The QuarterlyReviewof lkon~mics and Fmce, Vol. 33, No. 4, Winter, 1993, pages 439-445 Copyright 0 1993 Trusteesof the Universityof Illinois All rightsof reproductionin any form reserved. ISSN 00335797
A Note on Budget Deficits, Debt Service Payments, and Interest Rates Richard J. Cebula and Rupert G. Rhodd Georgia Institute of Technology and Florida Atlantic International
The potential
impact
has been investigated 1984,
of federal
1985; Evans 1985,
Makin
1983; Mascaro
and Khan
1988).
budget deficits on interest
extensively
(Barth
and Bradley
1987; Feldstein
and Meltzer
and Eckstein
1983; McMillin
Most of these studies examine
short term interest rates, most commonly somewhat
differently,
attention
in the literature.
tional macroeconomics transmit because
nominal
This neglect
generally
the effect of federal the interest-sensitive
to variations decompose Bradley
in long-term
upon
components
Ostrosky
interest
rates.
have received
deficits upon only limited
in view of the fact that conven(not short term) interest
Furthermore,
of the budget
and cyclical
debt outstanding
None of this literature
rates This is
such as business are most sensitive
of this research
although components
has
a few studies (Barth
and
the deficit in terms of
(Dwyer 1982; Holloway
has attempted
to examine
1986;
the impact of
that is, no study has examined
impact of the deficit net of (less) debt service payments. analysis below, however, measuring
most
deficit,
1990) or define
the deficit after allowing for debt service payments, empirical
1990;
of private sector spending,
into its structural
in the real national
1986; 1987).
1986, 1987,
of budget
and new home construction,
1988; Barth et al. 1984; 1985; Ostrosky
the net change
1986;
budget deficits to the real side of the economy.
the N.1.P.A measure
the total deficit
is unfortunate
1983,
US Treasury bill rate. Stated
rates of interest
argues that long-term
outlays on new plant and equipment focused
1986; Ostrosky
the impact
States
Iden, and Russek
1970; Hoelscher
the three-month
long-term
rates in the United
1981; Barth,
As argued in the section
the on
the deficit thusly may be very appropri-
ate. This note seeks to add to the literature upon the nominal
long-term
interest
allow for debt service payments
referred
on the national
our insights into the deficit-interest
to above in two ways: (1) it focuses
rate; and (2) it adjusts the value of the deficit to debt. The analysis seeks to improve
rate relationship.
QUARTERLY REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE
440
THE MODEL To a large extent
paralleling
Hoelscher
(1983;
1986),
long-term
nominal
Barth
and Bradley
and Zahid
rate of interest
rium of the following
(1988),
(1989),
Barth
the model
as being determined
et al. (1984;
adopted
here
by a loanable
1985),
regards
the
funds equilib-
form: D-S=B-M-C
(1)
where: D= S =
real domestic
private sector demand
real domestic
private sector supply of long-term
for long-term
M=
real net purchases
of securities
B =
real net borrowing
by the federal
C =
real net capital flows into the nation from other nations.
The following
standard
behavioral
by the central
bonds
bonds
bank
government
relationships
are hypothesized:
D=D
(R,P,RSR),
DR>O,DP
(2)
S=S
(R,P,RSR),
SR < 0, Sp > 0, SRSR> 0
(3)
where: R=
the nominal
P=
the expected subscripts
It is hypothesized function
of the expected
(1986))
it is argued
the real demand more
real short-term
interest
that the higher
extensively
rate and where
the
partial differentiation.
is an increasing
smaller investors
(ex ante)
denote
rate
that, in accord with the standard
for bonds
decreasing
rate of interest
future inflation
the expected
RSR=
demand
long-term
funds model,
of the nominal
inflation
rate. In addition,
the expected
for long-term substitute
loanable
function
short-term
following
real short-term
ceteris @ibus.
bonds,
the real
rate of interest
and a
Hoelscher
rate of interest, That
the
is, as RSR rises,
bonds for long-term
bonds
in their
portfolios. It is also expected bonds is a decreasing Hoelscher
(1986),
rate, the greater
it is argued
the incentive
of new short-term
bonds,
supply of long-term Substituting
that, in accord function
with conventional
of the expected that the greater
for bond suppliers
R=R(P,RSR,B,M,C)
the real supply of
real short-term
to issue new long-term
function
2 and 3 into Equation
wisdom,
rate. Furthermore,
the expected
ceterh paribus. Therefore,
bonds is an increasing
Equations
inflation
it is hypothesized
following interest
bonds in lieu that the real
of RSR.
