 (0.156)
1.058 (0.203)
0.842 (0.130)
0.355
1.016 (0.307)
0.739**
1.106 (0.102)
0.013
1.462***
0.006
RI PT
Non-
TE D
(0.236)
0.832 (0.185)
active
of
household (poorest as ref.)
0.887 (0.124)
Richest
0.828 (0.124)
0.735* (0.117)
AC C
(0.168) 4
0.012
1.702 (0.886)
0.711 (0.323)
0.206
(1.329)
1.229 (0.199)
1.789***
0.763 (0.151)
1.055 (0.130)
0.163
1.26 (0.364)
1.011 (0.205)
0.532
0.873 (0.183)
1.337* (0.229)
0.115
1.035 (0.333)
2.030***
0.102
EP
(0.098) 3
0.739 (0.280)
M AN U
Expenditure
2
0.593
3.119***
SC
economically
quintiles
0.065
0.073
<0.001
(0.521)
1.114 (0.259)
1.539* (0.339)
0.312
1.273 (0.438)
3.344***
0.038
(1.046) 0.758 (0.196)
30
2.663***
<0.001
1.151 (0.476)
2.966***
0.086
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
insurance
status of household (none
insured
as
ref.) 0.959 (0.527)
1.047 (0.271)
0.885
0.718 (0.527)
0.623 (0.264)
0.867
0.252 (0.314)
0.633 (0.488)
0.529
1.045 (0.537)
1.089 (0.248)
0.941
0.633 (0.400)
0.861 (0.282)
0.666
0.308 (0.306)
0.632 (0.372)
0.533
1.379 (0.314)
0.754 (0.298)
0.186
0.721 (0.331)
0.850 (0.510)
0.827
0.519 (0.537)
0.567 (0.594)
0.952
1.043 (0.311)
1.149 (0.242)
0.672 (0.307)
0.848 (0.270)
0.676
0.518 (0.573)
0.493 (0.265)
0.967
M AN U
Partially insured Fully insured insurance
TE D
Private
status of household insured
as
Partially insured Fully insured
AC C
ref.)
EP
(none
(1.079)
SC
Social
(0.601)
RI PT
(0.344)
0.791
31
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2.941***
(0.391)
(0.596)
0.128***
0.050***
(0.081) No of observations
3454
Model F-statistic
F(26,
in
household (no as
0.084
1.253 (0.435)
2.527*** (0.549)
ref.)
3428)
1.231 (0.510)
0.719
0.014***
0.016***
0.931
(0.018)
(0.034)
(0.015)
(0.019)
(0.011)
6150
3454
6150
3376
6150
F(26,
SC
0.031***
3842)
0.688
1.572 (0.846)
0.044***
F(26,
0.197
M AN U
Constant
0.087
RI PT
1.745**
Disable
3428)
F(26,
3842)
F(25,
3351)
F(26,
3842)
=24.54,
=7.28,
=9.48,
=6.94,
=6.30,
p-value<0.01
p-value<0.01
p-value<0.01
p-value<0.01
p-value<0.01
p-value<0.01
Pseudo-R2
0.087
0.142
0.106
0.103
0.131
0.101
Hosmer-Lemeshow
x2(8)=8.07,
x2(8)=9.82,
x2(8)=5.84,
x2(8)=4.25,
x2(8)=2.90,
x2(8)=5.82,
goodness-of-fit test
p-value=0.427
p-value=0.278
p-value=0.666
p-value=0.834
p-value=0.941
p-value=0.668
EP
AC C
Joint tests of ORs
TE D
=9.58,
<0.01
0.016
Note: a All observations with no CHE. * P-value<0.1; ** p-value<0.05; *** p-value<0.01. OR, odds ratio; SE, standard error; CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
32
<0.01
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Supplementary Table S10 Self-reported unmet needs for medical examination, 2008-2015 2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
5.4
5.5
5.5
7.5
8.0
9.0
10.9
12.3
First quintile
8.7
11.2
9.2
11.6
11.7
14.9
17.3
18.7
Second quintile
7.1
7.4
6.7
9.8
9.7
11.4
16.7
15.6
Third quintile
6.1
4.6
5.9
7.6
9.1
9.7
13.5
12.6
Fourth quintile
3.4
2.7
3.3
4.8
4.7
7.8
6.0
10.6
Fifth quintile
1.8
1.7
2.1
3.6
4.8
3.3
2.7
3.1
4.7
5.6
8.6
7.5
9.5
11.4
Total By income
1.1
3.9
M AN U
status Employed
6.1
7.4
8.8
Unemployed
10.8
11.7
15.7
15.6
persons Retired persons
9.3
Other inactive
5.8
9.3
8.9
11.7
10.8
11.2
12.5
15.6
7.3
6.4
6.9
8.1
9.7
11.7
11.5
EP
persons
TE D
persons
SC 1.0
By employment
RI PT
quintile
Note: Unmet need due to too expensive/too far/long waiting lists. Source: Eurostat, (2017).
