Community participation in Third World housing Potential and constraints
Reinhard J. Skinner
The term ‘community participation’ is almost unavoidable in discussions of low-income housing. Rarely, however, is the meaning of the expression considered, and, kfortunaiely, even less commonly is it seen in bractice. The author presents an analysis of its usefulness, its various forms, and the problems of implementation. He then- sets out recommendations for ways in which these problems - and the field of community participation itself - might best be handled in future.
I’crceptions
particlpatlon;
Hous-
wh:lt
(‘onfcrcnce elcv:ltcd reality.
ol
Settlements
to the
status
a
hc hoth
to the local
popirl:ition.
residents.
it C:iii
choice
incur
for
whichever to
nloi-c’
lx
l>rccisclv
\vh:lt
these
labour
identification
with
This
project
;I
acccpl;lhlc
and
01‘ their
reduction
ii nroicct. I .I
benefits
in into
means
cheapcf-.
lzor
cn\ irorimcnt,
in the
Ihcn.
co\t\
it seems
lxirticip;ltion.
might
hc,
ttlcq
thcrc
;It-C
‘1‘0 under\t;incl
howc\cr.
‘commiinit~
(digging
neecl\
one
can
pxticipation’
trench An
one’s for
to
IIIC;III.
~omn~~rni~y.
not the individual, pirrts
ot
the
collective
discussions
residents
by the project
to suit
the
house)
pipes),
interpretation
which
of the
them.
Cl’ or
of
rather
This
as
plans
intcndcd
0264.27511841060564-11$03.00
apply.
the
,, 1984 Butterworth
a11
of
activity
participate
for to
of
;I
;I
sccs the on!y
cxampIc.
as
(0
settlcnient’\
in modification
beneficiaries
it is
of individuals
is that which
prcscnted
resulted
worst.
xtivity
number
than
would
which
At
user which
budget.
the
as ;I
goes l’urthcr
of development
wihhcs
an identification
as actor - individuals
whole.
ugcnq
-
inclusion
to secure
in the project
interprets
own
constituent
costs
the mere
as
is expected
to maintain
labour
water
this
works
willingness
:I
conceived
At best.
howcvcr,
(building ;I
is often
communal
reducing
of
conception,
community.
(CP)
project.
;I
certain
translated a
individual
plans
;I
;I
;~ncl
lx)wc~-
and conceptions participation
as
and
In
ot the IX)O~-. ‘1‘0
cseculc
to
communit>
than this :I( wh:it
(‘ommunity
hc
making
of
houxin~~.
Foi- the nation:ll
to eyt:rblishecl
development
options.
from
of residents‘
may
way
it smoother
\vhcn it \v;14
low-inconic’
to the oroblcms
side 011~’ considers gkiinutl
more closely
seen
;I
in 1970.
It
N:rtion\
I,rojcct.
hencfit\
look
bc
lary.
United
different.
threat
al>fxo:lch ..
ii say in ttic
of improvement
the
at the
for very
potential
leaving
iiicaii
IXI~;ICC~I
something
of presenting - ;I popuI;Ir . impknicnting agcncics. it may
p;lrticilxition
accolade
in Vancouver ;I
of
it can mean
it GIII
community
its grcatu4t
inc’;iii\
Models
564
useluIncs4
on tIuni;in
hovx\,cr.
From The author is with the Institute for Housing Studies. Weena 718. PO Box 20718. 3001 JA Rotterdam. The Netherlands.
the
W;I\ probably
:rlmoat
govcrnmcnt
the Keywords: Community ina: LDCs
or
rcccived
(Figure
of the I).
& Co (Publishers)
The
Ltd
Figure 1. Lusaka, Zambia. Chawama upgrading - resident participation led to new road bending to avoid grocery store and bar.
principle underlying this approach is that if people agree to a plan they will not hinder its implementation and may well assist voluntarily in its introduction and maintenance. This pragmatic incentive of successful project completion is the real motivation behind such participation policies, despite the more grandiose references by project agencies and governments to the right of people to determine their own futures. A third conception of CP goes one step further. This places final decision making power in the hands of residents - preferably in the form of elected neighbourhood organizations. Agencies and technicians thus acquire an advisory role: their task is to facilitate the technical formulation of the community’s wishes. Although technical team and residents should work together. the residents, as beneficiaries. are the rightful ‘leaders’ of the project. Of course, it is this model of CP which is least acceptable to agencies and national governments: although it represents CP in its most complete form, it poses a challenge to the professional control of the technical experts of the agency and a potential threat. as organized popular power, to national government.
