P under supply disturbances; (v) the variances of the spot and futures prices respectively are both lower under demand disturbances than under supply disturbances; and (vi) the variance of the futures price is less than the variance of the spot price. 26The analogous tables for values 1 and 100 are available from the authors. “See McCafferty and Driskill (1980).
0.0084 0.833 0 0.833
3.29 1 11.465 0.765 16.507
3.338 16.503 0.819 16.699
a: P 03 p*
0: P 0; P’
0.0084 0.833 0 0.836
2
set
1
Parameter
15.837 18.567 0.813 16.287
15.156 21.016 0.754 15.197
3
Table 3
5 disturbances 0.134 3.335 0.0059 3.33 1 disturbances 0.134 3.33 1 0.0059 3.338
A. Demand 0.938 10.018 0.138 9.982 B. Supply 0.939 9.978 0.139 10.022
solutions.
4
Nonintervention
0.326 3.334 0.0143 3.333
0.326 3.340 0.0142 3.330
6
0.0392 0.834 0.0017 0.833
0.0392 0.835 0.0017 0.833
I
0.0061 0.909 0.0003 0.909
0.0061 0.909 0.0003 0.909
8
0.207 0.834 0.0001 0.833
0.207 0.834 0.0001 0.833
9
3.227 16.663 0.712 16.668
3.226 16.683 0.711 16.664
10
190
R.B. Campbell
and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention
in spot and futures markets
Initial conditions were therefore set in the range 0 to 1 with a grid search being carried out with alternative initial conditions within the range. No examples of multiple feasible solutions were found in the presence of intervention. Furthermore, numerous examples of nonfeasible solutions, after intervention, were found for particular initial conditions, but a unique feasible solution could always be found by using alternative initial conditions. The absence of multiple feasible solutions and the fact that intervention does not lead to existence problems is of some importance in a practical policy context. 6. Rule 1: G, = - I(P, - P) The results pertaining to rule 1, where the stabilization authorities are assumed to intervene in the spot market, are set out in tables 4 and 5. The solutions for the means and variances of the spot and futures prices are given in table 4. The percentage differences refer to the differences between the intervention solutions and the corresponding nonintervention solutions presented in table 3. The welfare results are reported in table 5. In both cases, the effects for demand disturbances and supply disturbances are given separately. The values of the intervention parameters 1=0.5, i= 10 proxy ‘low’ and ‘high’ degrees of intervention, respectively. 6.1. Effects on long-run distributions
of prices
As one would expect, intervention in the spot market by means of rule 1 results in the stabilization of both the spot and futures prices. Interestingly, very large reductions in the variances of both the spot and futures prices can be achieved for a relatively low degree of intervention; see, for example, ;1=0.5, cases 1 and 3. But it is also possible for negligible stabilization to be achieved for 2 =0.5. Examples of this are given in cases 2 and 8, which have in common a high value of a, but very different degrees of risk aversion. For relatively intensive intervention, the effect of a high a is swamped and it can be seen from table 4 that for A= 10 a high degree of stabilization of both the spot and futures price can be achieved for all parameter combinations. It is of interest to note that while significant reductions in both variances can be achieved, the futures price is always stabilized to a greater degree than the spot price even though the intervention occurs directly in the spot market. The reason for this can be seen from (28e). The intervention impinges on the variance of the futures price in two ways. First, it reduces the variance of the spot price. Secondly, by reducing the one-period variance of the spot price, it increases both the numerator and the denominator of q, the coefficient of 0;. It can be shown that on balance the effect on the denominator dominates, so that y falls, leading to a relatively greater stabilization of the futures market.
a= 10
i=os
0 100 0.8330 0.02 0.8343 -0.19
0.0001 -99.99 16.6068 0.63 16.6187 -0.12
% Diff
gJ Diff
F Diff
4
0.0023
0.0083
-13
0 - 100 0.8328 0 0.8358 -0.012
-9
0.1 124 -86 16.3528 -0.91 16.1294 0.18
-77
0.0077
0.7676
0 0.8334 0 0.8332 0.05
-100
0.0001 -99 16.6695 -4.55 16.6661 0.96
-73
0.0023
-99
0.0083
-8
0.0077 0 0 0.8334 0 0.8328 0
0.7621
L
?
0.1063 -86 16.8894 -3.3 - 16.6221 0.7
-17
1
-99
sets
ZDifl
2
% Diff
$DifT
% Diff
Parameter
1.708
4 5
0.0094 0 100 16.6028 - 10.6 16.6795 2.4
-99
0.0358 -96 16.3128 -12 16.7253 2.1
-89
1.7100
0.0094 - 100 0 ~ 100 16.6699 - 20.68 16.6660 5.50
0.0077 0
0.006
3.3334 - 0.04 3.3332 0.79
-100
-96
0.0077 0.0001 -99.93 9.9962 0.18 10.0038 -0.18
-99
0.0060 0.00003 - 99.49 3.3326 0.05 3.3348 -0.1
-96
B. Supply disturbances 0.3907 0.0946 -58 -30 0.390 0.00337 -72 -43 9.9812 3.3312 0.034 0.006 10.0189 3.3376 -0.033 -0.012
0 -100 10.0002 -0.18 9.9998 0.18
-99
0.0069
0.1940
0
0.0071 0.0001
0.0043
o.oooo3 -99.19 3.3326 -0.04 3.3337 0.02
-98
0.0001 -94.15 0.8333 - 0.08 0.8333 0.012
-89
0.0043
0.00133
0.0323
0.007 1
-22
-18
0.8335 -0.16 0.8333 0.02
-94
-89
0.8338 - 0.024 0.8332 0
0.0069
0.1940
0.0013
0.0322
0.8344 -0.02 0.8331 0
-24
-18
I
3.3321 -0.4 3.3337 0.021
-52
-40
3.3335 -0.20 3.3333 0.10
-100
-98
3.3375 - 0.08 3.3313 0.04
-51
-40
6
of prices: rule 1.
