Carnegie- Rochester
Conference
Series on Public Policy 29 (1988)
125 136
North- Holland
HE GOLD STA
ICHAEL D. BORDO Carnegie Mellon University and University of South Carolina
Marvin Goodfriend paper
which
will
be
literature. The paper
has written an
a carefully crafted, well-thought-out
important
focuses on
contribution
central
to
the
gold
standard
banking policy under the gold
standard. Its concern is with a fairly limited set of issues from the vast gold standard literature. Specifically, the paper examines short-run policy by and
a central bank to maintain gold convertibility and to stabilize prices interest rates. The
gold
standard
of relevance
is a domestic
gold
standard, since very little reference is made in the paper to internatioblal issues. The focus on short-run policy also avoids any discussion of the issue of the relative performance of the gold standard compared to other monetary standards, or with issue of the long-run viability of the gold standard. The key conclusion of the paper is that to affect the price level and
interest rates, monetary
policy
under
a gold
standard must
involve
activist gold policy which influences the nonmonetary gold stock. The framework of the paper
is a rational expectations
asset-pricing
model. Section II of the paper sets up the model with four assets: money (fiat money); gold
(held as a durable
asset but
not as money);
bonds:
physical capital. The model solves for the equilibrium price/rate of return for each asset and identifies the sources of stochastic disturbances th.3 can
affect
them.
The
key findings
in this
section
are:
(1) the
real
interest rate is independent of shocks to both the money and gold markets; (2) the price level is independent of shocks to the gold market; (3) the real price of gold is independent of monetary shocks. Section III extends the theoretical The gold standard is defined
as a
framework to the gold
standard-
fixed price of gold in terms of money.
The standard can be maintained by folio ing either pure gold policy -- t exchange of gold for bonds -- or pure monetary
olic
To maintain the standard using either type of policy, all
0 167 - 2231/88/$3.50
0 1988 Elsevier Science Publishers
B.V. (North-Holland)
that is required is that the difference between the growth rate of money and the growth rate of the nonmonetary gold
stock equal the difference
between the transactions service shocks growth rate (shocks to the growth rate in the demand for money) and the gold preference shocks growth rate (shocks to the growth rate of the demand for nonmonetary gold). To maintain this equality (equation 33b) the government itself does not actively
have
to be included in the arbitrage process. It can be done by the private market (i.e., by
corrrnercialbanks) as long as the appropriate amounts of
and nonmonetary gold are provided by the government.
money
In addition and
most important, it is argued that maintenance of convertibility does not require that the government hold gold reserves. This pure gold standard is then contrasted with the more traditional classical gold standard -- for example, the Barro (1979) model but
omitting
accounting for gold production. The key difference between the classical case and the pure gold standard, in this view, is the introduction of a gold reserve ratio, only because the Bank of England had one and it became popular in
the
literature. Goodfriend
then
demonstrates
that
a central
bank, committed to freely exchanging, on demand, money for gold and vice versa, while maintaining a fixed gold reserve ratio, uses up the degrees of freedom of both monetary and gold policy. To follow an activist monetary or gold policy and alter the price level or nominal interest rate, it must allow the gold
reserve ratio
to vary. The
paper
presents
an
excellent
discussion (Section 3.3.1) of the use of interest-rate policy to manage the gold reserve ratio and price
level in the
face of gold preference
and
transaction service shocks, and of the use of interest-rate and price-level smoothing by a centraT bank under the classical gold standard. The final part of the paper applies the analysis to the history of the gold standard. A distinction
is made between varieties of gold standard:
(1) a pure and private gold standard is compared to (2) a gold standard ith
fractional
reserves
and
(3)
a
government-operated
gold
standard.
Fractional reserves are held in gold not because it is necessary to meet redemption demand but to satisfy minimum transaction costs of exchanging earning
assets for gold upon redemption demand (government involvement in a
gold standard account and
reflects
its
monopolizing
role
the
in defining
issue of
the
currency).
value of
the
Goodfriend
unit of
views
the
latter as crucial to control of the interest rate, the gold reserve ratio, and the price level, Goodfriend reinterprets the Bank rate controversy. He comes out on the side of the traditional vie
of England altered Bank rate as
126
the key to management of the international gold standard. revisionist view of
ccloskey and
Zecher
He rejects the
(1976), based on the monetary
approach to the balance of payments, that perfect arbitrage in goods and asset markets made
central banks
inconsequential.