Degrees of CP In some projects, CP is seen merely as a collection of individual households constructing, or organizing the construction of their houses. This kind of activity hardly merits the term ‘community participation’ at all - it is individualized and limited in impact. This becomes clearer if we consider all projects in terms of the three stages of planning. implementation, and maintenance (although all will overlap to a certain extent). Some schemes are little more than conventional contractor-built operations. although they may be carried out in slum, squatter or sites and services areas. All works are undertaken by construction companies or public enterprises which assume that, on completion, the ‘new’ neighbourhood’s residents will participate to the extent of adding to and improving their dwellings and maintaining some of the new services delivered (such as street cleaning or clearing blocked drainage channels). Since all self-help housing projects include dwelling improvement, the special feature of this type of scheme is that it assumes maintenance will be undertaken by the population ‘served’. The failure of such schemes lies in the inability to realize that residents are unlikely to maintain that which they see as ‘officially’ provided and. therefore. as
CITIES November
1984
565
an officiA
responsibility
almost
other
all
:itxcnce
of commitment
Other
projects
virtually
be
willing
construct
to
The exclusion
guarantees
to project
stage.
maintain
of particip;ition
either
rescntmcnt
in
or the
maintcnnncc.
for participation
allow
it in the maintenance
expecting will
to m:iint:iin.
rcapects
in implemcnt;ltion ;I\ bell ;I\ While it is more likc1y that pcoplc
something
Lvhich
they
have
helped
to
(apart
from their own houses) this approach ma\ hackfire. Implementation. in the last instance. ;I> f2r ;is it at‘fects Iou-incomc populations means effort and time, and mav not alw:i);s he ;I sourc‘c ot pride in achievement since the idea will have originated from somelxd~ elx. It may hc. then. that implementation is wen hy residents purely, ;IS ;I form
of cheap
after
all.
the
labour.
agency’\.
which
they
participate: even it’ ii half-hearted whatever that maintenance tasks
to a pro,jc’ct \vhich i5.
may be resentment effort will
is made.
;~nd :I
there
he fulfilled
I-cfusal
to
i\ no guxmtcc
(Figure
2).
greatcst
degree of CP is seen in projects in which planning (decision making) is added to the implementation and maintcnanw spheres of collective activity. Scttlcment development non acquires ;I The
Figure 2. Kerege, Tanzania. Village improvement - CP demanded without consultation. Villagers abandoned work on ‘collectively built’ house for the village manager.
are donating
result
The
character
clcnied
Lvhat they with
the trained.
to ;lssi\t different
two
approache\:
pcop1c’ M ho dccidc
in the design of the project. togcthcr agency team. ‘‘ire more likely to he willing
professional
and.
to its miiintenunce. project
participate
All
other
;I part
in its implementation
commitment
Levels
it in the
Leant ;tnd play
5tagcs:
it
thereafter.
This
cannot
in one \taye if they
he
have sonic’ psvchologic:ll
4hokvs the assumed
;lrt’ excluded
interdcp’ndcnc\
from
01
rcsidcnta
that another
-will
(Figure
3).
of CP
settlements
such.
individual
needs
;I house
contain
and
individuals group
and group\
needs
and may decide
and
of
potential
to construct
it
individuals
activities. it\clf:
rcf‘usc
:ind.
as
14 t’xnilv disposal
Figure 3. La Paz, Bolivia. La Portada squatter upgrading - unskilled residents permitted by agency to make individual water connection. Such initiatives were freely incorporated into a sympathetic and non-paternalistic programme.