A. Demand disturbances 0.3904 0.0945 -89 -58 -30 0.034 0.0387 0.0034 -96 -12 -42 17.2358 10.0080 3.3343 - 18.0 -0.1 -0.01 16.5528 9.9920 3.3315 4.19 0.1 0.02
3
Table 4 Effects on distributions
0.00004
0.0019
0.9091 0 0.9094 0
0.00026
0.0056
0.909 1 0 0.9091 0
0
0.0019
o.Oc03 0 0.9091 0 0.909 1 0
0.0056
0.9091 0 0.9093 -0.01
-87
-69
-13
-8
-100
-67
-8
8
0.00005
0.1375
0.0067
0.1375
0.0067 0 100 0.8333 ~ 0.07 0.8333 0.012
-97
o.OOoO3 -70 0.8337 - 0.024 0.8333 0.012
-34
0 - 100 0.8334 - 0.08 0.8333 0.01
-91
0.8338 ~ 0.04 0.8332 0
-50
-34
9
0.1579
0.0083
0.7580
0.0083 O.oool - 99.99 16.6656 0.02 16.6669 -0.004
-99
0.1015 -86 16.6605 ~ 0.012 16.6678 0.0018
-71
0.0001 -100 16.666 - 0.09 16.666 0.02
-100
0.1014 -86 16.6708 - 0.07 16.6658 0.01
-17
10
0.6564 3.0895
0.3814
1.0378 3.4709
D. Total private we(fare AE(n) AE(V)
E. Gouernment
F. Total weljare AE(IIT) AE( V’)
- 3.1450 ~ 24.3307 - 1.9284
5.4456
B. Consumers AE(CS)
C. Speculators AE(n”) A[var IY( l)] A E( V)
- 1.6444 - 24.3307 -0.4279
A. Producers AE(I7”) d[var HP(l)] AE( V”)
1
o.OOQ41
0.00003 0.0004 o.oooo1
2
0.0042 0.0040
0.0039
o.OQO2 0.0012
- o.ooo2 0.0004 -0.ooo3
Parameter sets
5.8425 20.7982
0.8539
4.9886 19.9443
- 18.4657 149.5554 - 10.9879
32.4760
-9.0216 149.5554 - 1.5438
3
Table 5
5
0.2488 0.2992
0. I952
0.0536 0.1040
- 0.0963 -0.0914 -0.0917
0.2158
- 0.0658 -9.1431 - 0.0201
-0.0487 0.0054
0.0473
- 0.096 0.0067
-0.1120 -0.0033 -0.0110
0.0179
-0.0019 -0.3272 - 0.0002
A. Demand disturbances i,=o.5
4
Welfare effects: rule 1.
0.1120 0.1255
0.0970
0.0150 0.0285
-0.0516 ~ 1.3514 - 0.0449
0.0782
-0.0015 ~ 1.3514 - 0.0048
6
0.0177 0.0181
0.0161
0.0016 0.0020
~ 0.0087 -0.0527 -0.0085
0.0127
~ 0.0024 - 0.0527 ~ 0.0022
7
0.0029 0.0029
0.0028
O.OOQO8 O.GQOO8
-0.oQo5 -0.00001 - 0.0005
0.0006
- 0.00002 -0.00001 - o.oOOO2
8
0.0761 0.0174
0.0688
0.0073 0.0086
- 0.0080 - 1.2895 - 0.0074
0.0167
-0.0014 - 1.2895 -0.0007
9
0.5778 0.6360
0.3789
0.1989 0.2571
-0.3121 - 1.0577 -0.3068
0.7501
-0.2391 105.7742 -0.1862
10
Producers
-4.3906 - 34.9676 - 2.6423
1.2862 4.7829
0.0337 0.0339
0.0228
0.0829
E. Government
F. Total welfare AE(liT) AE(VT)
AW’) AE(Y)
0.0109 0.0111
- 0.0028 - 0.0026 - 0.0027
0.0133
0.0004 ~ 0.0026 0.0005
1.2033 4.7000
D. Total private welfare
7.9624
C. Speculators AE(lP) A[var Il’( l)] AE( I”)
-2.3685 - 34.9616 -0.6201
B. Consumers AE(CS)
A[varIP(l)] AE[Vp)
AE(W’)
A.
5.7948 23.6795
0.0944
5.7004 23.5851
-21.5696 - 178.8472 - 12.6272
38.2890
- 11.0190 - 178.8472 - 2.0767
0.4427 0.5320
0.0771
0.3656 0.4549
-0.1919 -0.1624 -0.1838
0.6649
-0.1074 - 16.2364 -0.0262
0.2731 0.3066
0.0705
0.0601 0.1707 0.1769
0.2026 0.2361
-0.1324 - 3.3503 0.1157
0.3601
-0.0251 - 3.3503 -0.0083
0.1106 0.1168
- 0.0405 -0.0112 - 0.0399
0.1569
- 0.0058 - 1.1234 -0.0002
0.0870 0.0920
0.0426
0.0444 0.0494
- 0.0477 -0.5057 -0.0452
0.1036
-0.0115 -0.5057 - 0.0090
0.0262 0.0262
0.0186
0.0076 0.0076
-0.0046 - 0.00006 - 0.0046
0.0123
-0.0001 - 0.00006 -O.OQOl
0.222 1 0.2257
0.0672
0.1549 0.1585
-0.0218 - 2.4155 - 0.0206
0.1785
-0.0018 -2.4155 -0.0006
0.7893 0.8685
0.0829
0.7064 0.7856
- 0.4648 - 1.4401 - 0.4576
1.4663
-0.2231
-0.2951
_ 144.0074
1.6911 19.1727 0.7325
C. Speculators AE(I7’) A[var n’( l)] AE( V”)
1.2504
0.4606
-
0.3838
Government
F. Total weljare AE(L”‘) AE(VT)
E.
