Carnegie-Ro~es~r ConStance Series on ~ b ~ Nor~-Holland
Po/icy 30 (1989) 11~ 128
POLICY REFORMAND THE RESOLUTIONOF THE DEBTCRISIS A COMMENT SEBASTIAN EDWARDS* University of California, Los Angeies and National Bureau of Economic Research
Anne Krueger has written an interesting and important paper on the prospects for solving the debt c r i s i s in the near future.
In a nutshell,
Krueger's argument is that there are two main requirements for the resol u t i o n of the c r i s i s . only then w i l l
F i r s t , world trade should grow at a healthy rate;
the indebted countries be able to s u f f i c i e n t l y increase
exports and generate the required trade surpluses. This expansion of world trade requires, in turn, that the industrial economies grow at respectable rates and that protectionist sentiments and policies are curbed. The second requirement is that the developing countries undertake far-reaching policy reforms that would result in an improvement in overall performance and growth. She suggests that the existing multilateral agencies - - and presumably a newly created one - - should provide new money to those countries seriously engaged in policy reform. Krueger provides important information regarding the role of capital flows in the development process, the origins of the debt c r i s i s , and the nature of the emergency phase of the adjustment, but says very l i t t l e about the details of what she considers to be the overriding requirements for regaining creditworthiness. proposed solutions - -
Although her c r i t i c a l revision of some of the
the new f a c i l i t i e s ,
changing the nature of the
l i a b i l i t i e s , and the "radical" schemes - - is persuasive, the paper does not go into a detailed discussion of what is meant by "policy reforms...[that are{ s u f f i c i e n t l y far reaching...", nor does i t discuss the specific ways in which these policy reforms - - which presumably include trade and financial l i b e r a l i z a t i o n and privatization - - should be implemented. In t h i s comment, thus, I w i l l concentrate on a number of specific issues related to the role of policy reform,
and in particular trade
l i b e r a l i z a t i o n , in the process of resolving of the debt c r i s i s .
0 167-223i189/$3.50 © 1989, ElsevierScience Publishers B.V. (North-Holland)
Manyof my
comments will be in the form of questions on the implementation of policy reform.
I. WHAT KIND OF TRADE REFORMS? Anne
Krueger
has been a pioneer
of the modern
literature on policy
reform in the poorer nations; she has long advocated that the developing countries undertake
steps toward
liberalizing
their external
sector.
It
comes as no surprise, then, that she now considers trade liberalization as a pivotal aspect other
authors
believe
that
in any longer-term solution to the crisis.
--
and
trade
indeed the reform,
supporters
coupled
with
of
the
Baker
A number of plan
privatization
and
--
also
finsncial
liberalization, is the most reasonable (only?) strategy that will allow the poor countries to regain creditworthiness
at the same time as they resume
growth. A problem with most of this recent literature, including this paper, is that
it
Moreover, meaning
of
is
seldom
through
clear
what
"trade
liberalization"
the years we have witnessed
"liberalization."
This
exactly
means.
some sort of shift in the
has introduced considerable
confusion
into the policy debate, with people never being sure what other participants really mean.
For instance, in a recent paper presented at the World
Bank-IMF Conference on the debt crisis
and adjustment with growth, Sachs
(1987) questioned the idea that "trade liberalization" policies are indeed a required component of successful debt strategies. advocated "outward-oriented" policies.
As an alternative
he
Waking reference to the experiences
of the East Asian countries -- Japan, Korea, Singapore, Taiwan, and Hong Kong -- Sachs argued that these countries'
success was to a large extent
due to an active role of government in promoting exports in an environment where imports had not yet been fully liberalized, and where macroeconomic (and especially fiscal) equilibrium was fostered. Sachs
depends
liberalization
on
how
outward
are defined.