566
CITIES
November
1984
(when not provided by the municipality) can best be handled by groups of families; planning for future service demands can only be undertaken at the level of the whole settlement. Occasionally mobilization of low-income residents is invited into the area of national politics. such as in Peru overtly between 1968 and 1975 and in Chile, more implicitly. between 1970 and 1973 (Appendix 1). The above categories show the different levels of grouping to be considered in CP and the distinctions are vital in planning for participatory projects. This becomes even more pronounced when different levels of CP need to take place simulta~wousl~ in some project spheres (eg house improvement. refuse disposal and schoolbuilding). and cotzsecuril-,ely in others (eg payment for plot registration, constructing a playcground for a block, and maintaining standpipes). In all cases. however, a formal community organization of one kind or another is necessary if settlement development is to be coordinated between varying levels of resident grouping over different periods of time. The agency itself is unable to assume such a role unless it is attached solely to the settlement concerned for an indefinite period (and then. of course. it is a community organization itself. however unrepresentative). The above analysis of conceptions. degrees and levels of CP leads to the conclusion that maximum community participation in each is the most rational as far as CP projects are concerned. Yet few programmes in the world adopt this approach. Among those which have come closest are Peru (1968-75). Zambia. Papua New Guinea. and Nicaragua (Appendix 2). Those which clearly have not are particularly worthy of note because of their much-publicised activities or large-scale investments: the Philippines, Sri Lanka. Tanzania, Malawi. and Indonesia (Appendix 3). The obvious question is. assuming CP has its merits. to what extent are different programmes capitalizing on it? When they are not, then why are they not?
Constraints
‘For
this
see
R. Skinner,
‘Community
Participation: its scope and organisation’,
in R. Skinner and M. Rodell, eds, People, Poverty and Shelter. Problems of SelfHelp Housing in the Third World, Methuen, London, 1983.
CITIES November
1984
on community
participation
It is impossible here to go through all the constraints on CP.’ but some of the major ones can be listed. First, many projects which aim to include a participatory element employ much the same staff as they did for non-participatory projects (eg completed new housing estates) and thus ignore the need for new skills, particularly the organizational. social skills. and those relating to communication and discussion with the ‘target’ population. Second, the nature of CP is that it is to some extent unpredictable: at times it will be slow to materialize or fail altogether: at other times a new and unexpected area of potential CP may arise. Any project which is bound by strict time schedules for completion of various components will fail to adapt itself to these realities. Third. standards can impede CP in two ways in particular. If standards of construction or infrastructure (especially social) are too high. they will exclude the possibility of relatively unskilled local labour being employed. At the dwelling level. if standards normally in force are not reduced vis-2-vis materials and type of construction. there is the danger that the poor will be unable to meet the requirements of a ‘permanent’ dwelling within a short enough period and thus \I,ill be excluded from the project (Kenya is an example of official demands for speedy attainment of ‘acceptable’ dwelling standards). Materials stan-
567
da&
pose another
problem
- production
standards
art3 too high for
materials.
then
the oligopc>lisGc
;I iicencc to print
granted
either
sIn;~ll
Fourth. planned decide
project
design
and provided for
thtmsclvcs
Pro.ject type also defines acccptecl
to so &xi&.
amenable to CP than sites possess socinl relationships time
and
and services
cooperation.
are assumed
to lack thcsc qualities
who
do
not
~istiri~ti(~ii. schcmcs
On
i\ to
or
felt
a4 argiccl
for
have heen
(‘I’.
It is
are more the
titrmcr
tcstcct over
and confidence in mutual aid area\.
on the other
hand.
they arc ~on~l3os~d of ptxq3lc
because
other.
each
the +,vholo one
cxn
accept
this
he pointed
it should
out that some sitcs and wrciccs anti-(‘P: those, for example. which arc
so inherently
are not
‘overspill’ transfer
know hut
that
resident\;
priorities
difficulty
which
wrvices
and
to
prt~,~ect~. hcc;It~sc
Icad to a certain degree of trusl
or collective
more
is for
of loug standing
nctworkx
Sites
The
maintenance.
md
setticmcnts
arid
who-will
poor
thcv can hc espectcii to l3c
an area of potential
squatter
that
the
mav he
the ~1st‘ of public spaces or the
a
more amenable to CP in implcmcntation ubovc. widely
to Cl’.