AW) AE(V)
0.0768 - 1.6342
1.1301
B. Consumers AE( CS)
D. Total private welfare
- 2.7444 15.04794 - 3.4968
A. Producers AE(nP) A[var nq l)] AE( V”)
1
0.00381 0.00093 0.00376
2
0.0040 0.00383
0.00385
0.00015 -0.oOOo2
-0.00006 0.00238 -0.00018
-0.0036
Parameter sets
24.4495 28.5008
0.8550
23.5945 27.6458
- 4.0033 - 27.7348 - 2.6665
17.9053
9.6925 - 54.2022 12.4027
3
Table 5 (continued)
5
1
0.2467 0.1659
0.1954
0.0513 - 0.0295
-0.0709 0.1551 -0.0787
-0.1543
0.2765 14.6024 0.2035
0.0519 0.0485
0.0473
0.0046 0.0012
- 0.0102 0.0069 -0.0105
- 0.0402
0.0550 0.6130 0.0519
B. Supply disturbances a=o.5
4
Welfare effects: rule
0.1240 0.1252
0.0970
0.0270 0.0282
~ 0.0380 0.0053 -0.0380
- 0.0570
0.1220 - 0.2440 0.1232
6
0.0232 0.0187
0.0161
0.0071 0.0026
-0.0086 ~ 0.0524 - 0.0084
-0.0056
0.0163 -0.0655 0.0166
7
0.0026 0.0026
0.0028
- 0.0002 ~ 0.0002
-0.005 0.0012 - 0.0005
- 0.0026
0.0029 0.0003 0.0029
8
0.0769 0.0779
0.0688
0.0081 0.0091
- 0.0077 -0.9165 - 0.0072
-0.0683
0.0841 - 1.0559 0.0846
9
0.5759 0.5396
0.3790
0.1969 0.1606
-0.2941 0.6929 -0.2976
-0.1068
0.5978 65.5656 0.5650
10
5.6348 60.730 2.5983
0.6523 -5.148
C. Speculatirs AE(Il’) d[var n”(l)] AE( V’)
D. Total private w&are AW0 AE(V)
F. Total welfare AE(IIT) AE( VT)
0.7352 - 5.0651
0.0829
- 1.0293
B. Consumers AE(CS)
E. Government
- 3.9532 55.28 -6.7170
A. Producers AE(Il”) d[var IIp(l)] AE( VP)
0.0335 0.0314
0.0228
0.0107 0.0086
0.00007 0.0265 -0.0013
- 0.0309
0.0415 0.0143 0.0408
24.1844 22.9089
0.0944
24.09 22.8 145
1.3503 28.16 - 0.0577
15.4017
7.3380 -2.6510 7.4705
0.4406 0.1705
0.0771
0.3635 0.0934
-0.1247 0.5057 -0.1500
-0.3251
0.8133 48.97 0.5685
0.2793 3.7840 0.2604
0.1706 0.1497
0.0601
0.1105 0.0896
- 0.0353 0.0403 -0.0373
-0.1335
1= 10
0.2850 0.2692
0.0705
0.2145 0.1987
- 0.0801 1.8734 - 0.0895
-0.1497
0.4443 1.2638 0.4379
0.0918 0.0934
0.0426
0.0492 0.0508
- 0.0440 -0.1315 - 0.0434
- 0.0294
0.1226 -0.1981 0.1236
0.0263 0.0262
0.0186
0.0076
-0.0045 0.0125 -0.0046
-0.0211
0.0333 0.0045 0.0333
0.2229 0.2253
0.0672
0.1557 0.1581
-0.0216 -2.1832 - 0.0205
-0.1957
0.3730 -2.5842 0.3743
0.7873 0.6814
0.0829
0.7044 0.5985
- 0.4302 1.9704 -0.4401
-0.1867
1.3213 1.92 1.2253
196
R.B. Campbell
and S.J. Turnoosky, Intervention
in spot and futures markets
In terms of variance reduction it would appear that for particular parameter combinations, little can be gained by increasing the degree of intervention beyond A= 1. This is so, for example, for cases 1, 3, and 10, which are typified by very low values of a. Furthermore, comparing the reductions in the variances in tables 4A and 4B it is seen that intervention in accordance with rule 1 is approximately equally effective in stabilizing for demand disturbances as it is for supply disturbances. The qualitative effect of intervention by means of rule 1 on the long-run mean prices depends critically upon the source of origin of the stochastic disturbances. In the case of demand shocks, the mean spot price is always lowered, while the mean futures price is always raised. The reason for this is seen from (28). The intervention reduces both the long-run and the oneperiod variance of the spot price. While this tends to reduce a,, there is a more than offsetting increase in b, so that a, +b rises, thereby lowering the long-run mean spot price P. At the same time, the coefficient of P in (28b) is increased, by a more than offsetting amount and the long-run mean futures price tends to rise. In the case of supply disturbances, the intervention may cause the long-run mean prices to either rise or fall. The reason is that whereas a, will still fall, b may now either rise or fall, rendering the net effect on the mean spot price r’ indeterminate. However, in all cases, the spot and futures prices move in opposite ways (as they do for demand disturbances). In comparison with the reductions in the variances, which we showed could be significant, the changes in the mean spot and futures prices are relatively small. The greatest reduction in the spot price achieved for all parameter sets was around 20 percent. The changes in the futures price are all much smaller, the maximum being less than 6 percent. In concluding our comments on the price effects, the following observations may be made. Whereas, the intervention appears to stabilize both demand and supply disturbances equally effectively, the intervention has a relatively greater impact on mean prices when disturbances originate with demand than when they are due to supply shocks. Secondly, reductions in the mean prices are fairly insensitive to varying degrees of intervention. Thirdly, as intervention increases, the mean spot and futures prices converge to a common value for a particular set of parameter values. Indeed, for A= 100 (not reported) the spot and futures prices are identical for each particular set of parameters. Finally, the reason why intervention has such a large impact on both variances but a relatively small impact on both mean prices can be explained by the fact that intervention by means of rule 1 has only an indirect effect on the means prices, whereas it impacts on the variances directly. 6.2. WeEfare effects Since the welfare
criteria
introduced
in Section
4 involve
the asymptotic
R.B. Campbell and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention in spot and futures markets
197
means and variances the prices, the results we have just been considering are the key inputs in determining the welfare effects within the economy of the intervention rule. The welfare of the various agents shall be discussed in turn. 6.2.1. Producers (i) The welfare of producers as measured by expected profit, can either increase or decrease with intervention. For most parameter sets, when disturbances originate with demand, expected profit tends to fall with intervention, while for supply disturbances, expected profit tends to rise. These findings reflect the stabilizing effect of intervention on the price level and are consistent with the usual results of the buffer stock stabilization literature. The exceptions to this pattern are marginal, except parameter set 1, where expected profit fall quite sharply with intervention in the presence of supply disturbances. This particular result is a consequence of the fall in the spot price, together with the only modest increase in the futures price. (ii) Intervention tends to stabilize the profit of firms (i.e. reduce its one period variance) in the presence of demand disturbances and generally, but not always, destabilize it in the presence of supply shocks. The reduction in the variance of the spot and futures prices are obviously stabilizing. But the variance of profit also depends upon (P’--P)‘. This tends to be reduced by intervention in the case of demand disturbances and to be increased in the case of supply shocks. In the former case, the stabilizing effects of the reduced variance of price is reinforced; in the latter case it is offset. (iii) The welfare of producers, as measured by E(V) generally falls in the case of demand disturbances and rises in the case of supply disturbances. The losses in the former case are less than those of expected profit. This is because intervention tends to stabilize producer profit in that case. Likewise, the gains in the latter case are less than those of expected profit. This is due to the destabilizing effect of intervention on profit associated with supply disturbances. 