1 and solving for R yields: (4)
BUDGET DEFICITS, DEBT PAYMENTS, 8cINTEBEST BATES
441
The expected signs on the partial derivatives in Equation 4 are:
The first two signs are based upon the behavioral assumptions underlying Equations 2 and 3 above. Thus, it is expected that the nominal long-term interest rate is an increasing function of the expected inflation rate since bond supply increases and bond demand decreases when the expected inflation rate rises. Next, the sign on R~R should be positive because the real long-term bond supply increases and the real long-term bond demand decreases when the expected real short-term interest rates rises. Also, it is expected (in accord with the “conventional wisdom”) that interest rate should be, ceterisparibus, an increasing function of federal government borrowing. In other words, as conventional macroeconomic theory argues, as the federal govemment attempts to finance a deficit, it presumably generates upward pressure on the interest rate as it attracts funds to absorb its debt issuance. In the section of empirical analysis below, it is argued that the deficit should be measured net of debt service payments. Next, because of the fact that the central bank purchases of securities act to offset the effects of government borrowing, it is argued here that RM is negative. Finally, the expected sign on RC is negative to reflect the fact that net capital inflows from other nations act to absorb domestic issues and thereby to produce downward interest rate pressure.
EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS: THE NOMINAL LONGTERM RATE OF INTEREST Based upon the model summarized in Equations 4 and 5, we estimate the following quasi-reduced-form equation:
where: Et=
the nominal average interest rate yield in quarter t on ten-year US Treasury notes, expressed as a percent per annum;
ao’ P,=
constant term; the expected inflation rate in quarter t, expressed as a percent per annum;
R!SR=
the ex ante real average interest rate yield in quarter t on three-month US Treasury bills, expressed as a percent per annum;
BSY, =
the ratio of the seasonally adjusted total federal budget deficit in quarter t, net of (less) debt service payments on the national debt in quarter t, to the seasonally adjusted middleexpansion trend GNP in quarter t, expressed as a percent;
442
QUARTFSLY REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE MJY,
=
the ratio of Mt, which is defined as the average of the seasonally adjusted current
and preceding
market
instruments
quarters’
adjusted middle-expansion CJY,
=
States in quarter
trend GNP in quarter stochastic
CL= The model Zahid (1988)) of fixed because
is quarterly rates
(Bretton
expectations
inflation
rate in quarter rate
three-month
(P,)
capital into the
middle-expansion
Woods)
began
to collapse. Income
Next,
US Treasury
We end with 1985:4
Accounts
from Thies
in 1986.
(1986),
Variable P, represents
t. The variable RSR, is computed t from
Following
during which the system
the Economic Report of the President. The
from
expectations.
in quarter
1971%1985:4.
this is the quarter
the nominal
who generates
the averageexpected
by subtracting
average
interest
the expected rate yield
the
Specifically,
deficit
bills in quarter
variable
is defined
the deficit is defined
service payment
here
as nowhere
are reinvested
deficit per se effectively credit markets.
overstates
Focusing
accurately
because
to the extent
the magnitude
of net federal
borrowing
the net drain in billions
that deficits
of current
impose
dollars.
from the
may enable
on our credit
us to
markets.
The data to compute
B, were
from the Economic Rqboit of the President.
obtained
Following
Barth
M, is computed
and Bradley
by averaging
(1989))
moving
in the monetary loanable
funds in the economy.
et al. (1984))
adjusted
of credit
average is adopted
base to influence
data were obtained
Barth
the seasonally
values of the net acquisition
two-quarter
market
in order
banking
quarter
instruments
to allow adequate
system liquidity
M, is expressed
and Hoelscher
current
in billions
in billions
of current
(1983))
and preceding by the Fed. This
time for changes
and hence of current
from the Flow of Funds Accounts of the Federal
The C, data are also expressed
the supply of dollars. The M,
Reserve
GNP (YJ was obtained of current
dollars.
