Government Protection, Political Connection and Management Turnover in China Louis T.W. Cheng, T.Y. Leung PII: DOI: Reference:
S1059-0560(16)30045-4 doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2016.03.010 REVECO 1261
To appear in:
International Review of Economics and Finance
Received date: Revised date: Accepted date:
26 January 2015 22 February 2016 1 March 2016
Please cite this article as: Cheng, L.T.W. & Leung, T.Y., Government Protection, Political Connection and Management Turnover in China, International Review of Economics and Finance (2016), doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2016.03.010
This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Government Protection, Political Connection and Management Turnover in China
Government Protection, Political Connection
RI P
T
and Management Turnover in China
MA
NU
SC
Louis T. W. Cheng* School of Accounting and Finance Hong Kong Polytechnic University Hong Kong Tel: (852) 2766 7140 Fax: (852) 2356 9550 E-mail address:
[email protected]
AC
CE
PT
ED
T. Y. Leung LSK School of Business and Administration Open University of Hong Kong Hong Kong Tel: (852) 2768 6949 Fax: (852) 2391 9095 E-mail address:
[email protected]
* corresponding author Highlights strategic firms perform better than non-strategic firms strategic firms employ top managers with different demographic profiles strategic firms are more likely to have management turnovers turnovers are less frequent if the chairpersons and CEOs are politically-connected
0
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Abstract
T
Mainland Chinese government employs two related strategies to protect its national
protection to industries of national interest.
It grants government
RI P
and economic interests in the process of financial liberalization.
In addition, it also maintains
We argue these strategic firms with economic and national interests
NU
strategic firms.
SC
political-linkage with certain firms to assert their influence. We term these firms as
demonstrate better performance and higher management turnovers.
Management
MA
turnovers are less frequent if the chairpersons and CEOs are politically-connected.
ED
The strategic firms also rebound better from financial distress than non-strategic firms.
PT
Keywords: political connection; government protection; management turnover; strategic firm
AC
CE
JEL: G32; G34; G38
1
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Government Protection, Political Connection and Management Turnover in China 1. Introduction
T
In the past two decades, China has become a successful case in expanding its economic
RI P
presence through listing its firms on the stock markets in Mainland and overseas.
To privatize
state-own assets that have investment value to investors while maintaining effective control and
The process of privatization can be a lengthy one and
NU
& Poulsen, 2004; Sun & Tong, 2003).
SC
influence is a delicate matter (Jones, Megginson, Nash, & Netter, 1999; Megginson, Nash, Netter,
the financial benefit to the firm is reflected by the trade-off between government guarantee and
MA
performance improvement being completely privatized (Borisova & Megginson, 2011). Economist (2012) suggests that state enterprises in China have become more productive and
ED
the government has become a more sophisticated owner.
Even for non-state firms, the In
PT
government strategically offers its patronage if these private firms appear to be a winner.
short, the Chinese government uses a portfolio of sophisticated techniques to maintain control to
CE
the listed firms, no matter they are state-owned or privately-owned.
AC
Among many tools to control the listed firms, two interesting practices in China related to maintaining political control capture our attention. national security interest as protected industries.
First, China classifies certain industries of Under such a government protection, these
firms get business and financial advantages from government but subject to foreign ownership restriction.
Second, in order to protect national security and economic interests, the Chinese
government deploys political connection to certain firms through the top management and directors, which is another common phenomenon in China.
While politically connected firms
and protected firms possess different characteristics and behave differently due to industry
2
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT structure and other factors, these two types of firms are important channels developed by the Chinese government to pursue certain national economic and political interest.1
T
We strongly believe that Chinese central government has a long-term national agenda to
the cooperation of all kinds of firms.
RI P
pursue economic stability and stable growth for the country. These agenda sometimes demand We call them strategic firms.
Depending on the nature
We realize that these two groups of firms have different
NU
industry and political connection.
SC
of the national interest, the forms of implementation are mainly through two channels: protected
characteristics. However, we argue that despite these differences, if the national strategy of
MA
managing these firms for national interest does exist, then we should expect certain common impacts on performance, management turnover, and reaction under distress.
We acknowledge
However, this is a worthwhile research questions to be examined for academic to better
PT
theory.
ED
that our classification of these two groups of firms into some category can be controversial in
understand the relationship between Chinese firms and the government.
CE
The idea of industry protection is related to privatization.
In order to protect its natural
AC
resources and state assets through the privatization process, governments of developing countries often make use of industry protection to reduce the impact from foreign competition and to protect ownership. The various effects of privatization are well documented (Jones et al., 1999; Megginson et al., 2004) and recently the issue of political connection has already formed its own literature (Boubakri, Guedhami, Mishra, & Saffar, 2012; Faccio, 2006).
In management
research, industry protection can be interpreted as a special kind of corporate resource under the
1
We understand that this grouping is debatable. Each firm has its own unique feature yet at the same time possesses some common characteristics (e.g., commonly used characteristics to group firms are industry, firm size, market to book). Thus, we can still use these common characteristics to group firms for a certain research issue even though these firms may not be similar in all other aspects.
3
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT resource based view of firms (RBV) (Barney, 1991; Teece, Pisano, & Shuen, 1997) while the human capital of networking is documented under the guanxi literature (Park & Luo, 2001).
T
In this study, we argue that governments of developing countries employ two related
RI P
strategies to protect their national security interest and economic interest through listed firms. We define firms as strategic firms if the firms are in the industries under government
SC
protection/regulation or if the firms are politically connected.
First, there are many reasons a
NU
country wants to protect certain industries (Hillman, 1982; Melitz, 2005). Such protected firms enjoy certain business advantages in terms of receiving government contracts and/or lower cost Second, a country can also deploy politically connected CEOs and board members
MA
of capital.
to keep a tight control on certain firms.
As emerging Asian countries, such as China, are
ED
well-known for their relationship-driven business style and strong government influence in
relationship.
PT
business and financial sectors, political connection is regarded as a very important business Thus, companies indeed welcome politically connected executives and board
CE
members even though such relationships come with a price of sub-optimal business decisions
AC
due to government influence at times. While this second strategy may not be as effective and direct as the first approach, it allows the government to pinpoint certain firms instead of the whole industries for strategic reasons. We conjecture that government protection and political connection are being used by developing countries such as China to achieve an overall control in listed firms.
Consequently,
these strategic firms are expected to perform better financially, employ top managers with certain characteristics and skill sets, and demonstrate different turnover patterns compared with non-strategic firms.
4
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Clearly, strategic firms need to appoint top managers who are willing and able to pursue political agenda if needed and increase shareholders’ wealth at the same time.
Such a
T
dual-objective requirement leads to a series of interesting empirical questions: Q1. What kind of
RI P
financial performance do these strategic firms demonstrate? Q2. What is the management turnover for strategic firms compared with non-strategic firms? Q3. When a firm is in financial
SC
trouble, what happen to the top managers of strategic firms? and lastly Q4. What is the
NU
post-turnover financial performance of strategic firms compared with non-strategic firms? Based on the literature and empirical questions stated above, we propose that 1) strategic
non-strategic firms.
MA
firms enjoying business and financial privileges have better financial performance relative to 2) Management turnover of strategic firms is subject to political decisions
ED
of government, leading to a different pattern relative to that of non-strategic firms.
3) Top
PT
managers of strategic firms with political ties are less likely to be replaced during financial distress.
4) Based on the conjecture that the financial well-being of strategic firms is protected
Our sample period covers eight years from 2001 to 2008.
We include all (but
AC
difficulty.
CE
by the government, we expect a speedy financial rebound of strategic firms after their financial
except financial) firms listed on the Shanghai Stock Exchange and Shenzhen Stock Exchange. The data on company returns, financial statements, board characteristics and ownership come from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database. and then classify the political connection data from the annual reports.
We hand-collect
There are a total of
7,959 observations in our sample. Our results show that strategic firms perform better financially compared with non-strategic firms.
Next, we examine top management turnovers and find that strategic firms are more
likely to have top management turnovers. We argue that turnover decisions of strategic firms
5
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT are somewhat influenced by political agenda of the government.
Thus the more frequent
turnover of strategic firms may be politically-driven and not be related to traditional
T
market-driven rationales such as moving to a higher pay job or being fired due to poor
RI P
performance.
We also find that after management turnover due to financial crisis, strategic firms In addition, there is no relation between the demographic
SC
outperform non-strategic firms.
We conjecture that this result is
NU
profile of top managers and post-turnover performance.
consistent with our argument that strategic firm performance is more related to its government
MA
protection and connection and less related to management leadership and ability when facing crisis.
ED
Following this section is background and hypotheses. Section 3 describes the research We conclude the study in Section 5.
PT
method. The results are presented in Section 4.
CE
2. Background and Hypotheses
AC
We argue that both guanxi and political connection literature supports our conjecture that political connection has been used as a channel for the mainland government to promote corporate China. First, the guanxi literature documents that in China, guanxi is a network of interpersonal ties and social connections that businesses use to exchange favors in order to achieve objectives. Social ties have been found to affect market and financial performance positively in emerging economies (Li, Poppo, & Zhou, 2008). Clearly, guanxi is useful to conduct business and marketing activities in China (Ambler, Styles, & Wang, 1999). political connection is a special type of guanxi.
In fact,
Peng and Luo (2000) define political ties as
informal social connections with officials in various levels of administration in the governments
6
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT (central, state or local) and regulatory agencies (tax authorizes, securities commission, stock exchange etc). Therefore, based on the past success of mainland government in employing
T
political influence to its advantage, using politically connected board directors and senior
RI P
management to influence business strategies at firm level would be expected. In addition, Calomiris, Fisman, and Wang (2010) show that the stock market assures the value of political They find that firms led by former government
SC
connection over the benefits of state ownership.
NU
officials experience positive market reaction to the disposal announcement of government shares in China.
MA
Some anecdotal evidence of such practice can be observed.
For instance, The Economist
(2012) reports that the Mainland government, through different means, provide support to
ED
industrial sectors or firms which have potential for success.