6.2.2. Consumers Consumers gain from intervention when the stochastic fluctuations originate with demand. They may either gain or lose when the fluctuations are due to supply disturbances. They usually lose when the fluctuations are due to supply disturbances, although, in the latter case they also make significant gains. The magnitude of the effects to consumers reflect the behavior of the mean and variance of the spot price. The reduction in the mean price tends to benefit them, while the reduction in the variance tends to harm them. The significant gains experienced for Parameter Set 3 are due primarily to the large reduction in the mean spot price (18 and 12 percent for demand and supply disturbances, respectively) which occurs in that case. Since the
198
R.B. Campbell and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention in spot and futures markets
reductions in the means through intervention are smaller under supply disturbances, the benefits to consumers are smaller in that case. It is also possible that increased intervention turns consumer gains into losses; see, for example, parameter set 1 for 1=0.5 and ,? = 10. This is because in the presence of supply disturbances, intervention can actually raise the mean spot price, thereby adversely affecting consumers. 6.2.3. Speculators (i) The expected profits of speculators always decline with intervention when disturbances originate with demand. The same applies in the case of supply disturbances for all but parameter set 1. The reduction in the variance of the spot price, resulting from intervention, tends to reduce the expected profit of speculators, But their expected profit also depends positively upon (P’ - P)‘; see (32a). As noted, this tends to decline with intervention in the case of demand disturbances, so that the expected profit of speculators is reduced unambiguously in that case. However, it tends to be increased in the case of supply shocks, thereby offsetting the losses from more stable spot price. Indeed, in the case of parameter set 1, this effect can dominate leading to gains to speculators. (ii) The one-period variance of speculative profits is almost always reduced through intervention, in the case of demand disturbances and usually increase in the case of supply disturbances. Exceptions in both cases do exist. The reason involves the effects of intervention on the variance of the spot price and the divergence between the long-run mean spot and futures prices. (iii) The welfare of speculators as measured by their overall utility function E(V) is always reduced by intervention in the case of demand disturbances and usually falls in the case of supply disturbances. Parameter set 1 is the exception for all degrees of intervention.
6.2.4. Total private welfare (i) Total private welfare effects, as measured by dE(Z7), are almost always positive for both disturbances. Exceptions are parameter set 5 for demand disturbances and parameter set 8 for supply disturbances, when small losses are incurred when intervention is weak. These losses, however, are converted to gains with more intensive intervention (A> 1). The overall private gains are larger in the case of supply disturbances than for demand disturbances. (ii) Total private welfare effects as measured by dE(V) are always positive in the case of demand disturbances, although there may be losses in the case of supply disturbances, through the increases in the variances in producer and speculator profits. More intensive intervention does not eliminate the losses as measured in this way, and indeed may intensify them.
R.B. Campbell and S.J. Turnoosky, Intervention in spot and futures markets
6.2.5.
199
Government
The government always ensures itself an expected profit from intervening in accordance with rule 1. For a given degree of intervention, their gains are marginally higher for supply disturbances, than they are for demand disturbances. For very high degrees of intervention (A= 100) gains become small. This of course is due to the fact that although il gets large, the subsequent decline in the variance of the spot price more than offsets this. The relationship between the intervention parameter A, and gains to the government is nonlinear. For example, for parameter set 2 gains to the government are increased as A increases from 0.5 to 1 to 10, before subsequently declining. There is therefore an optimal degree of intervention from the viewpoint of maximizing government revenue.28 6.2.6. Total welfare Total welfare as measured by expected profits is always positive. Total welfare as measured by dE(Vr) is always positive in the case of demand disturbances and with the exception of parameter set 1, in the case of supply disturbances as well. In this case the losses to producers are not compensated by the gains to the other agents in the economy. 7. Rule 2: H,_,=v(P{_,-P&J We consider now rule 2, whereby the stabilization authority behaves as a utility maximizing agent. In contrast to rule 1, we find that in general, stabilization is virtually ineffective for all degrees of intervention in terms of variance reduction and changes in the mean price. Indeed, rule 2 is so ineffective that only 2 of the 10 representative cases are worth reporting. Both of these cases (parameter sets 1 and 3) are associated with high risk aversion and inelastic demand. These are set out in tables 6 and 7. The effect of rule 2 on the distribution of prices and welfare for all other parameter sets is virtually zero. 7.1. Effects on long-run distributions
of prices
Intervention via rule 2 has the effect of stabilizing the spot and futures prices. In the case of demand disturbances, the mean spot price is reduced, while in the case of supply disturbances it can be either reduced or increased. Likewise, the mean futures price is increased in the case of demand disturbances, while it can be either decreased or increased in the case of supply disturbances. In most cases, the mean futures price is less than the ‘sin the limiting case when I= CC and stabilization authority are reduced to zero.