Hoelscher
this is because
from Holloway
In principle (1983;
1986))
(1986, Table 2) ; it too is expressed
following
Barth
and Holloway
it can be reasonably
argued
and Bradley
(1986))
(1989))
from trend
in billions
Evans
(1985;
we divide B,, M,, and Cr by Yr;
that the budget
and net capital flows should all be judged
System.
dollars and were obtained
the Flow ofFun& Accountsof the Federal Reserve System. The middleexpansion
actions,
that
in more US Treasury debt, the size of the current
on the deficit net of debt service payments
evaluate
B, is expressed
else in the literature.
here as the N.1.P.A federal budget deficit L%SS the debt
on Treasury debt. We follow this procedure
debt service payments
1987))
on
t (TBR,) . Both P, and TBR are expressed as per annum. TBR, was obtained from the Economic Report of the President.
a percent
Variable
adjusted
as a percent;
data (P,) were obtained
data on inflationary
inflation
of credit
to the seasonally
net flow of foreign
and initially covers the period
monthly
quarter
t, expressed
data for Rr were obtained
inflationary
System,
error term.
of the major revision of the US National
The
more
adjusted
t to the seasonally
we begin with 1971:4 because
exchange
Reserve
trend GNP in quarter t, expressed as a percent;
the ratio of the seasonally United
values of the net acquisitions
by the Federal
deficit,
monetary
policy
relative to the size of the economy.1
BUDGET DEFlClT!S, DEBT PAYMENTS, & INTEREST RATES Since
the federal
genous, its inclusion bias. Accordingly,
budget
Equation
nique, with the instrument
(lagged
two quarters),
President. In addition,
explains
adjusted
rate data were obtained
instruments
rate of the consumer
of the nominal
average interest
The criteria for choosing CPI,2
(CPI,2)
Equation
variable
variables,
(+lo.la)
DW = 1.71, where terms in parentheses
positive and statistically
significant
significant
using Ut_2, CPI,s
(7)
(-3.42)
DF = 50.
For example,
DW =
(+9.74)
1.72,
(net of debt service payments)
is
level. Thus, it appears exercises
a positive and
Rr in terms of other long-term
& as the nominal
average interest
+ 0.45B, /Yr - 2.03M,/Y, (+3.07)
coefficient
- O.lOC&
(8)
(-1.81)
(-1.55)
DF = 50. on variable
B/k’, is positive and
level, so that we infer once again that the deficit
exercises
rate of interest.
level. Of
on the deficit variable
(Mood,) ,3 the IV results are:
Rho = 0.10,
8, the estimated
at beyond the one percent
the expected
rate of interest.2
if we measure
bonds
exhibit
the one percent
coefficient
if we measure
corporate
(+4.06)
coefficients
the one percent
long-term
Mood, = 4.29 + 0.43P, + 0.83RSR,
long-term
(IV) technique,
at or beyond
at beyond
is also reached
yield on Moody’s Aaa-rated
nominal
parallel those of choosing
(net of debt service payments)
impact upon the nominal
This same conclusion
significant
lag
US Treasury notes (Three,*).
(-1.16)
7, all five of the estimated
budget deficit
As shown in Equation
and (2) the twoquarter
- 1.69M,/Y, - 0.2OC&
(+3.11)
is the fact that the estimated
rate measures.
respec-
lag of the
are t-values.
As shown in Equation
interest
P, and ES&,
yields:
Rho = 0.10,
signs, with four of the coeffkients
significant
Economic Rgbort of the
from the BusinRFs
6 by instrumental
(+5.32)
that the federal
the contempo-
Conditions Digest (March, was obtained from the Economic Report of the President.
as the instrumental
interest
the
as instruments
Rr = 2.16 + 0.59P, + O.SORSR, + 0.58B,/Y,
particular
is
rate of the
(1) the two-quarter
rate yield on three-year
was obtained
rate
with the lagged unemployment
of the variables
price index
CPI,p and Three,2
1989) ; variable Three,2 Estimating
(IV) tech-
of instrument
unemployment
from
have been adopted:
actual inflation
Ut_2 above. Variable
variables
the budget deficit, whereas
to allow for endogeneity
tively, two additional
is partly endo-
Ut_% The choice
terms in the system are not correlated
rate. The unemployment
and Three,2
using an instrumental
the fact that the lagged seasonally
error
payments)
the possibility of simultaneousequation
being the seasonally adjusted quarterly unemployment
civilian labor force systematically raneous
(net of debt service
6 is estimated
of the civilian labor force based upon
deficit
in the analysis introduces
443
a positive and significant
impact
upon
the
QUARTERLY REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE
444
CONCLUSIONS Within an open-economy
loanable-funds
framework, the impact of the US federal
budget deficit upon long-term interest rates has been investigated. Unlike the existing literature,
the deficit has been defined here as the N.I.P.A. budget deficit less debt
service payments. This focus on the deficit net of debt service payments is based on the idea that to the extent that debt service payments are reinvested in more US Treasury debt, the size of the total current deficit per se effectively overstates the magnitude of net federal government borrowing from the credit markets. The analysis has focused upon the nominal long-term interest rate, which has received only limited attention in the literature to date. The empirical
results imply that the federal budget deficit, net of debt service
payments, elevates the nominal long-term rate of interest. This finding has important implications. For example, to the extent that interest rates are higher in the U.S. than otherwise would be the case, the probability of “Third World” debt crises is elevated. In other words, higher interest rates in the U.S. will raise the cost of borrowing to Third World nations and thereby increase the likelihood of defaults by Third World nations on interest and debt payments. In addition, the evidence would imply, strictly from the U.S. perspective,
the existence
result of the budget deficit). slower capital formation
of crowding-out
In turn, the crowding
and slower economic
of private investment
out of private investment
(as a
implies
growth in the U.S. over the long run.