AC C
Eurostat online database. http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/lfs/data/database (accessed 08.07.2017).
33
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Acknowledgements
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
SC
RI PT
The authors would like to thank two anonymous reviewers for their helpful and constructive comments that greatly contributed to improving the final version of the paper
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
RI PT
Table 1. Changes in mean household consumption, health financing and CTP, 2008-2015 Equivalised household expenditure (€) Year
Medical products
Total
Outpatient
consumption
Pharmaceutical
M AN U
Total
CTP (€)
SC
Total OOPP
Inpatient
Per household
Share (%) of health expenditure to CTP
19670.77
1085.66
265.65
221.24
660.25
159.76
29656.48
6.93%
2009
19274.71
1064.68
261.51
214.00
615.59
187.58
28707.75
7.21%
2010
16720.26
904.83
251.45
216.06
487.00
166.37
24557.85
6.51%
2011
14786.40
809.93
237.50
200.31
391.11
181.32
21341.60
6.15%
2012
13333.39
731.60
246.54
220.35
295.48
189.57
18947.77
6.26%
2013
12969.27
773.40
287.96
262.54
274.93
210.50
17608.40
7.22%
2014
12609.93
805.36
316.62
286.24
263.99
224.75
17250.32
7.70%
2015
12649.60
830.72
319.17
291.79
251.17
260.38
17094.66
7.77%
Absolute change
-7021.17*
-254.94*
53.52*
70.55*
-409.08*
100.62*
-12561.82*
0.84%*
AC C
EP
TE D
2008
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Relative change
-35.69
-23.48
20.15
31.89
2008-2015 (%)
-61.96
RI PT
2008-2015 62.98
-42.36
12.12
SC
Note: All expenditures have been deflated to 2015 prices. OOPP, out-of-pocket payments; CTP, capacity to pay. * P-value<0.05 based on a t-
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
test of the mean difference between 2008 and 2015
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2009
2010
2011
2012
Headcount 23.71
22.22
20.45
21.48
(0.75)
(0.82)
(0.82)
(0.87)
Quintile ratio
2.03
2.69
1.46
CI
-0.138
-0.194
Weighted headcount
25.91
Total
2014
2008-2015 2015
Absolute
Relative
change
change (%)
5.18*
22.75
25.59
27.06
27.95
(0.88)
(0.93)
(0.73)
(0.75)
0.79
0.81
1.13
0.87
1.24
-0.80
-39.24
-0.104
-0.028
-0.007
-0.070
-0.012
-0.036
-0.18*
-73.73
28.32
24.53
21.02
21.64
27.38
27.39
28.96
3.05
11.77
2.08 (0.10)
2.24 (0.11)
1.86 (0.10)
1.69 (0.10)
1.75 (0.10)
2.28 (0.11)
2.56 (0.10)
2.65 (0.10)
0.57*
27.40
Quintile ratio
2.35
3.45
1.51
0.66
0.97
1.31
1.23
0.97
-1.38
-58.72
CI
-0.174
-0.269
-0.129
-0.016
-0.043
-0.074
-0.070
-0.014
0.16*
-91.73
Weighted overshoot
2.44
9.13 (0.34)
AC C
Total
EP
Overshoot
Mean positive overshoot
M AN U
22.77
TE D
Total
2013
SC
2008
RI PT
Table 2. Changes in the distribution of incidence and intensity of CHE at 10% threshold of CTP, 2008-2015
2.84
2.10
1.72
1.82
2.45
2.74
2.69
0.25
10.09
9.45 (0.33)
8.35 (0.31)
8.25 (0.38)
8.14 (0.30)
8.92 (0.29)
9.47 (0.27)
9.47 (0.25)
0.34
3.72
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
1.16
1.28
1.03
0.84
1.21
1.15
1.42
0.79
-0.37
-32.08
CI