J.P E.-C
the spot
price
is stabilized
exactly,
gains
to the
200
R.B. Campbell and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention in spot and futures markets Table 6 Effects on distributions Parameter 1 A. Demand z ZDifT
v=o.5
% Diff 2 2Diff 0; v=lO
sets
Parameter 3
I
disturbances
-0.1 0.7616 3.277 -0.4 17.4199
gDiff gfDiff
of prices: rule 2.
-0.26 16.5160 0.05 -1 3.2488 0.7343
P Diff gJDiff
-417.0344 - 16.5931 2.46
% Diff
0.52
sets 3
B. Supply disturbances 2 -0.1 15.734 0.7360 -2 19.9707 -4.97 16.0059 1.32 15.6852 -0.5 0.6919 -8 17.2646 - 17.85 16.5471 4.74
5Difi ” = 0.5
“/;, Diff
v=lO
$ Diff
% Diff
-0.222 0.8122 3.3307 -0.83 16.5104 0.042 16.6979 - 0.009
~15.7916 0.7813 0.272 -3.8 18.1421 - 2.29 16.3720 0.523
3.2730 - 1.95 0.7578 - 7.47 16.5810 0.47 16.6838 - 0.093
15.6945 -0.885 0.7007 - 13.76 16.9508 -8.71 16.6094 1.98
mean spot price, although this is not the case of supply disturbances with parameter set 1. An interesting comparison of rule 2 with rule 1 is that the former has a relatively greater impact on the mean than on the variance of the spot price. For example, with parameter set 3, setting v= 10 we find that for supply disturbances a 9 percent reduction in the mean is associated with a 0.9 percent reduction in the variance. With A= 10 in rule 1, we find that a 10.6 percent reduction in the mean is associated with a 99 percent reduction in the variances. In all cases, the change in both mean prices are always greater under rule 1 than under rule 2 (for equivalent values of the intervention parameters). Parameter set 3, with v= 100 (not reported) represents the greatest impact obtained for all rule 2 simulations. While the effects on the mean spot and futures prices are comparable in magnitude than under rule 1, the effects on the corresponding variances are considerably less. In summary, we see that in terms of price and variance reduction, rule 2 is substantially inferior to rule 1. Indeed, in most cases, intervention by means of such a rule will have a negligible impact on the market. 7.2. Welfare effects Since the welfare effects operate through the means and variances of the prices, the welfare effects essentially mirror them. In particular, in all but
R.B. Campbell and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention in spot and futures markets
201
Table 7 Welfare effects: rule 2. Parameter sets 1
3
-
1
3
A. Demand disturbances v=lO
v=o.5
A. Producers AE(W’) A[var np( l)] AE( VP) B. Consumers AE(CS) C. Speculators AE(Il”) A[var II’( l)] AE( V’) D.
- 5.8725 - 75.3054 -2.1073
0.3735
8.3171 - 8.6778 - 75.3054 -4.9126
-0.4260 - 3.1655 -0.2377
Government
F. Total we(fare AE(IIT) AE( V’)
- 2.043 - 27.4769 -0.6691
- 11.5065 - 175.5806 - 2.7275
B. Consumers AE(CS)
3.5804
30.3564
C. Speculators AE(lP) A[var II’(l)] AE( V’)
- 3.1007 - 27.4769 - 1.7268
-20.2136 - 175.5806 - 11.4346
- 1.5633 1.1845
- 1.3637 16.1943
1.9555
5.1514
0.3922 3.1400
3.7877 21.3457
D.
Total private welfare
A W’) AE(V) E.
-0.3031 - 3.7655 -0.1148
A. Producers AE(IP’) A[var IIp( l)] AE( VP)
Total private we!fare AEW) AE( V’)
-0.3556 0.0210
- 6.2332 1.2972
0.4104
7.8656
E.
1.6324 9.1628
F. Total welfare AE(L”‘) AE( VT)
0.0548 0.4314
Government
B. Supply disturbances v=lO
v=o.5 A. Producers AE(L”) A[var np( l)] AE( VP)
0.0502 -0.2088 0.0606
B. Consumers AE( CS)
-0.0588
C. Speculators AE( l7’) A[var I7’( l)] AE( V’) D.
0.6379 - 1.7260 0.7242
8.6114 - 34.09 11 10.3159
3.4678
B. Consumers AE(CS)
- 0.6509
13.2856
- 1.5437 - 13.4447 -0.8714
C. Speculators AE(IY) A[varnS(l)] AE( V’)
-0.1463 - 1.4784 - 0.0724
-3.8160 - 33.3667 - 2.1477
-0.1593 0.0009
18.081 21.4538
0.1383
1.1788
-0.021 0.1392
19.2598 22.6326
1.9314 - 13.6422 2.6135
D. - 0.0267 -0.0073
3.8555 5.2099
Total private welfare AEW) AE(V)
0.0249
1.5856
E.
-0.0018 0.0176
5.4411 6.7955
F. Total welfare AE(Il*) AE( V’)
Total private welfare
AE(n) AE(V) E.