Lenovo Group Limited (Lenovo) is
PT
a typical example of a “national champion” being created through the usage of political connection. While Lenovo is not a SOE, its founders are well connected politically because
CE
they are members of a unit of Chinese Academy of Science (i.e., an institution of the State
AC
Council of China), which provides the seed money for the establishment of Lenovo.
In addition,
the leading founder of Lenovo, Liu Chuanzhi, was a representative of National People’s Congress for several years.
When it acquired IBM’s personal-computer division for US$1.25
billion in 2004”, the government was providing support behind the scene. According to Gartner (2013), Lenovo overtook HP as the number one personal computer vendor as of the third quarter sales of 20132, and political connection serves as an important element in the success of Lenovo. In finance, the issue of protected industry is explored under the privatization literature (Jones et al., 1999; Megginson et al., 2004).
The management literature also examines similar
2
Source: “Gartner says worldwide PC shipments in the third quarter of 2013 declined 8.6 percent”, Gartner, October 2013, http://www.gartner.com/newsroom/id/2604616
7
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT empirical issue on protected industries but is labeled under the resource based view of firms (RBV) (Barney, 1991; Teece et al., 1997) while the human capital of networking is documented
T
under the guanxi literature (Park & Luo, 2001).
RI P
In many developing countries (such as Brazil, India, and Malaysia)3 especially China, certain industries (e.g., energy, raw materials, petrochemicals) are under government protection.
SC
Nee, Opper, and Wong (2007) argue that the Chinese central government retains control over the
telecommunications, and energy.
NU
firms in the strategically and politically important industries, which include utilities, Bass and Chakrabarty (2014) develop the resource security
MA
theory to argue that ownership affects resource acquisition.
They suggest that
government-owners are most concerned with securing their country’s future and focus more on The firms in the protected industries are usually large monopolies, able to
ED
resource exploration.
PT
receive subsidies and special treatment (e.g., less stringent profitability requirement in new equity issues) and under direct control of the State Council (Aharony, Lee, & Wong, 2000).
In
CE
addition, there are some industries which are under special government regulation with In short, putting firms in protected
AC
restriction on share ownership (Sun & Tong, 2003).
industries and regulated industries can be viewed as a government strategy and an effective way to protect a country’s security and economic interests. In fact, the literature has clearly documented that politically connected firms enjoy certain competitive advantages.
There are a number of studies showing that politically connected firms
have better performance (e.g., Cooper, Gulen, & Ovtchinnikov, 2010; Fisman, 2001). Besides, firms having political connections can also enjoy other advantages including securing government contracts and property right protection; getting preferential tax treatment; and access
3
For example, automobile industry is protected in Malaysia; computer industry is protected in Brazil in the 1990s; telecommunication, heavy machinery and renewable energy are protected in India.
8
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT to cheaper finance through political networks (Claessens, Feijen, & Laeven, 2008; Goldman, Rocholl, & So, 2009).
Also, Su, Fung, Huang, and Shen (2014) report that politically
T
connected firms pay higher cash dividends because they can obtain more government support.
RI P
According to the RBV theory in management, the ties through “political connections” should be considered as a valuable resource to attain competitive advantage. Boddewyn and
In the managerial networking literature, Burt (1997) suggests that
NU
difficult for others to imitate.
SC
Brewer (1994) argue that the capability to develop ties with political actors is a resource which is
social ties and contacts of top executives with external entities can reduce transaction costs
MA
through exchange of resources, information and knowledge.
In addition, Holburn and Zelner
(2010) show that firms with political resources and capabilities can lobby policy for their own
ED
benefits and protect their investments against adverse policy changes and political rent-seeking
PT
behavior of competitors.
Specifically, a few studies examine Chinese data and show these advantages as well.
Li
CE
and Atuahene-Gima (2001) argue that political networking is a unique resource in the
AC
transitional economy of China. Peng and Luo (2000) find that managerial networks with local and government officials allow the new ventures and firms to have better performance in China. Park and Luo (2001) show that the Chinese firms use “guanxi” as a strategic mechanism to overcome the competitive disadvantage by exchanging favors with government authorities. There have been a number of studies examining the relation between management turnover and performance.
In the finance and accounting literature, human resources are regarded as
firm (intangible) assets (Lajili & Zéghal, 2006). to the disposal of a corporate asset.
Therefore, dismissal of an employee is similar
According to the agency theory, top management is
9
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT accountable for firm performance and replacement of poorly performing staff is an essential element of effective governance (Fama, 1980; Shleifer & Vishny, 1997).
T
Many studies have shown that poor performance is related to forced turnovers, particularly
RI P
in countries where there is strong law enforcement (DeFond & Hung, 2004; Huson, Parrino, & Starks, 2001). CEO turnover is negatively related to firm performance measured by stock price
SC
and accounting performance indicators and the sensitivity between performance and turnover is
NU
the greatest in smaller firms (Murphy, 1999). Jenter and Kanaan (2015) find a higher probability of forced CEO turnover when there are declines in market and industry performance. Parrino,
MA
Sias and Starks (2003) show a negative relation between institutional ownership changes and likelihood of forced CEO turnover. Besides past performance, expected performance is also
ED
relevant in CEO turnover decision. Farrell and Whidbee (2003) show CEO replacement is related
PT
to forecasted 5-year EPS growth and dispersion in analyst forecasts. There are some studies showing that after forced turnover, there is improved performance (Huson, Malatesta, & Parrino,
CE
2004; McNeil, Niehaus, & Powers, 2004).
Yuan (2011) shows there is a lower sensitivity between
AC
management turnover in China.
Several studies have been conducted on top
turnover and firm performance for politically connected CEOs in SOEs.
Most studies show
that managerial turnover (chairperson or CEO) is related to pre-turnover firm performance (Chang & Wong, 2009; Firth, Fung, & Rui, 2006). performance, the results are mixed.
In the examination of post-turnover
Groves, Hong, McMillan, and Naughton (1995) find an
increase in productivity after managerial turnover while Firth et al. (2006) provide no evidence of improvement in post-turnover performance.
Chang and Wong (2009) show that only
loss-making firms, but not profit-making firms, have post-turnover profitability improvement. In short, based on the literature on protected industry, political connection, and management
10
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT turnover, we construct four hypotheses to test our empirical questions stated earlier.
T
2.1 Hypothesis Development
RI P
In this study, we argue that government protection and appointing politically connected top managers/board members together form a unified proactive strategy of the government in A country can protect its natural
SC
protecting its economic interests through listed firms.
NU
resources from being exploited by foreign countries through barriers of ownership and trade. By doing so, these protected firms also enjoy certain business advantages in terms of receiving
MA
government contracts and/or lower cost of capital.
Similar protection practice is also observed
in industries that are related to technology relevant to national defense (e.g., telecommunications,
ED
airlines). Another category of protected industry is those facing difficulty in competing against
PT
more mature and bigger foreign firms.
As shown in previous studies, government protection status is commonly granted for natural
However, political connection can be employed for firms of both national security
AC
interest.
CE
resources and technology intensive industries when a country mainly wants to protect its security
interest and economic interest.
The literature on political connection has documented clearly
the possibility of better performance and enjoying competitive advantage.
Consequently,
politically connected firms could perform better than non-connected firms. Our approach of consolidating government protection and political connection into the government’s strategic positioning framework is consistent with the ‘‘grabbing hand’’ argument of Shleifer and Vishny (1998) that politicians extract resources from listed SOEs under their control
to
fulfill
certain
political
agenda
11
other
than
maximizing
firm
value.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Government-owners are most concerned with securing their country’s future and focus more on resource exploration as a national strategy (Bass & Chakrabarty, 2014).
T
Fan, Wong, and Zhang (2007) show that in China, the right of the government to appoint These strategic firms may
RI P
CEOs significantly impairs firm performance and board governance.
not pursue value maximization all the time due to the boundary of national security and
SC
economic interests comes first when the two objectives lead to conflicting decisions.
NU
Nevertheless, strategic firms get business advantages (Agrawal & Knoeber, 2001) as well as cheaper and preferential financing as a reward/compensation from the government (Boubakri et Politically connected firms can lobby policy for their own benefits
MA
al., 2012; Cull & Xu, 2005).
and protect their investments against adverse policy changes and political rent-seeking behavior
ED
of competitors (Holburn & Zelner, 2010).
These competitive advantages exist in the forms of
PT
securing government contracts and property right protection; getting favorable tax treatment; and obtaining cheaper and preferential financing (Boubakri et al., 2012; Claessens et al., 2008; Cull
CE
& Xu, 2005; Goldman et al., 2009). Based on our argument that strategic firms enjoying
AC
business and financial privileges, we hypothesize that:
H1: Strategic firms demonstrate better financial performance relative to non-strategic firms.
Fan et al. (2007) suggest that firms appointing politically connected top managers and directors may exhibit rent-seeking behavior, their appointment and possibly turnover decisions for chairperson/CEO can be driven by different criteria (i.e., more than maximizing shareholder’s wealth).
In addition, Shen, Lin and Wang (2015) find it is more likely for
politically connected firms to demonstrate poor governance practice.
12
Clearly the CEO/board
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT member appointment in the strategic firms under the heavy influence of the government is a form of strategic decision.
We expect that management turnover of strategic firms is subject to
T
political decisions of government, which is exogenous and not always related to performance,
RI P
therefore:
SC
H2a: Strategic firms demonstrate a different pattern of management turnover relative to that of
NU
non-strategic firms.
H2b: Top managers of strategic firms with political ties are less likely to be replaced even during
MA
financial distress.
ED
Our third hypothesis is constructed to explore the possible difference in post-turnover
PT
performance of strategic and non-strategic firms facing financial distress. One of the major reasons for forced top management turnover is poor performance (DeFond & Hung, 2004; Huson These firms aim to improve performance after the replacement of
CE
et al., 2001).
Huson et al. (2004), among others, have shown that there
AC
poorly-performing top management.
is improved performance after forced turnover using the US data. Also, Chang and Wong (2009) show post-turnover profitability improvement in loss-making firms.