To have an effect
on
world interest rates and prices, according to Goodfriend, the central bank had to have a national monopoly of the currency. Using his framework, Goodfriend reinterprets the role of a lender of last resort, viewing Bagehot's rule (1873) (of lending freely at above the market
rate of
interest
interest) as providing
rate,
alternatively
as
an
an elastic currency
at a ceiling
irregular
interest-rate
form
of
smoothing. Finally he criticizes worldwide
elimination
the
by Barsky et
in
concert with the Bank of England to smooth interest rates. According
to
the
interest
rates
Federal Reserve,
in
the
acted
of
in
(1987) that
is
establishment
seasonal
al.
1914
explained by the
of
the story
which
Goodfriend, because the Fed was not a profit-maximizing central bank as was the Bank of England
(and other major
central banks),
it was willing
to
follow an interest-rate smoothing policy at the cost of a fluctuating and suboptimal gold reserve ratio. As noted, a central bank with a monopoly over the currency could then influence world interest rates.
In what follows I first raise several points related to analytical issues covered in Sections II and III of GoJdfriend's paper and then focus my attention on the application of the analysis to the history of the gold standard.
A
I
(1)
ANALYTICAL
ISSUES
Disregarding the effect of shocks from the goods market on the gold market
and,
more
important omissions. commodity and
a
leaving
fundamentally,
Under the gold
significant
gold market
impinged directly
on
gold
production
standard gold was an
fraction
countries -- especially at certain
out
of
production
times. Thus real
economic
important
in a number
disturbances activity.
are
of
to the
Also
the
diversion of capital from nongold-producing sectors affected the real interest rate. These shocks are co the long run and are recognized
nly believed to be important in
as a key source of long-run price
level instability, but at specific times in history such as the late 184Qs, 185Os, and late 1890s they run.
(2)
The argument
can be
t 127
intained
ithout go1
reserves (earlier made by Black
(1981) and Fischer (1986)) contravenes
the essence
of a gold standard. Fundamental to a gold standard are
maintenance
of a fixed price of gold
and redemption
on
demand of
If the public wishes to redeem paper money in
claims in terms of gold.
gold, in Goodfriend's scenario, the central bank has to sell a bond and then buy gold to meet the demand. Presumably this takes time and involves
transaction
If the
costs.
central
bank
cannot
instantly
redeem its liabilities in gold, then it violates the fundamental of the standard. The failure to redeem its liabilities in gold, it occurred
under well-understood
contingencies
rule
unless
such as a war or
a
financial crisis, would lead the government to lose credibility with respect to its commitment to follow the gold-standard rule. A promise to redeem
in the future at a discount sufficient to keep the money
price of gold unchanged (the suggestion in footnote 6) assumes that the extra cost of paying the discount is less than the investment in credibility capital by maintaining an earnest in the form of a gold reserve. The historical record teaches the opposite. The case for
a
private bank to hold reserves that Goodfriend makes applies also to a central bank. Thus it is questionable that the fixed dollar price of gold can be supported by either monetary or gold-stockpiling policy (Section With
IIi.1). a
gold
reserve
ratio
demonstrates (Section IILZ), gold demand
will
involve
in
place,
as
Goodfriend
admirably
shocks to money demand or to nonmonetary
both money
and
gold.
The
shocks
can
be
temporarily accommodated by pure monetary policy if the gold reserve ratio
adjusts.
Ultimately,
however,
as
the
history
of
the
gold
standard has taught us, the reduction of the gold reserve ratio, in response
to
financial
adoption
of
the
innovation
standard
by
to the point where (Triffin, 1960).
continued
(transaction
new nations the
service
shocks)
(gold preference
standard
was
no
longer
and
shocks) viable
Because of the very short-run time frame of the analysis, which treats the gold
closed
stock
as
fixed,
and open economies.
the model
no
explicit
distinction
is made
between
Unless an implicit assumption underlying
is of a very large economy, many real world issues of the
gold standard
in an open economy cannot be addressed. These include
the use of discount rate policy, 'gold policy," and other policies to affect the level of gold reserves.
128
B.
HISTORICAL
ISSUES
There are a number of instances where, in my opinion, the application of the model to the history of the gold standard does not quite jibe with the
generally
understood view
of
the
period.
In what
follows
I focus
primarily on the classical go?5 standard. The issues to be discussed are the author's treatment of: (1) private versus government gold sLandards; (2) the Bank rate con:roversy; (3) the lender of last resort; (4) pricelevel and interest-rate smoothing. 1.