orientation, Unfortunately,
Whether one agrees with
export with
promotion,
its vagueness
and
trade
Krueger's
paper has not helped solve the confusion that plagues this literature. In the more traditional policy literature of the 1960s and 1970s trade liberalization was defined in a very general way; what economists usually meant was some relaxation of trade and exchange controls. by now
classical
NBER
study on
trade
regimes
directed
In fact, by
in the
Bhagwati
and
Krueger, a liberalization episode was defined as a more extensive use of 116
the price mechanism that would reduce the anti-export bias of the trade regime. 1
In her review a r t i c l e on the problems of l i b e r a l i z a t i o n delivered
at the World Bank conference on the dynamics of l i b e r a l i z a t i o n ,
Krueger
(1986) argued that even a ( r e a l ) devaluation in the presence of QRs ( q u a n t i t a t i v e r e s t r i c t i o n ) constituted a l i b e r a l i z a t i o n episode. These are indeed very broad and mild d e f i n i t i o n s of l i b e r a l i z a t i o n . very few people w i l l
raise an eyebrow about them.
In f a c t , today
I t i s unclear from my
reading of the current paper i f t h i s type of reform i s what Krueger has in mind. Recently, however, "trade l i b e r a l i z a t i o n " has acquired a more d r a s t i c connotation, meaning ( f o r many people) an elimination of QRs coupled with a severe reduction of import t a r i f f s
to a uniform level of around 10 percent.
Moreover, trade l i b e r a l i z a t i o n has, in many ways, become synonymous with free market oriented p o l i c i e s with minimum or no government i n t e r v e n t i o n at any l e v e l ; l i b e r a l i z a t i o n has been taken as a synonym f o r laissez f a i r e . The difference between the old and new d e f i n i t i o n s of "trade l i b e r a l i z a t i o n " i s , of course, one of degree or i n t e n s i t y .
While a devaluation
in the presence of qRs, or the replacement of qRs by (quasi) equivalent tariffs,
i s a mild form of l i b e r a l i z a t i o n , the reduction of t a r i f f s
(with
no QRs) to a uniform 10 percent or, for that matter, the complete e l i m i nation of t a r i f f s ~
is a very d r a s t i c l i b e r a l i z a t i o n .
In order to c l e a r l y
understand the d i f f e r e n t issues involved in p o l i c y discussions i t i s , then, crucial to specify the i n t e n s i t y of the l i b e r a l i z a t i o n we are r e f e r r i n g to. Unfortunately, necessary to
this
is
not always done.
produce some s y n t h e t i c ,
without ideological biases, w i l l
It
is clear,
clarifying
then, that i t
pieces t h a t ,
put things into perspective.
is
hopefully It
i s im-
portant to pause and r e f l e c t ; to make an inventory of what we know, of what we t h i n k we know, and of what we do not know! This type of analysis, a l though humbling, should be of great help f o r policy evaluatiG~ and design. There i s l i t t l e doubt that a successful export promotion p o l i c y requires some kind of trade l i b e r a l i z a t i o n . In f a c t , the h i s t o r i c a l evidence c l e a r l y shows that those countries that have successfully embarked on that kind of strategy have had a more " l i b e r a l "
trade regime than those coun-
t r i e s f o l l o w i n g indiscriminate import s u b s t i t u t i o n . The successful outwardoriented countries have generally had lower coverage of p r i o r
lsee Bhagwafi (1978) and Krueger (1978).
117
licenses
systems, lower average t a r i f f s ,
less dispersion in their t a r i f f s , and less
episodes of real exchange rate overvaluation. Although the evidence supporting the merits of outward orientation is abundant, there
is no well-developed theoretical
model - -
or empirical
evidence for that matter - - linking very low (or zero) import t a r i f f s to higher 9rowth.2
Nor is there evidence suggesting that a completely "hands-
off" policy on behalf of the government is the most desirable alternative. In fact,
the success of the East Asian countries with export-led gro~h
suggests that
some selectively
determined degree of
intervention
specially aimed at supporting exports -- played a key role. and important question becomes one relating
--
The d i f f i c u l t
to the optimal degree of
government intervention or to the optimal level and structure of import tariffs.
This is indeed one of the most d i f f i c u l t question of economic
policy, whose answer (even at the pure abstract and theoretical level) w i l l depend on the existence of other distortions, the completeness of markets, and the availability of other policy tools, among other things.