-0.036
-0.074
-0.029
0.007
-0.034
-0.003
-0.057
0.021
0.06*
-158.84
9.46
10.15
8.59
8.19
8.42
8.95
10.01
9.27
-0.19
-2.01
Weighted
mean
positive
overshoot
RI PT
Quintile ratio
SC
Note: Standard errors in parentheses.* P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with x2 test for headcount, t-test
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
following a fractional probit regression for overshoot and F-test for concentration index. CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2009
2010
2011
2012
Headcount 7.59 (0.46)
8.24 (0.47)
6.38 (0.42)
5.84 (0.44)
6.11 (0.44)
8.83 (0.59)
M AN U
Total
2013
SC
2008
RI PT
Table 3. Changes in the distribution of incidence and intensity of CHE at 20% threshold of CTP, 2008-2015
2014
9.07 (0.45)
2008-2015 2015
10.00
Absolute
Relative
change
change (%)
2.41*
31.75
(0.47)
2.73
3.32
1.64
0.83
1.66
1.51
1.65
1.03
-1.71
-62.46
CI
-0.184
-0.274
-0.152
-0.046
-0.113
-0.076
-0.099
-0.043
0.14*
-76.83
Weighted headcount
8.98
10.49
7.35
6.11
6.80
9.50
9.97
10.43
1.44
16.04
Total
0.75 (0.06)
0.79 (0.06)
0.58 (0.05)
0.52 (0.06)
0.52 (0.05)
0.70 (0.06)
0.91 (0.06)
0.91 (0.06)
0.16
21.33
Quintile ratio
2.49
3.30
1.28
0.46
0.93
1.53
1.24
0.77
-1.72
-69.00
CI
-0.196
-0.297
-0.124
0.045
-0.039
-0.083
-0.094
0.047
0.24*
-124.17
Weighted overshoot
0.90
TE D
Quintile ratio
Total
9.86 (0.57)
AC C
Mean positive overshoot
EP
Overshoot
1.02
0.65
0.50
0.54
0.76
1.00
0.87
-0.03
-3.37
9.59 (0.53)
9.03 (0.53)
8.86 (0.69)
8.46 (0.55)
7.94 (0.39)
10.03
9.11 (0.37)
-0.75
-7.61
(0.43)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
0.92
0.98
0.78
0.55
0.56
1.02
0.75
0.76
-0.16
-17.49
CI
-0.013
-0.027
0.019
0.083
0.069
-0.008
0.003
0.088
0.10*
-794.38
9.98
9.85
8.85
8.12
7.88
8.01
10.00
8.31
-1.67
-16.76
Weighted
mean
positive
overshoot
RI PT
Quintile ratio
SC
Note: Standard errors in parentheses.* P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with x2 test for headcount, t-test
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
following a fractional probit regression for overshoot and F-test for concentration index. CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
SC
2008
RI PT
Table 4. Changes in the distribution of incidence and intensity of CHE at 30% threshold of CTP, 2008-2015
Headcount
2014
2008-2015 2015
Absolute
Relative
change
change (%)
2.97 (0.28)
2.99 (0.28)
2.18 (0.26)
1.73 (0.25)
1.82 (0.23)
2.66 (0.30)
3.20 (0.25)
3.46 (0.27)
0.49
16.50
Quintile ratio
2.61
3.71
1.19
0.53
1.37
2.60
1.69
1.06
-1.55
-59.27
CI
-0.209
-0.325
-0.103
0.007
-0.094
-0.105
-0.144
0.035
0.24*
-116.93
Weighted headcount
3.59
3.96
2.40
1.72
1.99
2.94
3.66
3.34
-0.25
-7.01
Total
0.27 (0.03)
0.27 (0.04)
0.19 (0.03)
0.17 (0.03)
0.15 (0.03)
0.17 (0.02)
0.35 (0.03)
0.30 (0.03)
0.03
11.11
Quintile ratio
2.32
3.12
1.04
0.21
0.56
1.73
0.95
0.43
-1.89
-81.49
CI
-0.192
-0.291
-0.115
0.233
0.061
-0.061
-0.067
0.196
0.39*
-202.04
Weighted overshoot
0.32
0.35
0.21
0.13
0.14
0.18
0.37
0.24
-0.08
-25.00
9.92 (1.10)
8.02 (0.98)