-0.0181 -0.1814 -0.0091
A. Producers AE(IIP) A[var np( l)] AE( VP)
Government
F. Total welfare AE(lI=) AE( VT)
Government
202
R.B. Campbell
and S.J. Turnovsky, lntervention in spot and futures markets
parameter sets 1 and 3, the effects are negligible. For the other two sets, the effects can be summarized as follows. (i) The expected profit of producers declines with intervention, if disturbances originate with demand; it increases in the case of supply disturbances. Intervention in accordance with rule 2 stabilizes profit in the case of demand disturbances, but destabilizes it for supply disturbances. Welfare of firms, as measured by E(V’), declines in the case of demand disturbances, but increases in the case of supply disturbances. (ii) Consumers gain from intervention with demand disturbances; they may either gain or lose in the case of supply disturbances. (iii) The expected profit of speculators declines with intervention, although they are stabilized as well. However, overall, the welfare of speculators declines. (iv) Private welfare, as measured by E(II) declines with intervention in the case of demand disturbances; in the case of supply disturbances it may either rise or fall. By contrast, private welfare, as measured by E(V) increases with intervention in the case of demand disturbances; for supply disturbances it may go either way. (v) The government gains from intervention. (vi) The overall gains from intervention are with one exception always positive. The exception is in the case of supply disturbances, where the measure E(ITT) is employed. In parameter set 1, the losses to consumers and speculators may dominate the gains to other agents.
8. Rule 3: H,_l=
-p(P;‘_,-Pf)
Representative solutions for intervention via rule 3 are set out in tables 8 and 9. Only for parameter sets 1, 3, 4, and 10 did this rule have uniformly substantial effects on the asymptotic distributions of prices. For parameter sets 5 and 6 significant effects could be generated for high degrees of intervention. For all other parameter sets the effects are negligible. Note that as p+co, g2-+0. However, since for parameter sets 2, 7, 8, and 9, the benchmark (no intervention) values of cj are so small, there is little opportunity for the present rule to stabilize the futures prices in these cases.
8.1. Effects on long-run distributions of prices Being symmetric with rule 1, one would expect that intervention with rule 3 to stabilize both the spot and futures prices (when effective). However, as can be seen from the solutions given in table 8, even though such a rule always stabilizes the futures price (albeit by a negligible amount) it can destabilize the spot price; e.g. parameter set 3 for p= 10. The reason for this is that one effect of this form of intervention is to reduce the slope of the
jl=lO
“/, Diff
Y$Difl
# Diff
3
15.630 -1 0.627 -17 20.9146 - 0.48 15.8171 0.13
16.640 +6 0.112 -85 20.3371 - 3.23 15.9326 0.86
3.2351 -1.4 0.7208 -6 17.4408 -0.14 16.5118 0.03
2.971
0.372 -51 17.2348 - 1.32 16.5530 0.29
-9
4
0.127 -8 10.0177 -0.004 9.9823 0.004
-1
0.927
0.937 -0.1 0.137 -0.4 10.0180 0 9.9820 0.001
A. Demand disturbances
1
Parameter sets
Table 8
3.210 -0.5 0.696 -2 16.682 -0.001 16.663 0
3.225 -0.02 0.7105 -0.1 16.6825 0 16.6635 0
10
p=lO
p=o.5
0.014
% Diff 2 ZDiff
-51.75 16.4052 -0.595 16.7190 0.117
% Diff
0.3952
FDiff $f Diff
O?
$Difi
- 10.72 2.9801
- 3.2870 1.53 0.7712 - 5.84 16.4917 -0.071 16.7017
$Diff
3
4
0.568
- 83.52 18.1030 -2.5 16.3794
0.1339
16.4552 3.92
0.080
- 15.6797 0.978 0.6864 - 15.52 18.5008 -0.357 16.2998
0
-7.9 9.9778 10.0222 0
0.1283
-1.17 0.9283
0
- 0.064 0.9387 0.1387 -0.431 9.9778 10.0222 0
B. Supply disturbances
%DiR
*
1
Parameter sets
Effects on distributions of prices: rule 3.
3.3341 0 3.3330 0
0.0141
_-1.4
0.3257
_ 0.06 1
6
3.2112 - 0.474 0.6969 -2.16 16.6625 0 16.6675 0
3.2257 - 0.025 0.7115 -0.112 16.6625 0 16.6675 0
10
Government
F. Total welfare AE(IIT) AE( V’)
E.
AWV)
Total private welfare AE(lI)
0.0302 0.1368
0.1645 0.5069
- 0.0467
0.0054
-0.4251 - 3.3740 -0.2564
0.2162 0.5536
-0.1216 ~ 1.0673 -0.0683
C. Speculators AE(n”) A[var nyi)] AE( V”)
0.8500
-0.2087 -3.3740 - 0.0400
3
0.0248 0.1314
0.2246
B. Consumers AE( CS)
D.
- 0.0782 - 1.0673 - 0.0249
A. Producers AE(llP) A[var Ilp( l)] AE( VP)
pzo.5
1
Parameter sets
-0.0012 0.0001
0.0003
-0.0015 ~ 0.0002
~ 0.00003 -0.0023 0.00009
0.0005
- 0.0020 -0.2310 -0.0008
4 p=lO
0.0002 O.OQO5
0.0001
0.0001 0.0004
0.0001 -0.0047 0.0001
0.0006
0.2884 3.3278 0.1220
C. Speculators AE(L”) A[var J7’( l)] AE( V”)
Government F. Total weware AE(flT) AE( V’)
E.
AE(n) AE(V)
0.1761 -0.1567
- 2.8936
3.0697 2.7369
2.1667
B. Consumers AE(CS)
D. Total private welfare
0.6146 3.3278 0.4482
1
5.8053
0.9913 0.7452 0.9540
0.7861 0.7115
-5.7417
6.5278 6.4532
0.7452 -0.3061
-0.2688
3
Parameter sets
A. Producers AE(IIP) A[var np( l)] AE( V”)
A. Demand disturbances -0.0006 ~ 0.4699 -0.OQO3
10
Table 9 Welfare effects: rule 3.