Therefore, based
on the conjecture that the financial well-being of strategic firms is protected by the government, we expect a speedier financial rebound of strategic firms after their financial difficulty for the strategic sample relative to their counterpart.
H3: Post-turnover performance improvement for financially distress firms is better for strategic firms than for non-strategic firms.
13
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
3. Sample and Variables
T
Our study covers a sample period from 2001 to 2008. The sample includes all firms
RI P
(except those in the finance sector) listed on the Shanghai Stock Exchange and Shenzhen Stock Exchange. We obtain our data on company returns, financial statements, board characteristics
SC
and ownership data from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database.
NU
We hand-collect the data of political connections from the annual reports. Our poor performing firm sample comes from two sources. We define poorly performing
MA
firms as those firms which are a) under the special treatment (ST) listing status due to regulation violation as well as inappropriate corporate behavior4 and b) have poor performance of negative
ED
returns, negative return on assets and negative change in return on assets in the turnover year.
PT
The special treatment announcement is a unique mandatory reporting requirement imposed by China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) on January 1, 1998 that when the firms have
CE
abnormality in the financial conditions, the Shanghai Stock Exchange and Shenzhen Stock
AC
Exchange have to announce that the firms are under special treatment and their short stock names are to be tagged with “ST” to alert the investors that the stocks may have the risk of delisting. The ST data come from the Corporate Governance file of CSMAR.
3.1 Defining Protected Industry and Political Connection In China, a number of industries (e.g., energy, raw materials, petrochemicals) are under government protection.
Nee et al. (2007) argue that the Chinese central government retains
4
Cheng, Leung, and Yu (2014, p. 71) provide detailed description of inappropriate corporate behaviors, which include two consecutive years of losses and/or asset shrinkage, ,adverse audit opinion on financial statements, a shrinkage of rights and interest, operation impairment or halt, major lawsuits, bankruptcy, violation of information disclosure rule, and investment risk.
14
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT control over the firms in the strategically and politically important industries, which include utilities, telecommunications and energy. We term these industries as protected industries.
T
The firms in the protected industries are usually large monopolies, able to receive subsidies and
direct control of the State Council (Aharony et al., 2000).
RI P
special treatment (e.g., less stringent profitability requirement in new equity issues) and under In addition, there are some industries
SC
which are under special government regulation with restriction on share ownership (Sun & Tong,
NU
2003). These industries include utilities, energy, telecommunication and finance. Although these industries are under more government regulation and intervention, the firms in these
industries as regulated industries.
MA
industries also receive more government support and have less competition. We term these In short, we group the firms in protected industries and
ED
regulated industries as firms possessing national security interest.
PT
Holburn and Zelner (2010) define political resources as stocks of available political factors to which the firm gains access, primarily ties with pivotal political actors such as government
CE
officials and interest groups that seek to influence them. Faccio (2006, p. 369) classifies a firm
AC
as politically connected if at least one of its large shareholders (holding at least 10 percent of voting shares directly or indirectly) or one of its top directors (chairperson, CEO, president, vice-president or secretary) is a member of parliament, or a minister, or is closely related to a top politician or party.5
Fan et al. (2007) define politically connected CEOs as those who serve as
current or former government bureaucrats (current or former officers of central or local governments or the military).
In this study, we follow a similar sprit to define a connected firm
but employ a more diversified measure by requiring a certain political connection for three board members.
5
Close relationship is defined to include friendship, former heads of state or prime ministers, past directorship held, foreign politicians or long-standing relationships with political parties.
15
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT By political connection, since chairpersons, CEOs and directors are all full-time positions in a firm, these executives are defined as having political connections if they were (not currently are,
T
as they cannot hold two full-time positions) formerly government officials. In addition, they also
RI P
have political connections if they are current members of People’s Congress and/or People Political Consultative Conference (PPCC) (these are honorary and part-time positions).
We
716 politically connected firms.
This definition of political connection yields
NU
chairperson or CEO being politically connected.
SC
categorize a firm as politically connected if the firm has at least two directors with either the
By changing this definition to at least three directors with
MA
either the chairperson or CEO being connected and at least one director with either chairperson or CEO being connected; the overall sub-sample sizes with political connection become 382 and We determine that in order to identify firms with sufficient political
ED
1,266, respectively.
PT
connection strength, the criterion of at least one director with either chairperson or CEO being connected may not be strong enough while at least three directors with either chairperson or
CE
CEO being connected results in too small a sub-sample size for analysis, especially for the forced
AC
turnover analysis focusing on poor performing firms in Tables 4 and 5. Consequently, we adopt the criterion of at least two directors with either chairperson or CEO being connected as our definition of political connection. Using this approach, we have a total of 716 politically connected firms out of 7,959 observations in our sample. Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics of the variables. which 1,590 are strategic firms.
We have 7,959 observations, of
Further decomposition of the strategic firm sample shows
1,095 protected firms and 716 connected firms, within which, 222 firms are both protected and connected.
The chairperson and CEO have a mean tenure of 3.88 years and 3.27 years,
respectively. The chairpersons (mean age = 49.83) are older than the CEOs (mean age = 45.94).
16
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT The chairpersons and CEOs are similar in their education levels, with 3.64 and 3.59 years of schooling, respectively.
The firms have a mean board size of 9.8 directors. The board has a
T
median of about one-third of independent directors. The directors hold small shareholding
1,579 are central SOEs and 4,033 are local SOEs.
RI P
percentage (1.58%). There are 1,081 firms with CEO duality. Out of 7,959 observations, In these 5,612 SOE observations, only 600
SC
(10.7%) are classified as connected firms (as the remaining 116 connected firms are non-SOEs).
NU
There are 1,366 and 1,791 firms replacing their chairpersons and CEOs, respectively. In our subsample of 896 poor performing firm observations, 410 firms experience top For these poorly performing firms, the mean ROA∆, mean Ret∆ and
MA
management turnovers.
mean MB∆ are -0.1085, -0.1098 and -0.9305, respectively.
4. Empirical Results
CE
4.1 Regression Models
PT
ED
[Insert Table 1 here]
AC
We have the following regression models to test our hypotheses. ROA/Ret/MB = 0 + 1 Strategic + 2 Board(Control) + 3 Firm(Control) + t tYeart + j j Industryj
(1)
CHTurn/CEOTurn = 0 + 1 Strategic + 2 Strategic*PC + 3 DemoV + 4 Board(Control) + 4 Firm(Control) + t tYeart + j j Industryj
(2)
ROA∆/Ret∆/MB∆ = 0 + 1 Strategic + 2 DemoV + 3 Board(Control) + 4 Firm(Control) + t tYeart + j j Industryj
17
(3)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Performance is measured in terms of annual stock return (Ret), market-to-book ratio (MB) and return on assets (ROA). We classify those firms in the industry sectors of finance6, utilities,
Next, if the firms have at least two directors, and either the chairperson
RI P
and special regulation.
T
energy, telecommunications, natural resources, and mass media as under government protection
or CEO are politically connected, they are labeled as connected firms. There are 611 connected
SC
chairperson observations and 285 connected CEO observations (out of which 180 strategic firms
NU
have connected chairpersons and CEOs at the same time) in our strategic sample. Using this approach, we have a total of 1,095 protected and 716 connected firm
sample (1,590 observations).
MA
observations (out of which 222 have dual identity).
Together, it constitutes our Strategic
There are 600 observations out of 5,612 SOE observations
ED
(10.7%) or a total sample of 7,959 (7.5%) are classified as connected firms. Such percentages
Mainland government.
PT
indicate that not all SOEs are strategically positioned through political connection by the Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under
CE
government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise.
Protected is a
AC
dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation and 0 otherwise. PC is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a politically connected firm and 0 otherwise. CHTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson is replaced and 0 otherwise.
CEOTurn is a
dummy coded 1 if the CEO is replaced and 0 otherwise. Replacement of poorly performing top management is an essential element of effective governance (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997) and also an important step for improvement.
McNeil
et al. (2004) and Huson et al. (2004) have shown that there is improved performance after forced turnover.
Barney (1991) suggests that the difference in resource endowments explains the
6
In our sample, we exclude firms in the finance sector. Therefore, although firms in the finance sector are classified as firms under government protection and special regulation, they are not included in the analysis.
18
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT difference in performance.
If we argue that the business advantages and protection enjoyed by
the strategic firms is a form of resources, then post-turnover performance should be related to
Ret is the change in return (year +1 minus year -1).
SC
year -1).
ROA is the change in return on assets (year +1 minus
RI P
measuring post-turnover performance.
T
political connection and government protection. We have three performance indicators for
market-to-book ratio (year +1 minus year -1).
Cheng, Chan and Leung (2010)
NU
We control for management demography in our analysis.
MB is the change in
show that management demography (e.g., age, education) and relational demographic differences
MA
between chairperson and CEO may affect financial performance (earnings per share, return on assets, market-to-book ratio and abnormal return) in Chinese firms.
If a firm would optimize
ED
the combination of the strategic position (government protection and political connections) and
PT
management capability, then the management demographic profile of strategic firms should be different from those of non-strategic firms. DemoV is the group of demographic variables of CH and CEO are the prefixes to represent the characteristics of
CE
chairperson and CEO.
Ten is the number of years staying in office.
Age is the
AC
chairpersons and CEOs, respectively. age. Edu is the number of schooling.7
We also control for the relational demography of top management team (TMT) (Chan et al., 2010).
These variables include DiffTen, which is the differential tenure of chairperson minus
that of CEO. DiffAge is the net value of the age of chairperson minus that of CEO.
DiffEdu is
the net number of schooling of chairperson minus that of CEO. In corporate finance, turnover is related to performance and governance.
Coles,
McWilliams, and Sen (2001), in the examination of the relation of governance mechanism and 7
For the number of schooling, we use three years for college education, four years for university education, six years for master degree and nine years for Ph.D degree.
19
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT performance, imply that the effectiveness of corporate governance mechanism is difficult to be identified and measured.