Private Versus Government Gold Standards. --
The distinction Goodfriend
makes between private and government gold standards is hard to relate to the experiences of England and the United States where government involvement has always been paramount. Thus from the beginnings of the standard
in eighteenth-century
England,
the government
defined
the
standard. The gold standard first appeared de facto in England in 1717 as a consequence of overvaluing of silver at the mint by Sir Isaac Newton. In the United States the bimetallic standard dated from 1792 when Congress defined the weight of silver in a dollar and the weight of gold in a gold eagle. Before the eighteenth century the monetary system based on metallic coins was not officially a standard. Coins circulated by weight, governments arbitrarily announced their values, and the free market kept prices in line with the weights, which were often out of line with official values. The invention of milling
in
the late seventeenth century to maintain the quality of the coinage was a key factor making
the establishment of the standard possible
(Redish, 1987). The United States never had a pure and private gold standard- It
was not pure because the country was on a bimetallic standard -- an effective silver
standard until
1834, thereafter
an effective
gold
standard. It was not private since the government defined the value of gold and silver coins and was ready to buy and sell the metals at the fixed price. Finally, the First and Second
Banks were not established
United States to give the government a role
111.
Goodfriend argues
on page
revenue
government
for
the
and
in the gold standard as
Rather they were to
aid
in the
in
set up to raise
unifying
the
COUntrY
(Timberlake, 1978; Fraas, 1974). 2,
The Bank
Rate
Controversy.
An
implication
that
I re
y central bank
argument in Section I
its domestic currency could affect world interest rates using its gold
129
policy. In my opinion, the Bank of England was the only central bank under the classical gold standard capable of such action. London, a net creditor, had special importance under the gold standard because it was
the
location of
capital,
co
odity,
and go'lcumarkets
that
served the world. As a consequence the Bank of England was able to use its Bank rate
to affect world
interest rates despite
a WlativelY
small gold reserve -- the famous "powerful bank rate weapon with a thin film of gold" (Sayers, 1951, p. 116). Other countries with much larger gold
had considerably
reserves
less pulling power
(Lindert,
oreover, though the Bank of England had a monopoly
1969). currency
towards
the
end
of
the
nineteenth
century
as
a
of the private
financial institution, it was relatively weak compared to the rapidly developing clearing banks. It had to supplement Bank rate with other instruments to make it effective (Sayers, 1951). (3)
Goodfriend's interpretation of Bagehot's
The Lender Of Last Resort.
rule as a ceiling interest rate at which the supply of currency is perfectly elastic applies to one special case -- an internal drain accompanied by an external drain. Bagehot made a distinction between the policy
to follow
in each of
the
cases of an
internal and an
external drain. In an internal drain "the best way for the Bank... to deal
with
a
drain
arising
from
internal
discredit
is
to
lend
freely..." (1873, p. 48). In an external drain, "the Bank of England requires the steady use of an effectual
instrument. That instrument is the elevation of the
rate of interest" (1873, p. 46). In the case of both an internal and an external drain, Bagehot's famous rule comes into play "Very large loans at very high rates are the best
remedy
for
the worst
malady
of
the money
market
when
a
foreign drain is added to a domestic drain" (1873, p. 56). The
implication of the paper is that ;n response to a liquidity
crisis per se (i.e., an internal drain), the Bank should Wercst
impose an
ceiling. TO the contrary, the appropriate prescription is not
a high rate but a clear signal to the public and the banks that their demands
for
currency
addition, the
term
and
reserves will
"irregular
be
freely
acco
smoothing'" is misleading.
Lender-of-
last-resort lending action is the opposite of smoothing. crisis need not threaten the ys true. In the United States it 32 but not in 1933, since the panic 130
ultimately
led
to
a
run
on
the
reflected the public's fear of i run on
the
discount
currency
rate
to
is the
stem an
dollar,
hich
in turn
may
have
inent devaluation ( igmore, 1987). A
reason
a central
external
drain.
bank must
Thus
raise
its
the Credit-Anstalt
crisis in Austria in 1931 was converted from a banking panic to a run on the schilling after the Austrian National Bank, acting as a lender of
last resort,
bailed out
the
Credit-Anstalt
without
imposing
a
penalty rate (Schubert, 1987). 4.
Price-Level And Interest-Rate Smoothing.
An implication of the paper,
based on the considerable amount of attention paid to the subject, is that price-level and interest-rate smoothing were important policies in the classical gold standard era. The historical record
suggests
that this may not have been the case. Little evidence exists that gold standard central banks were much concerned with smoothing the price level before I914 (although Dutton (1984) did find a limited effect in his Bank-rate-reaction fur&ion). McGouldrick
(1984),
may
The German Reichsbank, according to
have
followed
smoothing as it altered its portfolio
a
policy
of
interest-rate
in a countercyclical fashion,
but its policy was not the general rule among gold standard central banks. Perhaps we can interpret the evidence by Bloomfield (1959) and others that many central banks violated "the rules of the game" by sterilizing gold flows as evidence
it is true that under the interwar
the case is not clear. However, gold
exchange
followed.
standard,
Moreover,
such
for interest-rate smoothing, but
smoothing
Goodfriend's
policies
view
that
were the
more
widely
objective
of
maintaining an adequate gold reserve ratio was to pursue price-level and
interest-rate
smoothing
is
contemporaries. Their arguments (1)
to
strengthen
the
not
supported
by
the
writings
of
for building up gold reserves were:
lender
of
last
resort;
(2)
to
maintain
convertibility in the face of an external drain (Bagehot, 1873); and (3) to contribute to national security (Cassel, I935).