0.0799 0.0473
0.0115 0.0592 0.0085
0.0099
0.0585 5.9216 0.0289
0.0002 ~ 0.0324
~ 0.0797
4
10
0.0002 ~ 0.0005
-0.0018
0.002 0.0013
0.0010 0.0746 0.0007
0.0004
- 0.0046 -0.0700
-0.1470
0.1424 0.0770
0.0165 1.1883 0.0106
0.0109
O.OGQ6 0.1149 118.8300 0.0746 0.0002 0.0555
6
0.03200
- 0.00475 0.01841
E. Government
F. Total welfare AE(n“) AE( V’)
Total private welfare AJW) AE(V)
-0.03675 -0.01359
0.00120 -0.13518 0.00796
C. Speculators AE(II”) A[var P(l)] AE[V’)
D.
0.0951
-0.13305 -0.32815 -0.11665
B. Consumers AE( CS)
A. Producers AE(IP) A[var IP( l)] AE( VP)
p=os
0.5983 0.8258
0.0030
0.5953 0.8228
-0.1888 -1.8642 -0.0956
0.5324
0.2517 -2.6851 0.38596
0.0001 -0.0147 o.wO17
0.00004
O.OQOO6 0.00088
0.00086 0.00033 0.00113
0.00062
-0.0008 - 0.00029 o.OQOO2 0.00051
0.00014 -0.00153 0.00021
- 0.00024
- 0.0007 -0.1550 0.00005
/1=10
-2.7401 -0.8086 - 2.0808
Government
F. Total we&fare AE(IIT) AE( V’)
E.
AE(n) AWV)
1.9315 0.6593
1.5683 13.60997 0.8878
D. Total private welfare
0.8025
C. Speculators AE(lZ’) A[var IP( l)] AE( V’)
- 0.4394 11.8337 -1.0310
B. Consumers AE(CS)
B. Supply disturbances A. Producers - 0.00043 AE(W) - 1.4694 A[var W’(l)] 0.00030 AE( V”)
2.1951 1.4890
5.86574
8.0608 7.3547
1.1817 9.8989 0.6868
3.8211
3.0580 4.2244 2.8468
-0.0166 -0.0433
- 0.0699
0.0533 0.0266
0.0105 0.0488 0.0080
- 0.0028
0.0456 4.839 0.0214
- 0.0008 -0.0011
-0.00140
0.0006 0.0003 1
0.00057 0.03005 0.00042
- 0.00044
0.00047 0.02921 0.00033
-0.0181 PO.0768
-0.13716
0.1191 0.0604
0.01537 1.06698 0.01003
- 0.00068
0.10437 106.634 0.05106
206
R.B. Campbell
and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention
in spot and futures markets
supply curve and inventory demand function and both of these are destabilizing influences. In the case of parameter set 3, when p= 10, these effects dominate all the other stabilizing influences of the intervention. It is interesting to note that this case of destabilization of the spot price is associated with inelastic consumer demand and very high degrees of risk aversion for both producers and speculators. In practice, since the empirical evidence suggests that farmers are not as risk averse as the coefficients chosen for this parameter sets, the destabilization of the spot price may in fact not be such a problem. Despite the fact that high degrees of intervention in the futures market can destabilize the spot price, futures market intervention via rule 3 always reduces the mean spot price. As for the other two rules, the mean futures price is increased after intervention. In general, changes in both mean prices are less than the corresponding changes achieved under rule 1 and in some cases even less than for rule 2; see for example parameter sets 1 and 3. Similarly, reductions in both variances are relatively small. We noted that for rule 1 a considerable degree of spot and futures market stabilization could be achieved for relatively low degrees of intervention. In contrast, intervention in the futures market can achieve substantial stabilization in the futures market, but relatively little stabilization of the spot price. In fact, as futures market stabilization increases, spot price stabilization declines, until in particular cases, we get a reversal as noted above and the spot price becomes destabilized. Furthermore, significant reductions in the variability of the futures price can be achieved only for high degrees of intervention. 8.2. Welfare effects The allocation of the welfare effects resulting from intervention in accordance with rule 3 can be summarized as follows. (i) If disturbances originate with demand, the expected profit of producers always decreases with a low degree of intervention and increases with a high degree of intervention. The response in the case of supply disturbances is slightly less clear cut, although this same pattern generally applies in that case as well. A low degree of intervention always stabilizes producer profits, a high degree destabilizes them. The welfare of producers, as measured by E(V/), follows that of expected profit. (ii) Consumers always gain from intervention with demand disturbances; they may either gain or lose in the case of supply disturbances. (iii) The effect of intervention on the expected profit of speculators is somewhat mixed. In the case of demand disturbances it usually declines if the degree of intervention is low and to increase if the degree of intervention is high. In the case of supply disturbances, expected profit is increased, especially if the degree of intervention is high. For either demand or supply
R.B. Campbell and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention in spot and futures markets
207
disturbances a low degree of intervention stabilizes speculator profit, while a high degree of intervention destabilizes them. The welfare of speculators, as measured by E(V), generally, but not always, follows that of E(II”). (iv) Private welfare, as measured by E(n), is increased when the degree of intervention is high (p= 10). In the case of low degree of intervention, its effects are much less sure and private welfare losses may be incurred. The same comments apply when private welfare is measured by E(V). (v) The government tends to gain when the degree of intervention is low and to lose when it is high. (vi) The total welfare gains from intervention are generally positive or low degrees of intervention, but negative for high degrees of intervention. These general results merit some additional comments. First, the gains to consumers and producers under rule 3 are always less than the gains achieved under rule 1, with the corresponding losses being greater. Similarly, total private and overall total welfare gains are always less for rule 3 than rule 1, and indeed, as noted above, it is possible to get negative gains under the former. Second, for rules 1 and 2 it was found that speculators always lose from intervention. A major difference for rule 3 is that speculators can in fact gain. Indeed, as the degree of intervention increases, so does the chance that speculators’ welfare will be positive; it will always be so for p= 100. Where speculators lose under rule 3, the losses are in fact less than the corresponding losses achieved under rule 1. Therefore speculators will always be better off under rule 3 than under rule 1. However, the same general conclusion cannot be drawn for comparisons with rule 2, as the latter was so ineffective in producing nonzero gains that it is possible for rule 3 to yield very small losses for speculators, compared with the zero losses/gains under rule 2. A major divergence from the first two rules is that under rule 3, the stabilization authority may in fact lose. We can see from the expression for the gains to the stabilization authority that whether or not gains or losses are achieved depends essentially upon the relative sizes of x1 and x2, defined in (31). In the expression for these gains, (3bc), r(xl - 1) will always be negative. If x2 is close to unity, then the chances for gains will be increased. However, for large values of ,u, x2 will tend to decline thus enhancing the possibility of losses. In fact, from the simulation results we can conclude that the stabilization authority tends to lose for ,u= 10 and always does so for p= 100. Finally, we may note that whereas for rules 1 and 2 total welfare was greater than private welfare, this is not so for rule 3. On the contrary, as the degree of intervention increases under rule 3, society as a whole tends to lose, this being always the case for ,u= 100. This of course is due to the losses being incurred by the stabilization authority in that case, which more than offset the possible private gains.