6.59 (0.53)
11.03
8.80 (0.56)
-0.47
-5.07
Total
9.27 (0.79)
TE D
AC C
Mean positive overshoot
EP
Overshoot
9.05 (0.78)
M AN U
Total
8.75 (0.83)
(0.67)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
0.88
0.81
0.90
0.39
0.41
0.69
0.55
0.41
-0.47
-53.49
CI
0.010
0.022
-0.010
0.213
0.140
0.043
0.069
0.159
0.15
1419.39
9.17
8.85
8.84
7.81
6.90
6.31
10.26
7.40
-1.77
-19.32
Weighted
mean
positive
overshoot
RI PT
Quintile ratio
SC
Note: Standard errors in parentheses.* P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with x2 test for headcount, t-test
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
following a fractional probit regression for overshoot and F-test for concentration index. CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
SC
2008
RI PT
Table 5. Changes in the distribution of incidence and intensity of CHE at 40% threshold of CTP, 2008-2015
Headcount
2014
2008-2015 2015
Absolute
Relative
change
change (%)
1.03 (0.16)
1.05 (0.17)
0.78 (0.15)
0.59 (0.14)
0.49 (0.11)
0.57 (0.11)
1.34 (0.15)
1.19 (0.15)
0.16
15.53
Quintile ratio
2.09
2.12
0.80
0.21
0.51
0.68
1.49
0.44
-1.65
-79.07
CI
-0.156
-0.233
-0.091
0.188
0.058
0.043
-0.057
0.232
0.39*
-248.28
Weighted headcount
1.19
1.30
0.85
0.48
0.46
0.55
1.42
0.91
-0.28
-23.22
Total
0.09 (0.02)
0.09 (0.02)
0.06 (0.01)
0.06 (0.02)
0.04 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.14 (0.02)
0.09 (0.02)
0.00
0.00
Quintile ratio
1.75
2.57
0.73
0.05
0.21
1.50
0.50
0.17
-1.58
-90.15
CI
-0.168
-0.262
-0.046
0.541
0.263
0.021
0.015
0.365
0.53
-317.04
Weighted overshoot
0.11
0.11
0.06
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.14
0.06
-0.05
-45.64
10.67
8.65 (1.88)
4.83 (0.70)
10.13
7.68 (1.03)
-1.07
-12.23
Total
8.75 (1.29)
TE D
AC C
Mean positive overshoot
EP
Overshoot
8.51 (1.36)
M AN U
Total
7.35 (1.40)
(1.98)
(0.85)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
0.84
1.21
0.94
0.30
0.45
2.70
0.35
0.42
-0.42
-50.08
CI
-0.021
-0.038
0.078
0.297
0.184
-0.007
0.076
0.134
0.15
-737.49
8.93
8.83
6.78
7.50
7.06
4.86
9.36
6.65
-2.28
-25.52
Weighted
mean
positive
overshoot
RI PT
Quintile ratio
SC
Note: Standard errors in parentheses.* P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with x2 test for headcount, t-test
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
following a fractional probit regression for overshoot and F-test for concentration index. CHE, catastrophic health expenditure.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2008
0.915
2009
0.913
2010
0.923
2011
0.925
2012
0.928
2013
0.925
2014
0.911
2015
0.916
SC
FFCI
M AN U
Survey year
RI PT
Table 6. Changes in FFCI in OOPP, 2008-2015
AC C
EP
TE D
Note: FFCI, Financial Fairness Contribution index
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2009
2010
2011
Poverty headcount
Normalised poverty gap NGgross
2013
2014
2015
(0.01)
(0.02)
(0.01)
0.06
0.04
(0.04)
(0.03)
0.05
0.02
(0.03)
(0.02)
0.09
0.12
0.08
0.40
0.62
(0.05)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.28)