II,
FOREIGNCAPITALAND TRADEREFORM
Krueger argues that
the
existing
multilateral
private banks and even some new multilateral
institutions,
the
agencies especially created
for this purpose should provide new funds to those countries
seriously
engaged in policy reforms. The idea is to have a smooth transition from an i l l i b e r a l to an open economy. The new funds would mainly be used to finance needed increases in imports - -
not matched in the short run by corre-
sponding increases of exports - - and to finance new investments. An important question is whether, rather than encouraging refor,l, these capital inflows will make liberalization less likely. For a long time Rona~d McKinnon has strongly argued against providing financial assistance to countries embarked on a liberalization effort.
In a recent piece where
he evaluated the (less than successful) Southern Cone experiences with liberalization, he wrote: [Olfficial International
2See Luca~
agencies such as the World Bank or the
Monetary Fund should not t r y
(1988) f o r a discussion
of
these issues.
118
to buy trade
liberalization by giving aid.
Never t r y to bribe someone
into liberalizing, because you are injecting capit~l at the time the liberalization occurs, and you mak~ the liberalization much harder to sustain. en~)hasis in the original|
!McKinnon 1984, p. 478;
McKinnon's point has mainly to do with real exchange rate behavior. Successful trade liberalization requires a real exchange rate depreciation, while the absorption of foreign capital requires a real appreciation. What capital inflows do, then~ is preclude the real exchange rate from devaluing sufficiently.
There is now empirical evidence supporting this view.
A
series of studies on real exchange rate behavior in the developing countries have indeed found that increased capital inflows result, with other things given, in a real exchange rate appreciation (Edwards, 1989, forthcoming). The recent experience of the Southern Cone is educational. Argentina attempted to liberalize i t s trade regime at the same time as absorbing major quantities of foreign capital. The real overvaluation generatc~ by these capital inflows, plus other policy mistakes, resulted in the ~ade reform policies having very l i t t l e credibility. Domestic firms used the newly obtained foreign capital to lobby against the reform instead of investing in those sectors where the country had a comparative advantage (Rodriguez 1983, Calvo 1986). The Chilean case is somewhat similar. The absorption of large amounts of foreign capital after April 1980, coupled with the pegging of the nominal exchange rate resulted in a (quasi) fatal real overvaluation that exceeded 30 percent and greatly contributed to the Chilean crisis of 1982 (Edwards, 1985). I t has been argued that one way of avoiding these problems is by adopting a very active nominal exchange rate policy consisting of a crawling peg. According to this system, in order to avoid overvaluation, the nominal exchange rate is frequently devalued at approximately the rate of domestic inflation. This recommendation, however, ignores two important points. First, the absorption of the foreign capital requires a real appreciation. I f the real exchange rate cannot adjust because the nominai rate is constantly devalued, the transfer of foreign capital fron, the rest
119
of the world to the country w i l l not take place. 3
Second, a policy of
accelerating the rate of nominal devaluation to combat real appreciation w i l l usually fuel domestic i n f l a t i o n .
I I I,
LIBEKa,LIZATION AND STABILIZATION
Krueger's paper does not deal with the important issue of the interrelation between disinflation policies and trade liberalization reform. She does not address the question of whether i t is convenient to implement farreaching trade reforms in countries suffering from high rates of i n f l a t i o n , nor does she ask whether i t
is appropriate to implement trade reforms at
the same time as disinflation programs are being pushed. This problem is particularly important, since a f a i r l y large number of the major debtors s t ~ l l face very high rates of inflation and have not solved their macroeconomic disequilibrium. In the three major Latin ~erican debtors - Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico -~ i n f l a t i o n is s t i l l above i t s level prior to the c r i s i s . 4 In other writings Krueger has dealt with this issue.