NOTES 1.
It should be noted that the conclusions derived below are basically unchanged if we
simply express Bt, Mt, and Ct in billions of constant dollars. 2.
It should be noted that a similar conclusion is reached ifwe do not subtract debt service
from the deficit, that is, if we replace Bt in Equation 6 with the tot&federal budget deficit (Dt) per se. The IV results are given by: Rt = 3.55 + 0.4OPt + 0.48RSRt + 0.41DJYt (+3.10)
(+4.80)
DW = 1.51,
(+2.90)
Rho = 0.24,
- 0.60MJYt
- 0.18CJYt
(-0.43)
(-2.30)
(9)
DF = 50.
with the time period studied being 19’71:4-1985:4. Dt is expressed in billions of current dollars and was obtained from the Economic Rqbort of the President. As shown above, the total budget deficit variable also exercises a positive and significant impact upon nominal longer-term interest rate. 3. Variable Moodt was obtained from the Economic Rtprt
of the President.
BUDGET DEFICI-IS, DEBT PAYMENTS, & INTERFST BATES
445
REFERENCE!3 Barth, James R and Michael D. Bradley. 1989. “Evidence on Real Interest Effects of Money, Deficits, and Government Spending.” Quarterly Reuti ofEconomics and Business 29(Spring): 49-57. c-4 Barth, James R, George Iden, and Frank S. Russek. 1984. “Do Federal Deficits Really Matter?” Contemporary Policy Issues 3(Fall): 79-85. 1985. “Federal Borrowing and Short Term Interest Rates: Comment.” Southern 131 -. Economic Journal 52(0ctober): 554-559. [41 Dwyer, Gerald E 1982. “Inflation and Government Deficits.” Economic Inquiry PO(July): 315-329. [51 Evans, Paul. 1985. “Do Large Deficits Produce High Interest Rates?” American Economic Review 75(March): 68-87. 1987. “Interest Rates and Expected Future Deficits in the United States.” Journal [61 -. of Political Economy 95(February) : 3455. 171 Feldstein, Martin and Otto E&stein. 1970. “The Fundamental Determinants of the Interest Rate.” R&zw ofEconomics and Statistics 52(May): 363-375. I81 Hoelscher, Gregory. 1983. “Federal Borrowing and Short Term Interest Rates.” Southern Economic Journal 50(0ctober): 319-333. 1986. “New Evidence on Deficits and Interest Rates.” Journal of Money, Cnzdit, and [91 -. Banking Z8( February) : l-l 7. [lOI Holloway, Thomas M. 1986. “The Cyclically Adjusted Federal Budget and Federal Debt: Revised and Updated Estimates.” Sur-ueyof Current Business 66(March): 11-17. Makin, John H. 1983. “Real Interest, Money Surprises, Anticipated Inflation and Fiscal [ill Deficits.” Review of Economics and Statistics 65(May): 374384. 1121 Mascara, Angelo and Allan H. Meltzer. 1983. “Long and Short Term Interest Rates in a Risky World.” Journal of Monetary Economics 20( March) : 15 l-200. McMillin, W.D. 1986. “Federal Deficits and Short Term Interest Rates.” Journal of ll31 Macmeconomics 8( Summer) : 403-422. Ostrosky, Anthony L. 1990. “Federal Government Borrowing and Interest Rates: A [l41 Comment.” Southern Economic Journal 56 (January): 802-803. 1987. “Government Deficits and Interest Rates.” Weltwirtschuftliches Archiv [l51 -. 123(December): 905-914. 1986. “Deficits and Financial Crowding Out.” Public Chuice IO(January): 69-76. 1161 -. 1171 Thies, Clifford. 1986. “Business Price Expectations.” JournaZofMoney, Credit, and Banking 18(August): 234250. I181 Khan, Zahid. 1988. “Government Budget Deficits and Interest Rates: The Evidence Since 1971, UsingAlternativeDeficit Measures.” Southern EconomicJournal54(April): 725-731. [ll