(0.41)
TE D
0.01
0.03
0.09
0.13
0.15
0.44
0.68
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.06)
(0.28)
(0.41)
0.02
0.00
0.01
0.07
0.04
0.06
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.01)
(0.04)
(0.02)
(0.05)
EP
PIH
0.02
AC C
Hnet
0.01
M AN U
Subsistence poverty
Hgross
2012
2008-2015
SC
2008
RI PT
Table 7. Changes in the poverty impact of OOPP, 2008-2015
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.01
0.02
0.13
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.02)
(0.09)
Absolute
Relative
change
change (%)
0.62*
8182.58
0.62*
994.07
0.00
6.16
0.13
26698.35
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.03
0.01
0.03
0.15
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.02)
(0.11)
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.02
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.02)
6.47
9.13
9.99
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
9.10
8.81
9.83
(3.00)
(3.97)
(3.26)
2.64
-0.32
Population being poor pre-payment
8.58
59.24
Poor population becoming poorer post-
19.80
71.62
PING
PINMPG
0.02
324.52
14.44
223.32
13.25
145.59
6.81
6.13
20.91
(1.57)
(6.56)
(1.25)
(4.36)
(6.96)
11.50
19.76
6.70
6.95
22.36
(2.77)
(5.94)
(0.73)
(4.29)
(9.08)
2.90
1.84
-0.11
0.82
1.45
-1.19
-45.08
27.23
74.80
82.28
55.48
80.16
71.58
834.27
8.58
29.83
0.00
25.20
14.49
6.56
0.00
-19.80
-100.00
19.80
10.93
72.77
0.00
3.23
37.95
19.84
-51.78
-72.30
71.62
-0.16
EP
AC C
Non-poor population becoming poor post-
2584.83
17.92
Contributors to total poverty gap (%)
payment
0.15
8.60
TE D
NMPGnet
M AN U
Normalised mean positive gap NMPGgross
RI PT
0.01
SC
NGnet
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Relative poverty Poverty headcount
PIH
24.13
29.93
40.27
(0.65)
(0.85)
(1.12)
(1.30)
(1.47)
14.82
16.72
24.77
(0.67)
(0.91)
(1.12)
0.99
1.64
0.64
(0.25)
(0.38)
(0.35)
3.06
3.11
(0.17)
(0.22)
NGnet
PING
AC C
NGgross
46.54
47.15
(1.69)
(1.32)
(1.28)
29.94
40.78
46.67
47.69
49.03
(1.31)
(1.47)
(1.66)
(1.35)
(1.25)
0.01
0.51
1.35
1.16
1.88
(0.32)
(0.30)
(0.43)
(0.36)
(0.41)
7.18
10.96
11.93
12.90
12.81
(0.29)
(0.38)
(0.50)
(0.64)
(0.54)
(0.58)
5.40
EP
Normalised poverty gap
45.32
SC
15.08
M AN U
Hnet
13.83
TE D
Hgross
RI PT
payment
3.44
3.59
5.66
7.27
11.05
12.46
13.42
13.42
(0.18)
(0.23)
(0.30)
(0.38)
(0.50)
(0.66)
(0.53)
(0.57)
0.38
0.48
0.26
0.09
0.09
0.54
0.52
0.61
33.32*
240.94
34.22*
230.92
0.89*
90.48
9.74*
318.14
9.98*
289.93
0.23
61.15
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
(0.05)
(0.06)
(0.05)
(0.06)
22.15
20.63
22.37
24.00
27.22
(0.78)
(0.84)
(0.70)
(0.64)
(0.65)
23.22
21.45
22.84
24.29
27.11
(0.75)
(0.80)
(0.68)
(0.65)
1.07
0.83
0.47
People leaving poverty
0.50
0.64
People staying in poverty
13.33
14.45
People entering poverty
1.49
2.28
Normalised mean positive gap
PINMPG
27.16
(0.81)
(0.64)
(0.76)
26.71
28.14
27.36
(0.65)
(0.83)
(0.61)
(0.74)
0.29
-0.11
0.39
0.43
0.94
1.26
1.04
1.02
23.18
28.67
39.24
1.58
1.27
AC C
EP
TE D
Population dynamics post-payment (%)