208
R.B. Campbell and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention in spot and futures markets
9. Final comments In this paper we have analyzed the effects of three alternative intervention rules on the long-run distributions of both the spot and futures prices, together with the welfare implications which stem from these effects. The results for each rule have been summarized at the appropriate part of the text, with some comparisons being made. Space limitations preclude further detailed discussion here, and we conclude with some general observations. As a general proposition we find that intervention in the futures market is not as effective in stabilizing either the spot price or the futures price as is intervention in the spot market. Indeed, the plausible rule of buying futures contracts when their price is low and selling when they are high, while stabilizing the future price may actually destabilize the spot price. Furthermore, the analogous type of rule undertaken in the spot market will always stabilize the futures price to a greater degree than it does the spot price. The basic reason for these findings is due to the impact that intervention has on the behavioral relationships of the private sector. It underscores the need to develop the analysis in terms of a utility maximizing framework. The various rules we have considered can generate rather different distributions of welfare gains, including the overall benefits. The first rule, of intervening in the spot market has the greatest effect. The allocation of benefits depends in part upon the sources of the disturbances. With demand shocks, consumers and government gain at the expense of speculators and producers. With supply disturbances producers and the government gain at the expense of speculators and consumers. Much the same emerges (although to a smaller degree) with rule 2. In both these cases the gains to society from intervention will generally (but not always) be positive. In the case of rule 3, however, the benefits depend crucially upon the degree of intervention. However, a high degree of intervention, which may be needed in order to generate significant stabilizing effects on the spot price, may in fact generate overall welfare losses. In particular, it is likely to lead to losses by the stabilization authority and will therefore not be favored by them. As a practical matter, therefore, intervention via the spot market is the most desirable form of intervention. As a final point, we may note that our analysis treats the numbers of producers and speculators as being fixed exogenously. An important possibility is that the introduction of price stabilization through intervention will influence the number of participants in the market. An interesting extension of this analysis, therefore, would be to allow the numbers of agents to be endogenously determined through free entry or exit from the market.
R.B. Campbell and S.J. Turnovsky, Intervention in spot and futures markets
209
References Bray, M., 1981, Futures trading, rational expectations and the efficient markets hypothesis, Econometrica 49, 575-596. Brent, R.P., 1973, Some efficient algorithms for solving systems of non-linear equations, SIAM Journal of Numerical Analysis 10, 327-344. Buccola, S.T., 1981, The supply and demand of marketing contracts under risk, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63, 5033509. Danthine, J., 1978, Information, futures prices, and stabilizing speculations, Journal of Economic Theory 17, 79998. Feder, G., R.E. Just and A. Schmitz, 1980, Futures markets and the theory of the firm under price uncertainty, Quarterly Journal of Economics 65, 273-276. Freund, R.J., 1956, The introduction of risk into a programming model, Econometrica 24, 253264. Houthakker, H.S., 1967, Economic policy for the farm sector (American Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC). Kawai, M., 1983, Price volatility of storable commodities under rational expectations in spot and futures markets, International Economic Review 24, 43-5459. King, R.P. and L.J. Robison, 1981, An interval approach to measuring decision maker preferences, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63, 510-520. Kramer, R.A. and R.D. Pope, 1981, Participation in farm commodity programs: A stochastic dominance analysis, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63, 119-120. McCafferty, S. and R. Driskill, 1980, Problems of existence and uniqueness in non-linear rational expectations model, Econometrica 48, 1313-1317. Newbery, D.M.G. and J.E. Stiglitz, 1979, The theory of commodity price stabilization rules: Welfare impacts and supply responses, Economic Journal 89, 799-817. Newbery, D.M.G. and J.E. Stiglitz, 1981, The theory of commodity price stabilization, (Oxford University Press, Oxford). Peck, A.E., 1976, Futures market, Supply response and price stability, Quarterly Journal of Economics 90,407423. Rolfo, J., 1980, Optimal hedging under price and quantity uncertainty: The case of a cocoa producer, Journal of Political Economy 88, 100-l 16. Stein, J.L., 1961, The simultaneous determination of spot and futures prices, American Economic Review 51, 1012-1025. Turnovsky, S.J., 1978a, The distinction of welfare gains from price stabilization: A survey of some theoretical issues, in F.G. Adams and S.A. Klein, eds., Stabilizing world commodity markets (Heath-Lexington, Lexington, Mass.). Turnovsky, S.J., 1978b, Stabilization rules and the benefits from price stabilization, Journal of Public Economics 9, 37-57. Turnovsky, S.J., 1979, Futures markets, Private storage, and price stabilization, Journal of Public Economics 12, 301-327. Turnovsky, S.J., 1983, The determination of spot and futures prices with storage commodities, Econometrica 51, 1363-1387. Turnovsky, S.J. and R.B. Campbell, 1985, The stabilizing and welfare properties of futures markets: A simulation approach, International Economic Review 26, 277-303. Working, H., 1958, A theory of anticipatory prices, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 48, 188-199. Yassour, J., D. Zilberman and G.C. Rausser, 1981, Optimal choices among alternative technologies with stochastic yield, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63, 718-723.