Removal of poorly performing CEO is a necessary condition of good
T
governance, and hence turnover-performance sensitivity is a measure of governance quality Volpin (2002) and DeFond and Hung (2004) suggest that the firms
RI P
(Shleifer & Vishny, 1997).
which do not dismiss the poorly performing management have weak governance. DirIndR is the proportion of independent
SC
We have four variables for Board(Control).
Borokhovich, Parrino,
NU
directors to board size, which is our measure of board independence.
and Trapani (1996) find that the likelihood of executive turnover (voluntary and forced)
MA
increases monotonically with the percentage of independent directors. percentage of shares held by directors to total shares.
DirHold is the
Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue that
Chen (2014) and Cheng et al. (2010) argue that board size is related to
PT
reduce agency cost.
ED
awarding shares to top management helps align the interests of managers and shareholders to
Therefore, we include BoardSize, which is the number
of directors on board in our models.
CEO duality is related to turnover and probability of
CE
corporate performance and governance.
Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and
AC
financial distress (Simpson & Gleason, 1999). CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. We have six variables for Firm(Control).
CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a
state-owned enterprise (SOE) controlled by central government and 0 otherwise.
LocalSOE is a
dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or county government and 0 otherwise.
Aharony et al. (2000) report that firms in protected industries are
state monopolies under direct control of State Council and Firth et al. (2006) find that turnover-performance sensitivity is higher for firms with major shareholders being legal entities. ROA is return on assets.
DA is debt to asset ratio.
20
LnAsset is log of total assets.
FirmAge is
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT the number of years the firm is established.
Jensen (1986) suggests that leverage is a corporate
governance measure as debtors also play a role in disciplining managers. We use firm size
In addition, large firms have more resource advantage than small firms (Barney,
RI P
larger firms.
T
(LnAsset) as a control as Dalton and Kesner (1983) find that managers are more entrenched in
SC
1991).
NU
4.2 Results for Hypothesis 1 (H1)
Aharony et al. (2000) show that the firms in protected industries are usually large
MA
monopolies, able to receive subsidies and special treatment (e.g., less stringent profitability requirement in new equity issues) from the government support and have less competition.
ED
Studies on political connections also document that politically connected firms have better
PT
performance (e.g., Cooper et al., 2010; Fisman, 2001) and enjoy various benefits (e.g., Goldman et al., 2009). Therefore, we expect the strategic firms (Strategic) with government protection
CE
and political connection should perform better.
In Table 2, we report the results for firm
AC
performance in terms of return on assets (ROA), stock price return (Ret) and market-to-book ratio (MB). Consistent with our expectation, the coefficients on Strategic are positively related to ROA (0.011), Ret (0.064) and MB (0.437), all significant at 0.01 level.
We have also conducted
our performance analysis using dummies for protected firms (Protected) and connected firms (PC) separately.
Except for the coefficient on PC in the run of regression for ROA, the
coefficients on Protected and PC are all positively related to ROA, Ret and MB.
These results
indicate that strategic firms perform better than non-strategic firms and support our H1. [Insert Table 2 here]
21
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT We further explore if there exists a different demographic profile of top managers in strategic vs non-strategic firms.
Table 3 reports the binary logit regressions in which the
T
dependent variables are Strategic, Protected and PC dummies. Our results show that there exist
education.
RI P
some significant differences in demography in terms of chairperson age, CEO age and CEO In addition, there are also some differences in one governance variable (board size)
SC
and a few firm characteristics (SOEs, debt level, firm size and firm age).
While these findings
demographic profiles.
NU
may be exploratory, they do indicate that strategic firms employ top managers with different This finding is consistent with the management literature that when a
MA
firm owns a unique type of valuable resources, it needs a particular type of human resources to exploit them so that the valuable resources and capabilities can be developed in combination in
ED
order to attain competitive advantage (Barney, 1991).
PT
[Insert Table 3 here]
CE
4.3 Results for Hypothesis 2 (H2)
AC
Table 4 presents the results for our H2 (a and b) which examines the relationship between strategic firm and turnover. The first two columns in Table 4 show the results for all turnovers (both voluntary and forced). We also conduct the analysis using poorly performing firms because we want to examine if there exists any difference in the impact of Strategic dummy on forced turnovers.
In view of the identification problem of forced and voluntary turnovers
(Chang & Wong, 2009; Huson et al., 2004), we argue that during crisis, when the firm is in trouble, there should be a strong incentive for the board and shareholders to replace top management, leading to a forced turnover.
In this forced turnover sample, there are 313 CEO
22
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT turnovers (CEOTurn) and 274 chairperson turnovers (CHTurn). The results are reported in the third and fourth columns in Table 4.8
T
For both total and forced turnover samples, the Strategic dummies are all positively
RI P
significant except for CEOTurn in the forced turnover sample. Economically, this statistical finding suggests that strategic firms are more likely to have higher management turnover than This finding supports H2a.
SC
their non-strategic counterparts.
Interesting enough, the
NU
interaction dummies (Strategic*PC) are significantly negative with a bigger coefficient than Strategic (except for CEOTurn in total sample).
This result lends support to our H2b.
MA
Combining these two coefficients together; we can generate an economic interpretation that politically connected firms have a lower probability to experience chairperson turnovers under
ED
both normal and poor performing situations.
The higher overall turnovers for strategic sample
at the national level.
PT
are due to the fact that strategic firms often execute state strategy on human capital deployment It is indeed a common practice of Mainland government to rotate senior For instance, on January 16, 2012, with the approval of China
CE
executives among SOEs.
AC
Banking Regulatory Commission, extraordinary general meeting (EGM) and board meeting, the Agricultural Bank of China (ABC) and China Construction Bank (CCB) announced that ABC would appoint Jiang Chaoliang (previously as the president of China Development Bank) as chairperson and CCB would appoint Wang Hongzhang (previously as the Party member of the People’s Bank of China) as chairperson. These incidents show that in Mainland China, top managers are being moved around in SOEs which may have little to do with manager performance in their own firms, but more to do with the needs of other SOEs and state agencies.
8
Besides examining the demographic characteristics of top management on individual level, we also repeat the analyses using the relational demographic difference between chairperson and CEO. We report the results on individual level in Table 3 and Table 4. The results on relational demographic difference are qualitatively similar and available upon request.
23
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Another interesting observation about the stronger negative coefficient of Strategic*PC suggests that politically connected firms tend to maintain a more stable management team even facing Yuan (2011) also finds it is less likely to replace politically connected CEOs
T
poor performance.
RI P
even they have poor performance. Our finding is consistent with the common wisdom in China that when an individual or corporation is connected to the State, the State would protect the
SC
connected entities during bad times.
NU
[Insert Table 4 here]
In Table 4, for the total turnover sample, some control variables of management Many studies have shown that management turnover is positively
MA
demography are significant.
and negatively related to age and tenure (Kang & Shivdasani, 1995).
We find that there are
ED
more top manager turnovers if they are older and have lower education level.
Among the
PT
control variables for board governance and firm characteristics, we find that the coefficients on DirHold, ROA, LnAsset and FirmAge are significant and show consistent directional relations
CE
with CHTurn and CEOTurn.
Our results suggest that top management is more likely to
AC
experience turnover when director shareholding (DirHold) is lower and the firms have lower profitability (ROA), longer establishment time (FirmAge) and are smaller in size (LnAsset)9. However, Dual, CentSOED and LocalSOED show different signs with CHTurn and CEOTurn.
Dahya, McConnell, and Travlos (2002) suggest that chairpersons with CEO duality
have more power on board and may entrench longer tenure in the firms.
The coefficients on
Dual are not related to CHTurn. However, there are negatively significant relations between Dual and CEOTurn, indicating that the CEO is less likely to experience turnover when there is CEO duality. 9
Firth et al. (2006) also find that there is a lower likelihood for large firm to replace chairperson. They explain that large firms need more skilled managers who are usually in short supply, hence deterring large firms from dismissing the chairpersons.
24
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Central SOEs and local SOEs are different in top management turnover decisions. There are more chairperson turnovers and less CEO turnovers in central SOEs.
The coefficients on
T
LocalSOED are not related to CHTurn, but are negatively and significantly related to CEOTurn.
RI P
Owing to fiscal decentralization, Chang and Wong (2009) suggest that local governments should focus more on economic performance than on achievement of social and political objectives.
SC
Therefore, the firms owned by local government should be more likely than those owned by the
NU
central government to discipline poorly performing CEOs. They find that firms owned by local governments are more likely to have CEO turnover. Our result is inconsistent with that of
MA
Chang and Wong (2009) as we find CHTurn and CEOTurn to have positive and negative associations with CentSOED, respectively.10
ED
Finally, we also divide the sample into strategic vs non-strategic subsamples to examine how
PT
top manager’s turnover may relate to demographic, governance, and firm characteristics. The results are reported in Appendix 1. Overall findings seem to suggest that the top manager’s
CE
turnover (especially for CEOs’) for strategic and non-strategic firms is related to different sets of
AC
governance and firm variables (with limited common variables).
4.4 Results for Hypothesis 3 (H3) Our final analysis (H3) examines whether the strategic firms in crisis show better performance improvements after replacing the top managers for the forced turnover sample. Our rationale is based on the ‘‘grabbing hand’’ argument of Shleifer and Vishny (1998).
If the
strategic firms are under state control to fulfill certain political agenda other than maximizing firm value, these firms should also receive business and financial benefits from government in 10
However, the study of Chang and Wong (2009) is mainly on the turnover of CEO. In addition, their robustness check also shows that the activity of chairperson on firm management affects managerial turnover, the more active the chairperson, the lower the probability of CEO turnover.
25
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT difficult times, which are exactly the case defined in our poor-performing subsample. Thus we expect these strategic firms should rebound better financially after the management turnovers.
T
The results are reported in Table 5. Our three performance indicators are change in return
RI P
on assets (ROA), change in stock returns (Ret) and change in market-to-book ratio (MB).