Contributors to total poverty gap (%)
(0.09)
27.71
5.01
22.64
4.14
17.83
0.20
-0.87
-81.31
1.44
1.13
0.62
124.54
44.30
45.09
46.03
32.70
245.32
1.55
2.37
2.60
3.00
1.52
101.95
SC
NMPGnet
(0.07)
26.32
M AN U
NMPGgross
(0.10)
RI PT
(0.05)
Population being poor pre-payment
75.49
72.50
81.11
85.33
87.62
84.02
85.25
84.31
8.83
11.69
Poor population becoming poorer post-
20.28
22.69
16.98
13.47
11.50
14.52
13.20
13.66
-6.62
-32.65
payment
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
4.23
4.81
1.90
1.20
0.88
payment
1.47
1.55
RI PT
Non-poor population becoming poor post-
2.03
-2.20
-52.07
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. OOPP, out-of-pocket payments. * P-value<0.05; mean difference between 2008 and 2015 was tested with
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
SC
x2 test for poverty headcount and t-test following a linear regression for poverty gap.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 8. Determinants of CHE of households at 40% threshold, 2008 vs. 2015 OR (SE)
Wald test of equality of ORs p-value
Northern Greece
1.628 (0.853)
0.679 (0.235)
0.164
Central Greece
1.770 (0.955)
0.610 (0.245)
0.114
Aegean islands, Crete
1.515 (0.956)
SC
Region (Attica as ref.)
2015
RI PT
2008
0.831 (0.374)
0.439
M AN U
Urbanicity (Urban as ref.) 2.172 (1.226)
1.618 (0.512)
0.649
Rural
2.257* (1.101)
1.415 (0.518)
0.444
Household size
0.516*** (0.098)
0.788** (0.078)
0.049
Elderly in household (no as ref.)
0.611 (0.347)
3.661*** (1.552)
0.012
24.075*** (17.982)
1.917 (1.704)
0.029
0.478* (0.193)
0.624 (0.215)
0.615
1.037** (0.019)
1.024* (0.014)
0.556
Primary education
0.413** (0.166)
1.308 (0.494)
0.037
Secondary education
0.473 (0.216)
0.484 (0.259)
0.974
Post-secondary non-tertiary
0.751 (0.832)
0.824 (0.614)
0.945
Tertiary education
0.682 (0.512)
0.141*** (0.099)
0.125
TE D
Semi-urban
Children under 5 in household (no as ref.)
EP
Sex of household head (males as ref,) Age of household head
AC C
Education of household head (no formal education as ref.)
Economic activity of household head
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
a
0.371 (0.321)
0.252
Retired
9.465*** (5.514)
0.313*** (0.137)
<0.001
Non-economically active
3.368* (2.362)
0.362 (0.233)
0.019
2
1.488 (0.719)
1.381 (0.446)
0.898
3
1.836 (0.835)
2.671*** (1.011)
0.526
4
1.53 (0.868)
8.675*** (3.433)
0.012
Richest
2.064 (1.209)
8.450*** (4.043)
0.062
0.657 (0.972)
1.836 (0.901)
0.510
0.289 (0.364)
b
0.325
Partially insured
a
a
Fully insured
a
0.273 (0.286)
0.216
Disable in household (no as ref.)
1.091 (0.959)
1.612 (0.960)
0.713
Constant
0.002*** (0.003)
0.004*** (0.004)
0.740
No of observations
3091
5835
Model F-statistic
F(23, 3068)=5.02,
F(24, 3844)=7.86,
p-value<0.01
p-value<0.01
0.137
0.106
RI PT
Unemployed
SC
(Employed as ref.)
Expenditure quintiles of household
Social insurance status of household (none insured as ref.)
Fully insured
TE D
Partially insured
M AN U
(poorest as ref.)
Private insurance status of household
AC C
EP
(none insured as ref.)