In fact her
article in the Brookings volume on i n f l a t i o n and stabilization (Krueger, 1981) is possibly the f i r s t piece de~oted to a systematic treatment of the relation between trade liberalization and stabilization policies. According to her, in theory there are few connections between the causes of inflation and those determining the nature of a country's trade regime. From there she goes on to argue that as long as a crawling peg system i s adopted, and the real exchange rate is maintained at the "appropriate" possible to reforms.
level, i t
is
basically separate the effects of stabilization and trade
She points out that " . . . i n principle the interaction between
different types of inflation and trade regimes can be minimal" (p. 83). Krueger's main message is that liberalization and stabilization programs
~The o n l y e x c e p t i o n s t o t h i s is when the a d d i t i o n a l e x p e n d i t u r e c a p i t a l f a l l s cOmpletely on imports o r t h e accumulation of f o r e i g n forthcOming}. In t h e case of t h e debt c r i s i s j i f t h e new funds are payments, t h e degree o f o v e r v a l u a t i o n may be reduced, b u t i t is v e r y f u l l y avoided.
f i n a n c e d by t h e f o r e i g n assets (Edwards, (~989} f u l l y used t o make debt u n l i k e | y t h a t i t w i l l be
4 A f t e r t h e f a i l u r e o f t h e h e t e r o d o x A u s t r a l and Cruzado p l a n s , A r g e n t i n a and B r a z i l see~ t o be p a r a l y z e d in the a n t i i n f l a t i o n a r y front. M e x i c o , on th~ ~ t h e r hand, Se~nS t c be making sOme progress w i t h i t s "Plan de ~ o l i d a r i d a d . "
120
can indeed be undertaken si~Jltaneously. However, as noted above i t is unclear whether i t is indeed possible to engineer a major disinflation while maintaining a crawling peg regime and a depreciated real exchange rate.
In theory, disinflation programs w i l l have
a higher probability of success i f domestic prices are (so~what) anchored to world prices.
This anchoring process, of course, requires (at least for
some time) a pegged nominal rate (and not a crawling peg). inflation
has
an
inertial
component, the
disinflation
I f domestic process will
i n i t i a l l y result in real exchange rate appreciation, hurting the chances of a successful major liberalization. Table 1 contain~ data on the evolution of the real exchange rate in 14 major successful stabilization programs.
In order for a country to qualify
as a "success~ in this exercise, i t had to meet the following requlre~.~ents: an inflation of (approximately) 50 percent per annum or more had to be reduced by at least one-half in no more than three years.
The table con-
tains all such cases since 1955 for which data can readily be obtained from the IFS.
As can be seen, in the majority of these "successful" s t a b i l i -
zation programs, g out of 14, the disinflation process was accompanied by real exchange rate appreciation.
Although this evidence is by no means
conclusive, i t suggests that there is a nontrivial tradeoff between stabilization and liberalization.
At this point an open question refers to ways
of designing successful policies that would allow countries to (at least p a r t i a l l y ) escape this tradeoff.
Surely just adopting a crawling peg will
not do the t r i c k in every (and not even in many) countries. A crucial objective of any stabilization program, and indeed of those undertaken by the major debtors, is to reduce the magnitude of the fiscal deficit.
Many times there will be an important trade-off between a trade
liberalization that fiscal objective.
reduces import t a r i f f s
and the achievement of thi~
Surprisingly, the policy and theoretical literatures on
trade liberalization policies have, most of the times, tended to ignore the fiscal
role of t a r i f f s
policy
discussions on trade
traditional public.
in the developing nations.
trade theory,
Most theoretical and
liberalization assume, along the
that t a r i f f
lines of
proceeds are handed back to the
In r e a l i t y , however, things are very different: governments do use
t a r i f f proceeds to finance their expenditure. This is particularly the case in many of the poorer developing countries, where for ulfferent
insti-
tutional reasons taxes on international trade represent a high percentage of government revenue. As long as tariFC rates are below the maximum revenue t a r i f f , there 121
Table I
D i s i n f l a t i o n and Rear Exchange Rates
GROUP 1: Country
DISINFLATION W!TH REAL APPRECIATION Years
Inflation
FI~R Index
Argentina
1976 1979
443.2 159.5
i00.0 43.0
Chile
1974 1977 1980
504.7 91.9 35.1
100.0 81.9 67.6
Costa Rica
1982 1985
90. I 15.1
100.0 94.5
Iceland
1983 1985
86.1 32.0
100.0 82.3
Nicaragua
1979 1982
48.2 24.8
100.0 64.6
Philippines
1984 1985
50.3 23.1
100.0 89.7
Ghana
1977 1980
116.5 50.1
100.0 78.8
Uruguay
1968 1970
125.3 17.0
100.0 80.7
?aire
1960 1971
53.3 5.8
100.0 85.2
GROUP 2:
DISINFLATION WiTH REAL DEPRECIATION
Dang ! adesh
1974 1977
54.7 8.6
100.0 209.6
Somalia
1980 1982
58.8 22.6
100.0 160.0
Turkey
1980 1983
110.2 32.9
100.0 146.0
Uruguay
1973 1976
97.0 50.6
!00.0 119.1
1979
108.6
1982
36.2
Za i r e
Notes: The RER index r e f e r s t o the b i l a t e r a l increase in the index denotes real depreciation.