SC
The coefficients on Strategic are positively related to Ret (Rety+1 – Rety-1) and MB (MBy+1 – MBy-1), indicating that the strategic firms experience bigger performance improvements than This finding that the strategic firms perform better is
NU
those for the non-strategic firms. consistent with H3.11
MA
[Insert Table 5 here]
In Table 5, for the demographic characteristic variables, the subscript “N” indicates the We find that none of the demographic characteristics
ED
newly appointed chairperson and CEO.
PT
on the individual level is significant, except for GMEduN, which is significantly related to ROA.
CE
The insignificance of the demographic characteristics of the newly appointed top management suggests two possible interesting observations.
First, combining the finding of performance
AC
improvement for strategic firms and no relationship between performance and new top management demography, we conjecture that the replacement of poorly-performing top management as shown in Table 5 is an evidence of corporate governance (Shleifer & Vishny, 1997).
The western culture of accountability imposed on top managers often times leads to
their forced resignation even though the poor performance may not be entirely due to their fault. We argue that our result here is consistent with such a practice. Our second interesting observation is based on the result that no relationship is found between performance improvement and new top management demography but the performance 11
In the examination of managerial turnover in Chinese firms, Firth et al. (2006) report that turnover is negatively related to profitability, but find no evidence of post-turnover improvement in performance. Our results show performance improvement of strategic firms relative to non-strategic firms, which is a different benchmark.
26
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT improvement is positively related to Strategic.
Such a finding can be explained by the
argument that the performance improvement has little to do with the new managers’
T
demographic profile (i.e., can be viewed as a proxy of managerial ability) but more to do with
RI P
the business and financial advantages from government due to the government protection and/or political connection.
SC
In addition, we also measure the relational demography of the newly appointed top We find ROA and
NU
management team (TMT) for the characteristics of age and education level.
MB are negatively and significantly related to DiffEduN. This result suggests that the higher
MA
the education level of CEO as compared to that of the chairperson, the greater the increase in return on assets and market-to-book ratio.
Among the other control variables, we find that
ED
firms with larger board independence (DirIndR), higher shareholding percentage (DirHold) and
turnover.
PT
longer establishment time (FirmAge) have greater increase in stock return after management In addition, the local SOEs are more likely to have positive change in market-to-book
CE
ratio after turnover, a finding which is consistent with the argument of Chang and Wong (2009)
financial loss.
AC
that state shareholders have incentive to improve firm performance particularly during period of
4.5 Additional Analysis In our main analysis, we use PC which is a dummy for politically connected firm. For robustness purpose, we compile a politically connected index to measure the strength of political connectedness to repeat our analyses. This politically connected index is a weighted score index which takes into account the political connectedness of different types (former government officials, People’s Congress representatives or PPCC committee members) and at various levels
27
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT (from central or national down to county levels).
For the type of connectedness with
government officials, there are four levels: central, provincial, city and county.
We assign 1
T
score for deputy official and 2 scores for chief official at county level; 3 scores for deputy
RI P
official and 4 scores for chief official at city level; 5 scores for deputy official and 6 scores for chief official at provincial level; and 7 scores for deputy official and 8 scores for chief official at For the type of connectedness with the representatives of People’s Congress,
SC
the central level.
We assign political
NU
there are also four levels: national, provincial, city and county.
connectedness scores to People’s Congress membership, which are 4, 3, 2 and 1 for national,
MA
provincial, city and county levels, respectively.
For the type of connectedness with the
committee members of PPCC, there are two levels: national and regional.
We assign the score
Our new measure of political connectedness, PCScore, is the natural logarithm
PT
national PPCC.
ED
of 1 for connectedness with committee members of regional PPCC and the score of 2 for that of
of the total sum of connectedness scores for all the board members (chairperson, CEO, and
CE
directors). We repeat the regression analysis on management demography and turnover using
AC
PCScore instead of PC and report the results in Table 6. For the analysis on management demography, we show that there exist significant differences in demography for chairperson and CEO for politically and non-politically connected firms.
For the analysis on management
turnover, the overall results are weaker for the PCScore variable but still significant for chairperson, meaning that politically connected firms do not change their chairpersons as much relative to non-politically connected firms.12 [Insert Table 6 here]
12
We thank the anonymous reviewer for suggesting the politically connected index as alternative measure of political connectedness.
28
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT To address the concern for the potential endogeneity problem that the government decision for keeping firms under government control and political connectedness decision are not random,
We match each of the strategic firms with unique non-strategic firms
without using the same firm again for matching.
RI P
with strategic firms.13
T
we apply the propensity score matching (PSM) method to select non-strategic firms to match
We conduct the original analyses of Tables
SC
2-4 using the PSM approach by 1,590 pairs of strategic and non-strategic firms (in total 3,180
NU
observations). The results are reported in Tables 7-9. As shown in Tables 7-9, the results using 7,959 observations and 3,180 observations are qualitatively the same. Our main findings
MA
that: (1) strategic firms perform better than non-strategic firms; (2) strategic firms employ top managers with different demographic profiles; (3) strategic firms are more likely to have
ED
management turnovers; and (4) politically connected firms have a lower probability to
PT
experience chairperson turnovers under normal and poor performing situations, remain the same.
AC
CE
This suggests that our results are robust after considering the concern for endogeneity. [Insert Table 7 here] [Insert Table 8 here] [Insert Table 9 here]
5. Conclusion Nowadays, emerging market governments are able to employ a full range of sophisticated strategies to enhance the effectiveness of state-owned assets in improving their economies.
In
this paper, we use data from a transitional economy, China, which provides us an opportunity to explore two related government strategies deployed on listed firms, government protection as well as political connections. 13
Declaring a protection status is a way to protect national security
We thank the anonymous reviewer for suggesting the PSM method to address the endogeneity concern.
29
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT interest and these protected and regulated firms are large monopolies which enjoy the benefits of government subsidies and less competition. The ties through political connections are also
T
valuable economic interest as “guanxi (relationship)” provides important networks to reduce We show that these strategic firms are related to firm
RI P
transaction cost (Burt, 1997).
performance and management turnover, especially during firm-level crisis.
SC
Based on the conjecture that the business benefits and therefore financial performance of
NU
strategic firms do not rely heavily on top managers, the post-turnover performance change of strategic firms is independent of demographic profiles of new top managers.
MA
economy, there are many recently privatized SOEs and protected firms.
In a transitional
This study sheds light
on how the Chinese government’s strategic firms perform financially and demonstrate a different Political connection literature normally defines connected
ED
pattern of management turnover.
PT
firms by the personal connection of a single CEO.
Our paper defines a politically connected
firm by using a more restrictive standard: when the chairperson or CEO plus at least two
CE
directors have former ties in the governments at various forms and levels.
This measure may be
AC
a more comprehensive proxy of political networks. Our analysis on the effect of political connection shows that connected firms experience few turnovers in the total and forced turnover samples, indicating that top managers in connected firms may enjoy protection from the board, which can be under the influence of the government. We do not, however, condemn such protection as these strategic firms also enjoy better financial performance during the normal times and enjoy a stronger financial improvement in the post-turnover year after facing the financial distress.
Such a two-way street of benefits and
responsibilities has well been documented in the political connection literature.
We add to the
literature by demonstrating consistent evidence related to management turnovers.
30
Finally,
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT additional analysis in future research is needed to better understand the main drivers of
AC
CE
PT
ED
MA
NU
SC
RI P
T
management turnovers for strategic and non-strategic firms.
31
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Acknowledgements
T
The authors acknowledge that this research project was financially supported by the Research
Polytechnic University Project No. PolyU1471/11H).
We thank Professor Michael Firth for his
AC
CE
PT
ED
MA
NU
SC
valuable comments.
RI P
Grants Council of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, China (Hong Kong
32
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT References Agrawal, A., & Knoeber, C.K. (2001). Do some outside directors play a political role? Journal of
T
Law and Economics, 44, 179-198.
RI P
Aharony, J.C., Lee, W.J., & Wong, T.J. (2000). Financial packaging of IPO firms in China. Journal of Accounting Research, 38, 103-126.
SC
Ambler, T., Styles, C., & Wang, X. (1999). The effect of channel relationships and guanxi on the
NU
performance of inter-province export ventures in the People’s Republic of China. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 16 (1), 75-88.
MA
Barney, J.B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17, 99-120.
ED
Bass, A.E., & Chakrabarty, S. (2014). Resource security: Competition for global resources,
PT
strategic intent, and governments as owners. Journal of International Business Studies, 45, 961-979.
CE
Boddewyn, J.J., & Brewer, T.L. (1994). International-business political behavior: New
AC
theoretical directions. Academy of Management Review, 19 (1), 119-143. Borisova, G., & Megginson, W.L. (2011). Does government ownership affect the cost of debt? Evidence from privatization. Review of Financial Studies, 24, 2693-2737. Borokhovich, K.A., Parrino, R. & Trapani, T. (1996). Outside directors and CEO selection. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 31, 377-397. Boubakri, N., Guedhami, O., Mishra, D., & Saffar, W. (2012). Political connections and the cost of equity capital. Journal of Corporate Finance, 18, 541-559. Burt, R. (1997). The contingent value of social capital. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 339-363.
33
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Calomiris, C.W., Fisman, R., & Wang, Y. (2010). Profiting from government stakes in a command economy: Evidence from Chinese asset sales. Journal of Financial Economics, 96,
T
399-412.
RI P
Chan, R.Y.K., Cheng, L.T.W., & Leung, T.Y. (2010). Corporate performance implications of relational demographic differences: On age and titles of chairpersons vs. general managers of
SC
listed Chinese companies. British Journal of Management, 22, 96-113.
NU
Chang, E.C., & Wong, S.M.L. (2009). Governance with multiple objectives: Evidence from top executive turnover in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 15, 230-244.
MA
Chen, I. (2014). Financial crisis and the dynamics of corporate governance: Evidence from Taiwan’s listed firms. International Review of Economics and Finance, 32, 3-28.