Analysis of additional issues using Goodfrie OUM
be of considerable interest. I
131
occasionally
left it; (3) the reasons for the high variability of real
output and price levels under the gold standard (Bordo,
(1982)
;
eltzer
and Robinson,
(1988)).
ere not followed?
132
as it
(1981);
Cooper,
because smoothing policies
Street. Reprint of the 1915 xW.k:~
(1873)
Hw York:
Arno Press.
Barro, R.3. (1979)
oney and the Price Llevel Under the Gold ShndarQ. JOLURQZ, 89:
Barsky, R.B., (1987)
13-33.
ankiw, N.H.,
iron,
3.A.
and
The Worldwide Change in the Behavior of Prices in 1914. Conference.
Ecsnontic
Interest &&?s
estern Economics Association
and
Infwmt ional
Vancouver, British Columbia, July.
Black, F. (1981)
Reserves. A Gold Standard with Double Feedback and NeE!& rtB:'!ra assachusetts Institute of Technology.
imeo) Sloan School, Bloomfield, A.3. (1959)
Monetary Policy Under the International
Gold Standard
/880-1914.
New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
(1981)
The Classical Gold Standard: Some Lessons for Today. Federal Ressme t?ankof St. Louis Review.
Cassel , G. (1935)
The Downfall of the Goki Standard.
Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
Cagan,
P, (1965)
Determinants
and Effects
of Chumges in the Stock of
1960. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research,
(lM2)
The
Gold
Standard:
Historical
133
Facts
and
Future
Prospects.
Dutton, J. (1984)
The Bank of
England and the
International Gold
A.J.
Schwartz
Standard:
(eds.), A
Rules of the New
Game
the
.D. Bordo
Evidence.
Retrospectivs
under
OR the
Classical
ar,.i COZCZ
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Standard,l821-1931.
Fischer, S. (1986)
Monetary Rules and Commodity Money Schemes under Uncertainty. 17: 21-35.
Jolusncll of Monetary Economics, Fraas, A,, ;r:19r’4;j
lhe
Second
Bank
of the United
States: An
Instrument
Interregional Monetary Union. Journal of Economic
History,
for
34:
447-62. Friedmans 11.. and Schwartz, A.&. (1963)
A Monetary
History
of the United
States
1867-1960.
Princeton:
Princeton University Press. Lindert, P.H. (1969)
Key
Currencies
md
Gold
Princeton
1900-1913.
Studies
in
International Finance, No. 24. ccloskey, D.N. and Zecher, J.R.
(1976)
How the Gold Standard Worked 1880-1913. Johnson Payments.
(eds.),
The
Monetary
J.A.
Approach
Frenkel and H.G.
to
the
BaZunce
of
Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
cGouldrick, P. (1984)
Operations of the German Central Bank and the Rules of the Game,
1879-1913.
M.D. Bordo
Retrospective OR the CZ&caZ
and
A.J.
Schwartz
Gold Stmtdard,
1822-1931.
(eds.),
A
Chicago:
University of Chicago Press. eltzer, A.H. and Robinson, S. (1988)
Stabilit
Under
the Gold
Standard
oney, History and hternational
a
J.
Schwartz.
Chicago
(forthcoming).
134
in Practice.
Finance:
University
.D. Bordo
ays in Honor of of
Chicago
Press
Redish, A. (1987)
The
Evolution of
University
the Gold
Standard in England,
of British Columbia
1770-iR30.
(Mimeo).
Sayers, R.S.
(1951)
The Development of Central Banking After Bagehot.
History Review,
Economic
2d ser., 4 (no. 1): 109-16.
Schubert, A. (1987)
Tne
Credit-Anstalt
Revisited.
Crisis
of
193i:
A Financial
Crisis
Journal of Economic History, 47: 495497.
Timberlake, R.H., Jr. (1978)
The Origin of Central
Banking
in the
United
States.
Cambridge:
Harvard University Press. Triffin, R.
(1960)
Gold cmdthe Dollar Crisis.
New Haven: Yale University Press.
Wigmore, B. (1987)
Was the Bank Holiday of 1933 A Run on the Dollar Rather than the Banks? Journal of Economic History,
135
47: 739-756,