122
I00.0
133.5
index with r e s i d e r t o the U.S. d o l l a r . An Data constructed Nith raw data fro~ the IMF.
will be a trade-off between trade liberalization and the generation of the government surplus required to finance debt servicing.
While the reduction
of tariffs will generally reduce distortions, it will also have a negative effect on goverrnent finances.
!f the reduction of goverr~ent expenditure
is not enough to reduc~ the deficit sufficiently, what is required, then, is to replace trade restrictions by less distortive taxes that are capable of generating the same (or a higher) amount of revenue. This, of course, means that major reforms of the t~_x system would be required in most countries.
As long as this tax reform effort also focuses on efficiency
aspects, it will tend to be concentrated on the imposition of a value-added tax {VAT), among other taxes.
This is not easy and ~akes time, as a number
of efforts to implement sweeping tax reforms have rec~.ntly shown.
Tax
reforms are not only politically difficult to approve, but from an administrative perspective they are many times very difficult to get goi~j. This is particularly the case in the poorer countries where the preexisting tax syste~ is often rudimentary.
Indeed the recer,t Indonesian tax reform has
shown clearly the difficulties involved in these types of efforts. {See Conrad and lillis, 1984). However, in middle-income countries where there is an operating tax system of some sophistication, a major tax reform can be implemented with some speed. The Chilean tax reform of 1975 is, in that sense, a good example; in little over a year a major tax overhaul that introduced a VAT, full indexation, and unification of corporate and r~ncorporate tax rates was successfully i~lemented {Edwards, 1985). Although in most cases the implementation of a major tax refo~u will take a substantial amount of time, there are some policies conducive both towards improved efficiency and higher revenues in th~ short run.
The most
obvious one is the replacement of QRs {i.e., licenses, prohibitions and so on) by i~ort tariffs.
A well-known feature of QRs is that unless they are
auctioned, the government misses the revenue associated with the trade restriction.
As recognized elsewhere by Krueger (1978), by replacing the
QR by a tariff it is possible for the government to recapture this revenue. The replacement of QRs by tariffs has two other potentially desirable effects.
First, there is the possibility of a positive effect on income
distribution.
This is because in most cases large (or even multinational)
firms or ~ j o r established merchants get the import licenses and, thus, the rents.
By replacing the QRs by tariffs these rents are passed on to the
goverr~ent, allowing it to reduce other taxes, or even to increase expenditure on social programs.
Second, the replacement of tariffs by QRs will
generally increase the effectivene-~ of devaluations. 123
The reason is that
the effects of devaluations are s i g n i f i c a n t l y different under quantity rationing ( i . e . , import quotas or licenses) than under import t a r i f f s .
In
the l a t t e r case a (real) devaluation w i l l result in a higher price of both importables and exportables relative to nontradables. while the domestic price of
exportables w i l l
importables w i l l usually not be affected.
UnderQRs, however,
still
increase, that of
All the devaluation w i l l do is
reduce the rents received by the party that got the license. C r e d i b i l i t y is a fundamental ingredient of successful structural reforms.
I f the public attaches a nontrivial probability to policy reversal,
i t w i l l t r y to anticipate t h i s event, genera%ly introducing strong destabil i z i n g forces into the structural adjustment process.
On the other hand,
c r e d i b i l i t y on the trade reform is very closely related to the macroeconomic policies being pursued alongside the trade reforms. Latin America's history is replete with frustrated economic reforms that have failed due to the lack of c r e d i b i l i t y .