ED
Cheng, L.T.W., Chan, R.Y.K., & Leung, T.Y. (2010). Management demography and corporate
PT
performance: Evidence from China. International Business Review, 19, 261-275. Cheng, L.T.W., Leung, T.Y., & Yu, W. (2014). Information arrival, changes in R-square and
AC
67-81.
CE
pricing asymmetry of corporate news. International Review of Economics and Finance, 33,
Claessens, S., Feijen, E., & Laeven, L. (2008). Political connections and preferential access to finance: The role of campaign contributions. Journal of Financial Economics, 88, 554-580. Coles, J.W., McWilliams, V.B., & Sen, N. (2001). An examination of the relationship of governance mechanisms to performance. Journal of Management, 27, 23-50. Cooper, M.J., Gulen, H., & Ovtchinnikov, A.V. (2010). Corporate political contributions and stock returns. Journal of Finance, 65 (2), 687-724. Cull, R., & Xu, L.C. (2005). Institutions, ownership, and finance: The determinants of profit reinvestment among Chinese firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 77 (1), 117-146.
34
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Dalton, D.R., & Kesner, I.F. (1983). Inside/outside succession and organizational size: The pragmatics of executive replacement. Academy of Management Journal, 26, 736-742.
RI P
and top management turnover. Journal of Finance, 57, 461-483.
T
Dahya, J., McConnell, J., & Travlos, N. (2002). The Cadbury committee, corporate performance,
DeFond, M.L., & Hung, M. (2004). Investor protection and corporate governance: Evidence
SC
from worldwide CEO turnover. Journal of Accounting Research, 42, 269-312.
NU
Economist (2012, Jan, Special Issue). How State Enterprise is Spreading. Faccio, M. (2006). Politically connected firms. American Economic Journal, 96, 369-386.
MA
Fama, E. (1980). Agency problems and the theory of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88, 103-288.
ED
Fan, J.P.H., Wong, T.J. & Zhang, T. (2007). Politically connected CEOs, corporate governance,
Economics, 84, 330-357.
PT
and post-IPO performance of China’s newly partially privatized firms. Journal of Financial
CE
Farrell, K.A., & Whidbee, D.A. (2003). Impact of firm performance expectations on CEO turnover
AC
and replacement decisions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 36 (1-3), 165-196. Firth, M., Fung, P.M.Y., & Rui, O.M. (2006). Firm performance, governance structure and top management turnover in a transitional economy. Journal of Management Studies, 43, 1289-1330. Fisman, R. (2001). Estimating the value of political connections. American Economic Review, 91, 1095-1102. Goldman, E., Rocholl, J., & So, J. (2009). Do political connected boards affect firm value? Review of Financial Studies, 22, 2331-2360.
35
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Groves, T., Hong, Y., McMillan, J., & Naughton, B. (1995). China’s evolving managerial labor market. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 873-892.
T
Hillman, A.L. (1982). Declining industries and political-support protectionist motives. The
RI P
American Economic Review, 72 (5), 1180-1187.
Holburn, G.L.F., & Zelner, B.A. (2010). Political capabilities, policy risk and international
SC
investment strategy: Evidence from the global electric power generation industry. Strategic
NU
Management Journal, 31, 1290-1315.
Huson, M., Parrino, R., & Starks, L. (2001). Internal monitoring mechanisms and CEO turnover:
MA
A long-term perspective. Journal of Finance, 56, 2265-2298. Huson, M., Malatesta, P., & Parrino, R., (2004). Managerial succession and firm performance.
ED
Journal of Financial Economics, 74, 237-275.
PT
Jensen, M.C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American Economic Review, 76, 323-329.
CE
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
AC
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-360. Jenter, D., & Kanaan, F. (2015). CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation. Journal of Finance, forthcoming, DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12282. Jones, S.L., Megginson, W.L., Nash, R.C., & Netter, J.M. (1999). Share issue privatizations as financial means to political and economic ends. Journal of Financial Economics, 53, 217-253. Kang, J., & Shivdasani, A. (1995). Firm performance, corporate governance, and top executive turnover in Japan. Journal of Financial Economics, 38, 29-58. Lajili, K., & Zéghal, D. (2006). Market performance impacts of human capital disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 25, 171-194.
36
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Li, H., & Atuahene-Gima, K. (2001). Product innovation strategy and the performance of new technology ventures in China. Academy of Management Journal, 44 (6), 1123-1134.
T
Li, J.J., Poppo, L., & Zhou, K.Z. (2008). Do managerial ties in China always produce value?
RI P
Competition, uncertainty, and domestic vs. foreign firms. Strategic Management Journal, 29 (4), 383-400.
SC
McNeil, C., Niehaus, G., & Powers, E. (2004). Management turnover in subsidiaries of
NU
conglomerates versus stand-alone firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 72, 63-69. Megginson, W.L., Nash, R.C., Netter, J.M., & Poulsen, A.B. (2004). The choice of private
MA
versus public capital markets: Evidence from privatizations. Journal of Finance, 59 (6), 2835-2870.
ED
Melitz, M. (2005). When and how should infant industries be protected? Journal of International
PT
Economics, 66, 177-196.
Murphy, K.J. (1999). Executive compensation. In O. Ashenfelter and D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of
CE
Labor Economics (pp. 2485-2563). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
AC
Nee, V., Opper, S., & Wong, S.M.L. (2007). Developmental state and corporate governance in China. Management and Organization Review, 3 (1), 19-53. Park, S.H., & Luo, Y. (2001). Guanxi and organizational dynamics: Organizational networking in Chinese firms. Strategic Management Journal, 22, 455-477. Parrino, R., Sias, R.W., & Starks, L.T. (2003). Voting with their feet: Institutional ownership changes around forced CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics, 68 (1), 3-46. Peng, M.W., & Luo, Y. (2000). Managerial ties and firm performance in a transition economy: The nature of a micro-macro link. Academy of Management Journal, 43 (3), 486-501.
37
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Shen, C.H., Lin, C.Y., & Wang, Y.C. (2015). Do strong corporate governance firms still require political connection and vice versa? International Review of Economics and Finance, 39,
T
107-120.
RI P
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52, 737-783.
NU
cures. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
SC
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. (1998). The grabbing hand: Government pathologies and their
Simpson, W.G., & Gleason, A.E. (1999). Board structure, ownership, and financial distress in
MA
banking firms. International Review of Economics and Finance, 8, 281-292. Su, Z.Q., Fung, H.G., Huang, D.S., & Shen, C.H. (2014). Cash dividends, expropriation, and
ED
political connections: Evidence from China. International Review of Economics and Finance,
PT
29, 260-272.
Sun, Q., & Tong, W.H.S. (2003). China share issue privatization: The extent of its success.
CE
Journal of Financial Economics, 70 (2), 183-222.
AC
Teece, D.J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18 (7), 509–533. Volpin, P. (2002). Governance with poor investor protection: Evidence from top executive turnover in Italy. Journal of Financial Economics, 64 (1), 61-90. Yuan, Q. (2011). Public governance, political connectedness, and CEO turnover: Evidence from Chinese state-owned enterprises. Working paper, Melbourne University.
38
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 1 Descriptive Statistics
6878 6380 3926
19.0000 71.0000 9.0000 22.0000 75.0000 9.0000 0.6250 0.7481 19.0000
1.0000 26.0000 0.0000 1.0000 26.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 5.0000
2.8517 7.4514 2.5006 2.4503 6.7121 2.4484 0.1064 0.0789 2.2147
0.0320 2.5689 0.4843 20.2467 21.2052 27.8091 9.0000 26.0000
-3.9919 0.0081 14.9375 1.0000
0.1917 0.4944 1.0553 4.0892
-0.1085 -0.0246 4.5715 -0.1098 -0.0581 2.1648 -0.9305 -0.5983 37.8300
-4.0158 -2.8945 -38.2488
0.7311 0.8636 11.9270
NU
1081 1579 4033
ED
6593 6168
MA
0.0177 0.5108 21.3129 9.3851
1366 1791
3.0000 50.0000 4.0000 3.0000 45.0000 4.0000 0.3333 0.0000 9.0000
RI P
3.8803 49.8269 3.6404 3.2695 45.9354 3.5927 0.3038 0.0158 9.8404
T
Mean Median Maximum Minimum Standard Deviation
SC
Dummy Code = 1 Dummy Code = 0 1590 6369
PT
Strategic CHTen CHAge CHEdu CEOTen CEOAge CEOEdu DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE ROA DA LnAsset FirmAge CHTurn CEOTurn ROA Ret MB
AC
CE
Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. CH is the prefix to represent the characteristic of chairperson. CEO is the prefix to represent the characteristic of CEO. Ten is the number of years staying in office. Age is the age. Edu is the number of schooling. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. ROA is return on assets. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. CHTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson is replaced and 0 otherwise. CEOTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the CEO is replaced and 0 otherwise. ROA is the change in return on assets. Ret is the change in return. MB is the change in market-to-book ratio.