Pseudo-R2
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Hosmer-Lemeshow
goodness-of-fit
test
x2(8)=12.699,
x2(8)=8.52,
p-value=0.123
p-value=0.384
Joint tests of ORs
<0.01
RI PT
Note: a All observations with no CHE; b all observations with CHE. * P-value<0.1; * p-value<0.05; *** p-value<0.01. OR, odds ratio; SE, standard error; CHE,
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
SC
catastrophic health expenditure.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 9. Determinants of impoverishment due to OOPP of households (relative poverty), 2008 vs. 2015 OR (SE)
Wald test of equality of ORs p-value
1.371 (0.576)
0.963 (0.203)
0.452
Central Greece
1.488 (0.635)
0.705 (0.233)
0.166
Aegean islands, Crete
1.535 (0.762)
0.982 (0.273)
0.433
M AN U
Northern Greece
SC
Region (Attica as ref.)
2015
RI PT
2008
Urbanicity (Urban as ref.) Semi-urban
1.272 (0.570)
1.196 (0.262)
0.901
Rural
0.813 (0.302)
1.851** (0.459)
0.065
0.631** (0.138)
0.960 (0.086)
0.077
TE D
Household size Elderly in household (no as ref.)
1.350 (0.744)
3.810*** (1.251)
0.106
Children under 5 in household (no as
4.510** (3.253)
1.502 (0.701)
0.200
Sex of household head (males as ref,)
0.479** (0.161)
0.955 (0.191)
0.078
Age of household head
1.013 (0.013)
1.014* (0.008)
0.938
Primary education
0.542* (0.174)
1.357 (0.284)
0.017
Secondary education
0.429* (0.191)
1.417 (0.364)
0.020
Post-secondary non-tertiary
0.921 (0.782)
2.899** (1.253)
0.229
Tertiary education
0.344 (0.358)
1.146 (0.456)
0.280
AC C
EP
ref.)
Education of household head (no formal education as ref.)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Economic activity of household head (Employed as ref.) 0.421 (0.460)
2.006* (0.833)
0.182
Retired
1.29 (0.692)
0.779 (0.261)
0.425
Non-economically active
1.818 (1.030)
1.093 (0.416)
0.456
2
1.405 (0.410)
1.551** (0.276)
0.771
3
0.092*** (0.059)
0.216*** (0.094)
0.272
4
0.037*** (0.039)
0.056*** (0.058)
Richest
a
a
RI PT
Unemployed
Expenditure quintiles of household
(none insured as ref.)
0.782
1.823 (2.393)
1.821 (1.166)
1.000
1.785 (1.832)
2.150 (1.186)
0.873
0.302 (0.316)
0.727 (0.766)
0.554
a
1.021 (0.763)
0.978
Disable in household (no as ref.)
1.059 (0.686)
0.915 (0.411)
0.854
Constant
0.030*** (0.042)
0.003*** (0.002)
0.120
No of observations
2761
5833
Model F-statistic
F(24, 2737)=3.33,
F(25, 3843)=6.07,
p-value<0.01
p-value<0.01
Fully insured
TE D
Partially insured
M AN U
Social insurance status of household
SC
(poorest as ref.)
EP
Private insurance status of household (none insured as ref.)
AC C
Partially insured Fully insured
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Pseudo-R2 Hosmer-Lemeshow
goodness-of-fit
test
0.158
0.099
x2(8)=7.19,
x2(8)=8.36,
p-value=0.516
p-value=0.399
0.208
RI PT
Joint tests of ORs
Note: a All observations were not impoverished. * P-value<0.1; ** p-value<0.05; ***
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
SC
p-value<0.01. OR, odds ratio; SE, standard error; OOPP, out-of-pocket payments.
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
SC
RI PT
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Research highlights
AC C
EP
TE D
M AN U
SC
• • • •
Both incidence and overshoot of catastrophic out-of-pocket payments (OOPP) have increased considerably The additional catastrophic burden has been distributed progressively Both incidence and intensity of relative poverty have increased significantly 1.9% of households were impoverished due to OOPP in 2015 The catastrophic and poverty impact of OOPP is rising since 2012
RI PT
•