In that respect, the
frustrated Argentinian trade reform during the Martinez de Hoz period is very educational.
Due to the lack of c r e d i b i l i t y on the future of the
preannounced trade reform, firms used foreign funds in order to survive in the short run.
As Carlos Rodrfguez ((1983), p. 28) has put i t
in his
evaluation of the Argentina experience of 1978-82, As
a
consequence of
the
lack
of
credibility
on the
continuity of the economic program, many firms - would have disappeared due to the t a r i f f
which
reductions - -
decided to get into debt in order to remain operating while waiting for
a change in the economic strategy [emphasis
added]. A fundamental aspect of establishing c r e d i b i l i t y is related to the perception that the public has of the internal consistency of the policies being pursued. In that respect, for example, the inconsistency of the Argentinian fiscal policy - - which maintained a very large d e f i c i t - - and the preannounced exchange rate policy severely undermined the degree of c r e d i b i l i t y of the reform process. The i n a b i l i t y to establish consistency between fiscal and exchange rate policies has many times been at the heart of the trade reform c r e d i b i l i t y crises in Latin America (Edwards, ICBg). An important question is whether a gradual ( i . e . , slow) trade reform would be less or more credible than an abrupt one. Theoretical models of c r e d i b i l i t y of economic policy are only now being developed, and have not yet reached ,evel that enables us to answer t h i s question with enough precision. In principle, i t is possible to argue that gradualism has 124
characteristics
that work in both directions, at the same time enhancing
and compromising credibility. On the one hand by reducing the unemployment effect and by allowing for I firmer fiscal equilibrium, a gradual trade reform will tend to be more credible; on the other hand a slow reform will allow those groups negatively affected by it {i.e., the import substitution manufacturing sector) to organize and nobly against the policies. At the end, as is so often the case in economics, whether gradualism will enhance credibility will depend on factors specific to each country. What is clear, however, is that policymakers should always pay special attention to the establishment of credibility when pursuing important long-te~) structural refo~s of the type proposed by Krueger for restoring creditwurthiness in debtor countries.
125
REFERFNCES Bhagwati, J.
(1978)
Anatomy and Consequences of Ezchonge Control Regimes, NBER, Cambridge, HA., Ballinger Publishing Co.
Calvo, G.
(1986)
Fractured Liberalism: Argentina Under Martinez de Hoz, EconomicDevelopmentandCulturalChange, 34: 511-31.
Conrad, R. and G i l l i s , M. (1984)
The Indonesian Tax Reform of 1983, Harvard Institute for Internaticnal Development, Discussion Paper No. 162.
Edwards, S.
(1985)
Stabilization With Liberalization: An Evaluation of Ten Years of Chile's Experiment With Free Market Policies, Economic Development and Cultural Chonge, 33: 223-54.
(1989)
Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation and Adjustment: Exchange Rate
Policy In Developing Countries, MIT Press (forthcoming). Krueger, A.O. (1978) Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development. Liberalization Attempts and Consequences, Ballinge~ Publishing Co. for NBER,
(1981)
Interactions Between InFlation and Trade Regime Objectives in Stabilization Programs, Economic Stabilization in Developing Countrie.% (eds.) W.R. Cline and S. Weintraub. Brookings Institution: Washington, D.C.
(1986)
Problems of Liberalization, Economic Liberalization in Developing Countries, (eds.) A. Choski and O. Papageorgious. Oxford: Basi 1 Blackwell.
126
Lucas, R.E. (1988)
On the Mechanics of Economic Development, JournoI of Monetary Economics, 22: 3-42.
NcKinnon, R. (1984) The International Capital Market and Economic Liberalization in LDCs, The Dev~opingF.conomies, 22: 476-81. Rodriguez, C.A. (1983) Politicas de Estabilizaci6n en la Economi~ Argentina, 19781982, CuadernosdeEconomia. Sachss J. (1987)
Trade and Exchange Rate Policies in Growth-Oriented Adjustment Programs, OrowtlPOr~entedAd]u~tment Programs, (eds.) V. Corbo, H. Goldstein and M. Khan. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund and the World Bank.
127