39
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Table 2
IP
T
Analysis on Financial Performance
0.224 93.1 0.00 7959
0.226 86.8 0.00 7959
CE
0.224 93.1 0.00 7959
PT
ED
MA NU S
-0.489 0.00 -0.491 0.00 -0.471 0.00 -1.564 0.00 -1.814 0.00 -1.537 0.00 13.284 0.00 11.967 0.00 13.041 0.00 0.011 0.00** 0.064 0.00** 0.437 0.00** 0.013 0.02* 0.104 0.00** 1.115 0.00** 0.001 0.56 0.055 0.01** 0.287 0.02* 0.048 0.32 0.049 0.30 0.021 0.68 2.477 0.00** 2.281 0.00** 2.478 0.00** 1.832 0.07 2.171 0.03* 1.927 0.05* 0.110 0.00** 0.109 0.00** 0.093 0.00** 1.658 0.00** 1.802 0.00** 1.651 0.00** 1.411 0.00** 1.859 0.00** 1.414 0.00** -0.002 0.06 -0.002 0.08 -0.002 0.06 0.008 0.01** 0.006 0.05* 0.008 0.01** -0.013 0.50 -0.006 0.77 -0.012 0.54 -0.001 0.91 0.001 0.91 0.002 0.81 0.034 0.07 -0.044 0.03* -0.034 0.08 0.418 0.01** -0.451 0.00** -0.429 0.00** -0.001 0.90 -0.001 0.89 -0.001 0.85 0.011 0.56 0.022 0.30 0.010 0.60 -0.155 0.30 -0.149 0.32 -0.185 0.22 0.004 0.41 0.004 0.40 0.005 0.34 -0.031 0.05* -0.030 0.07 -0.030 0.05* -0.534 0.00** -0.553 0.00** -0.559 0.00** -0.117 0.00** -0.117 0.00** -0.118 0.00** -0.040 0.00** -0.042 0.00** -0.041 0.00** -0.351 0.01** -0.359 0.01** -0.358 0.01** 0.027 0.00** 0.027 0.00** 0.027 0.00** 0.045 0.00** 0.057 0.00** 0.045 0.00** -0.406 0.00** -0.390 0.00** -0.415 0.00** -0.001 0.04* -0.001 0.04* -0.002 0.01** 0.017 0.00** 0.022 0.00** 0.017 0.00** 0.047 0.00** 0.064 0.00** 0.053 0.00**
AC
Intercept Strategic Protected PC DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE DA LnAsset FirmAge Industry Dummies included Year Dummies Included Adj R2 F-statistics p-value N
CR
ROA Ret MB Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value
0.423 177.9 0.00 7959
0.358 165.3 0.00 7959
0.423 177.8 0.00 7959
0.120 33.7 0.00 7959
0.104 29.8 0.00 7959
0.120 35.0 0.00 7959
ROA is return on assets. Ret is the annual stock return. MB is the market-to-book ratio. Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
40
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 3 Analysis on Management Demography
T
0.00 0.00** 0.00** 0.04* 0.98 0.00** 0.77 0.03* 0.21 0.00** 0.33 0.00** 0.00** 0.36 0.00** 0.00** 0.00**
PC Coeff -11.066 0.020 0.020 0.011 -0.029 0.019 0.060 1.079 -0.503 0.141 -0.352 0.142 0.369 0.559 -0.267 0.253 -0.058 554.8 0.00 7959
RI P
-11.391 -0.057 -0.019 -0.030 0.000 0.022 0.004 -1.354 -0.977 0.059 -0.108 0.785 0.851 -0.666 -1.726 0.484 -0.055 607.6 0.00 7959
SC
0.00 0.47 0.04* 0.41 0.60 0.00** 0.02* 0.26 0.07 0.00** 0.17 0.00** 0.00** 0.87 0.00** 0.00** 0.00**
MA
-9.449 -0.009 -0.009 -0.011 -0.007 0.019 0.031 -0.597 -1.141 0.099 -0.134 0.508 0.755 0.112 -0.960 0.352 -0.045 1026.0 0.00 7959
ED
Intercept CHTen CHAge CHEdu CEOTen CEOAge CEOEdu DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE ROA DA LnAsset FirmAge LR Statistic p-value N
Protected Coeff p-value
NU
Strategic Coeff p-value
p-value 0.00 0.24 0.00** 0.55 0.14 0.01** 0.00** 0.15 0.53 0.00** 0.02* 0.36 0.00** 0.18 0.15 0.00** 0.00**
AC
CE
PT
Protected is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation and 0 otherwise. PC is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a politically connected firm and 0 otherwise. Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. CH is the prefix to represent the characteristic of chairperson. CEO is the prefix to represent the characteristic of CEO. Ten is the number of years staying in office. Age is the age. Edu is the number of schooling. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. ROA is return on assets. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
41
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 4 Analysis on Management Turnover
SC
NU
ED
-0.115 -3.692 0.004 0.068 0.391 -0.060 -0.549 0.071 -0.157 0.032 373.0 0.000 7959
0.59 -0.196 0.77 1.528 0.40 0.00** 0.225 0.04* 0.902 0.02* 0.00** -0.117 0.38 -1.321 0.01** 0.09 -0.003 0.17 0.00** 0.014 0.24 0.00** -0.097 0.00** -0.011 0.35 0.019 0.00** -0.048 0.00** 0.85 -0.927 0.08 -0.880 0.46 0.00** -1.154 0.03* -2.685 0.45 0.77 0.021 0.12 0.034 0.39 0.46 -0.269 0.00** 0.089 0.67 0.00** -0.194 0.02* 0.227 0.33 0.44 -0.319 0.00** 0.048 0.80 0.01** -0.557 0.00** -0.104 0.45 0.23 0.036 0.52 0.026 0.57 0.00** -0.099 0.00** -0.154 0.07 0.00** 0.025 0.00** 0.014 0.53 228.2 80.6 0.000 0.00 7959 896
MA
0.393 0.519 -0.626 -0.020 0.025 -0.123
PT
Intercept Strategic Strategic*PC CHTen CHAge CHEdu CEOTen CEOAge CEOEdu DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE ROA DA LnAsset FirmAge LR Statistic p-value N
RI P
T
Total Turnover Sample Forced Turnover Sample CHTurn CEOTurn CHTurn CEOTurn Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value 2.558 0.14 -0.491 0.24 0.930 0.05*
-0.005 0.012 -0.053 -1.500 -1.018 0.028 -0.048 -0.270 -0.092 -0.211 -0.002 -0.134 0.010 65.6 0.00 896
0.08 0.34 0.08 0.20 0.68 0.48 0.81 0.23 0.60 0.13 0.97 0.09 0.65
AC
CE
CHTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson is replaced and 0 otherwise. CEOTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the CEO is replaced and 0 otherwise. Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. CH is the prefix to represent the characteristic of chairperson. CEO is the prefix to represent the characteristic of CEO. Ten is the number of years staying in office. Age is the age. Edu is the number of schooling. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. ROA is return on assets. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
42
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 5 Analysis on Post-turnover Performance for Forced Turnover Sample
T
ROA Ret MB Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value
PT
ED
MA
NU
SC
RI P
Intercept -0.168 0.84 -0.189 0.83 -1.527 0.04 -1.175 0.12 -2.455 0.88 -8.172 0.65 Strategic 0.021 0.78 0.019 0.79 0.314 0.00** 0.335 0.00** 3.204 0.05* 4.345 0.02* CHAgeN 0.001 0.84 0.004 0.48 0.038 0.70 CHEduN -0.020 0.10 -0.016 0.24 -0.490 0.06 CEOAgeN 0.001 0.85 0.006 0.25 -0.140 0.21 CEOEduN 0.034 0.04* 0.013 0.38 0.315 0.24 DiffAgeN 0.001 0.85 -0.001 0.80 0.081 0.34 DiffEduN -0.023 0.05* -0.013 0.26 -0.439 0.04* DirIndR 0.293 0.65 -0.060 0.93 2.268 0.00** 2.350 0.00** 1.544 0.86 -2.240 0.83 DirHold 0.267 0.65 -0.047 0.94 5.210 0.00** 4.965 0.00** 12.657 0.16 8.871 0.34 BoardSize 0.009 0.63 0.013 0.50 -0.023 0.20 -0.024 0.18 -0.435 0.16 -0.412 0.20 Dual -0.036 0.78 -0.002 0.99 -0.046 0.65 -0.034 0.74 0.110 0.95 -0.021 0.99 CentSOE -0.089 0.41 -0.081 0.46 -0.020 0.86 -0.025 0.82 1.378 0.48 1.264 0.48 LocalSOE 0.030 0.68 0.050 0.50 0.078 0.37 0.084 0.33 2.609 0.05* 2.364 0.06 DA -0.048 0.46 -0.045 0.49 0.011 0.69 0.013 0.63 -0.680 0.11 -0.651 0.10 LnAsset -0.014 0.75 -0.004 0.92 -0.011 0.77 -0.007 0.86 0.403 0.63 0.424 0.64 FirmAge 0.005 0.63 -0.003 0.72 0.051 0.00** 0.051 0.00** 0.106 0.48 0.139 0.32 Industry Dummies included Year Dummies Included Adjusted R-square 0.004 0.036 0.369 0.368 0.004 0.003 F Statistic 1.063 1.585 8.465 8.932 1.057 1.037 p-value 0.383 0..036 0.000 0.000 0.390 0.416
AC
CE
ROA is the change in return on assets (year +1 minus year -1). Ret is the change in return (year +1 minus year -1). MB is the change in market-to-book ratio (year +1 minus year -1). Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. CH is the prefix to represent the characteristic of chairperson. CEO is the prefix to represent the characteristic of CEO. Age is the age. Edu is the number of schooling. DiffAge is the age difference with the age of chairperson minus that of CEO. DiffEdu is the difference in number of schooling with the number of schooling of chairperson minus that of CEO. The subscript “N” indicates the newly appointed chairperson and CEO. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
43
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 6 Analysis on Management Demography and Turnover using PCScore
0.89 0.00** 0.71 0.48 0.00** 0.49 0.00** 0.22 0.00** 0.00**
PT
0.00 7955
-0.082 -3.642 0.006 -0.064 0.404 -0.054 -0.551 0.071 -0.150 0.034
-0.244 0.279 -0.072
-0.012 0.019 -0.048 -0.913 -1.143 0.022 0.270 -0.191 -0.318 -0.558 0.036 -0.098 0.025
363.63 0.00 7959
228.62 0.00 7959
T
0.07 0.00** 0.00** 0.01** 0.01** 0.00** 0.00** 0.23 0.00** 0.77 0.00** 0.00** 0.27 0.67 0.00** 0.89
0.76 0.00** 0.00** 0.07 0.00** 0.00**
Forced Turnover Sample CHTurn CEOTurn Coeff p-value Coeff p-value
RI P
-0.007 0.010 0.014 -0.013 0.004 0.016 0.682 0.165 0.054 0.008 0.085 0.072 0.046 -0.007 0.108 0.000 0.119 27.754
0.223 0.530 -0.207 -0.022 0.025 -0.123
0.44 0.30 0.09
0.35 0.00** 0.00** 0.09 0.03* 0.11 0.00** 0.02* 0.00** 0.00** 0.53 0.00** 0.00**
0.10 0.30 0.16 0.78 0.75 0.43 0.69 0.12 0.65 0.13 0.94 0.10 0.44
0.72 0.04* 0.28
SC
0.00**
NU
-2.729
ED
p-value
CE
Intercept Strategic Strategic*PCScore CHTen CHAge CHEdu CEOTen CEOAge CEOEdu DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE ROA DA LnAsset FirmAge Adjusted R2 F-statistic LR Statistic p-value N
Coeff
Total Turnover Sample CHTurn CEOTurn Coeff p-value Coeff p-value
MA
PCScore
2.918 0.09 1.378 0.753 0.03* -0.488 -0.351 0.06 0.377 -0.003 0.15 0.010 0.39 -0.097 0.00** -0.005 0.013 -0.042 -1.124 0.41 -0.383 -3.729 0.32 -0.782 0.039 0.34 0.031 -0.106 0.60 0.080 0.218 0.34 -0.346 0.083 0.65 -0.079 -0.100 0.46 -0.206 0.032 0.47 0.003 -0.201 0.01** -0.128 -0.005 0.81 0.017
58.28 0.00 896
72.90 0.00 896
AC
PCScore is the natural logarithm of the total score of the different rankings in government hierarchy, People’s Congress and People Political Consultative Conference held by the board members. Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. CHTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson is replaced and 0 otherwise. CEOTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the CEO is replaced and 0 otherwise. CH is the prefix to represent the characteristic of chairperson. CEO is the prefix to represent the characteristic of CEO. Ten is the number of years staying in office. Age is the age. Edu is the number of schooling. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. ROA is return on assets. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
44
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 7 Analysis on Financial Performance using Propensity Score Matching Method ROA Ret MB Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value
0.178 28.5 0.00 3180
6.595 0.474 4.339 0.644 -0.002 0.118 -0.456 -0.758 -0.428 -0.127 -0.001
T
0.00** 0.01** 0.00** 0.00** 0.79 0.01** 0.39 0.51 0.23 0.00** 0.24
RI P
-0.680 0.052 1.060 1.657 0.001 0.079 0.029 -0.019 -0.033 0.043 0.004
SC
0.00** 0.00** 0.91 0.00** 0.16 0.47 0.44 0.28 0.10 0.00** 0.00**
NU
-0.286 0.012 0.003 0.083 -0.001 0.004 0.005 0.006 -0.056 0.018 -0.003
MA
Intercept Strategic DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE DA LnAsset FirmAge Industry Dummies included Year Dummies Included Adj R2 F-statistics p-value N
0.455 92.5 0.00 3180
0.00** 0.01** 0.00** 0.41 0.93 0.47 0.09 0.00** 0.17 0.18 0.95
0.114 13.4 0.00 3180
AC
CE
PT
ED
ROA is return on assets. Ret is the annual stock return. MB is the market-to-book ratio. Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
45
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 8 Analysis on Management Demography using Propensity Score Matching Method Coeff
p-value
-6.813 -0.021 0.010 -0.003 -0.045 0.025 0.019 -0.291 -0.515 0.107 -0.281 0.038 0.154 -0.043 -0.717 0.217 -0.005 292.7 0.00 3180
-5.069 -0.034 -0.012 -0.014 -0.031 0.030 0.009 -1.398 -0.444 0.085 -0.156 0.402 0.394 -0.570 -1.078 0.211 -0.036 196.0 0.00 2192
-7.292 0.002 0.020 -0.022 -0.053 0.033 0.059 -0.003 -0.429 0.169 -0.456 -0.031 0.059 0.932 -0.992 0.145 0.014 147.3 0.00 1432
0.00** 0.95 0.03* 0.39 0.03* 0.00** 0.03* 1.00 0.61 0.00** 0.02* 0.88 0.72 0.49 0.01** 0.01** 0.44
SC
RI P
0.00** 0.06 0.12 0.50 0.11 0.00** 0.66 0.09 0.62 0.00** 0.27 0.01** 0.00** 0.62 0.08 0.00** 0.01**
NU
MA
0.00** 0.16 0.13 0.87 0.01** 0.00** 0.27 0.67 0.42 0.00** 0.02* 0.77 0.16 0.97 0.09 0.00** 0.66
PC
T
Protected Coeff p-value
ED
Intercept CHTen CHAge CHEdu CEOTen CEOAge CEOEdu DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE ROA DA LnAsset FirmAge LR Statistic p-value N
Strategic Coeff p-value
AC
CE
PT
Protected is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation and 0 otherwise. PC is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a politically connected firm and 0 otherwise. Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. CH is the prefix to represent the characteristic of chairperson. CEO is the prefix to represent the characteristic of CEO. Ten is the number of years staying in office. Age is the age. Edu is the number of schooling. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. ROA is return on assets. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
46
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 9 Analysis on Management Turnover using Propensity Score Matching Method
0.174 0.95 -0.266 0.57 0.963 0.05*
RI P
SC
NU
ED
-1.324 -4.018 -0.030 -0.148 0.052 -0.327 -1.586 -0.184 -0.042 0.011 148.6 0.000 3180
0.14 -1.478 0.15 1.806 0.60 0.00** 0.361 0.01** 1.269 0.01** 0.00** -0.220 0.10 -1.393 0.02* 0.20 -0.009 0.03* 0.00** 0.049 0.07 0.00** -0.047 0.46 -0.013 0.47 0.025 0.00** -0.004 0.84 0.17 -2.044 0.01 -3.296 0.26 0.01** -0.032 0.97 -13.464 0.57 0.20 -0.022 0.28 -0.125 0.13 0.37 -0.329 0.03* -0.171 0.71 0.75 -0.082 0.57 0.554 0.21 0.02* -0.373 0.00** -0.169 0.67 0.04* -1.124 0.02* -0.483 0.18 0.36 -0.149 0.29 -0.140 0.36 0.41 -0.021 0.65 -0.171 0.26 0.49 0.022 0.10 0.014 0.76 72.7 39.9 0.000 0.07 3180 292
MA
-1.639 0.453 -0.544 -0.024 0.042 -0.109
PT
Intercept Strategic Strategic*PC CHTen CHAge CHEdu CEOTen CEOAge CEOEdu DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE ROA DA LnAsset FirmAge LR Statistic p-value N
T
Total Turnover Sample Forced Turnover Sample CHTurn CEOTurn CHTurn CEOTurn Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value
0.004 0.45 0.032 0.26 0.039 0.50 -6.746 0.00** 10.644 0.68 -0.140 0.08 -1.096 0.04* 0.302 0.50 -0.169 0.65 -0.667 0.10 -0.241 0.14 0.002 0.99 0.033 0.48 51.6 0.01 292
AC
CE
CHTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson is replaced and 0 otherwise. CEOTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the CEO is replaced and 0 otherwise. Strategic is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is in the industries under government protection/regulation or is politically connected and 0 otherwise. PC is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a politically connected firm and 0 otherwise. CH is the prefix to represent the characteristic of chairperson. CEO is the prefix to represent the characteristic of CEO. Ten is the number of years staying in office. Age is the age. Edu is the number of schooling. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. ROA is return on assets. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
47
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Appendix 1 Analysis between Strategic Firms and Management Turnover using Subsamples
109.339 0.000 1590
299.984 0.000 6369
-2.074
0.12
1.827
0.01
0.022 0.034 0.020 -1.691 -0.203 -0.052 -0.133 -0.020 -0.385 -1.384 0.137 0.001 0.027
0.36 0.00** 0.48 0.16 0.87 0.09 0.53 0.93 0.05* 0.05* 0.44 0.99 0.19
-0.023 0.014 -0.066 -1.813 -1.789 0.040 -0.280 -0.259 -0.262 -0.502 0.025 -0.152 0.001
0.10 0.00** 0.00** 0.00** 0.00** 0.01** 0.00** 0.01** 0.00** 0.00** 0.64 0.00** 0.87
SC
-0.103 -3.384 0.010 0.056 0.445 -0.012 -0.438 0.061 -0.162 0.033
0.33 0.19 0.00** 0.00**
0.88 0.00** 0.59 0.57 0.00** 0.89 0.02* 0.25 0.00** 0.00**
NU
0.35 0.06 0.52 0.60 0.99 0.05* 0.12 0.05* 0.20 0.03*
0.821 -0.018 0.018 -0.131
MA
1.296 -4.682 -0.021 0.122 -0.003 -0.451 -1.475 0.336 -0.084 0.053
0.02 0.61 0.00** 0.00**
ED
-3.648 -0.014 0.061 -0.094
PT
Intercept CHTen CHAge CHEdu CEOTen CEOAge CEOEdu DirIndR DirHold BoardSize Dual CentSOE LocalSOE ROA DA LnAsset FirmAge Industry Dummies included Year Dummies Included LR Statistic p-value N
RI P
T
CHTurn CEOTurn Strategic Sample Non-Strateg ic Sample Strategic Sample Non-Strateg ic Sample Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value Coeff p-value
52.667 0.005 1590
185.018 0.000 6369
AC
CE
CHTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson is replaced and 0 otherwise. CEOTurn is a dummy coded 1 if the CEO is replaced and 0 otherwise. CH is the prefix to represent the characteristic of chairperson. CEO is the prefix to represent the characteristic of CEO. Ten is the number of years staying in office. Age is the age. Edu is the number of schooling. DirIndR is the proportion of independent directors to board size. DirHold is the percentage of shares held by directors to total shares. BoardSize is the number of directors on board. Dual is a dummy coded 1 if the chairperson and CEO are the same person and 0 otherwise. CentSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by central government and 0 otherwise. LocalSOE is a dummy coded 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise controlled by province, city or country government and 0 otherwise. ROA is return on assets. DA is debt to asset ratio. LnAsset is log of total assets. FirmAge is the number of years the firm is established. * 0.05 significance level ** 0.01 significance level
48