inst~~ll~~ti~~n xcctrcling
the opporfunity
neects. Given
of the
the Icss scope thcrc
on 5uch issue5
sequence of iIi~r~lstrLl~tilr~
supply
sector
driven cwt of the project (the Prty-amme suffers f~-mt this
can be ;I hinchxncc
in alvance,
to
formal
money at the expense
ilnp~~~~rishe~{ or Improvcmcnt Kampung
Where these
and price.
producers
or monopolistic
he further
Indonesi:tn problem).
source
‘informal
sites for squatter upgrading schcmcs can. to II certain extent. old relationships
to the new a~-C;I. and collective
13lots (by ernPloym~nt-b;tsctd ovcrwnw
cooperatives.
for
the ~3r~)l3l~i~i of’ lack of knowlccige
Undoubtedly.
that of political
howcvcr, control.
the
Where
greatest
hctwecn
problem
;~~~t~nomoii~
iIppliC~lti0ll
csxnplc)
[or
can sin,ilarl!; rcsidunt\.
with
respect
collective
to (‘P
~~r~anization
is is
h!; the govcrnmcnt to constitulc ii thi-eat lo national 4tahility. the cstahlished frumework of decision making (eg ‘the Part\;‘) will he maintained and local lxwer5 cont‘inetl to the ;Ircas ot’ rclativtlv pcrwivccl
in~li~i~lL1~ili~~~l. huilciin~
of
small
hoiiws
ipup. or
here arc the Philippines bc severely
568
curtailed
or
o~~i~i~ill~
maintcnmcc ;~nd ‘I‘unisia.
of
~~)iltf-~~ll~~l activities.
p-ccii
/\a ;Irgucd
;II-as.
‘I‘vpical
carlier.‘(‘I’
wch
8s
csaniplcs is certain
to
by such apprcxlchc\.
CITIES
November
1984
It should not be assumed that even wifhirl countries the different actors in the low-income housing field share similar views of CP. It may be that ‘participation’ is part of official ideology but implementing agencies see it as impeding technical efficiency. Sometimes this is quite understandable: it is relatively easy for the President to make a public statement or issue a decree promoting largc-scalc CP; it is quite another matter for a ministry or project agency to reorganize its methods of operation to comply with it. This brings us to the question of how far one should try to go with CP. Since CP does not automatically guarantee success, it is unwise to advocate switching immediately from non-participatory programmcs to those in which CP is prominent. Lack of experience in such programmes brings a host of problems. Are there sufficient suitable personnel for new types of projects? Are existing organizational structures suited to two-way communication and working together with poor populations‘? Are the populations themselves - used as they are to a ‘top-down’ autocratic approach - prepared to accept the idea of CP as presented to them‘? The more such questions are problematic, the greater the chance of failure. And while initial failure is not a reason to abandon CP, it does provide ammunition for groups within national decision making structures which are opposed to CP. It is probably safer, therefore, to introduce the approach gradually, paying great attention to it in its early stages and thereby aiming at an initial success which can prepare the ground for more ambitious ventures. It is often said that if CP is to be successful it must include dialogue between the official agency and the target population. What is not so clearly stated, though it should be obvious, is that dialogue between the constituent parts of the agency itself, and any other authorities likely to be drawn into the programme, is also necessary. In Lusaka’s squatter upgrading programme, the Housing Project Unit held regular ‘briefings’ of its own staff both as a means of problem-solving and coordination of aims and efforts. At the interagency level it may sometimes be the case that policy is decided in consultation with one agency to the exclusion of another. Where this occurs planning is not only likely to be inefficient (the excluded agency will have some spheres of expertise which could be contributed at this stage) but may also lead to resentment which produces non-cooperation, or unrealistic demands being placed on the excluded agency which could have been avoided if it had been brought into the initial discussions. This kind of problem may account for the poor cooperation sometimes experienced between the municipal (servicing) authority (the BMA) and the National Housing Authority in Thailand’s upgrading programme, where the NHA has been the dominant decision maker. Of course. another way in which CP can create its own institutional problems is where there is an existing lack of coordination between agencies and departments which is compounded with the introduction of CP-type programmes. Where there is no efficient working relationship between departments responsible for service installation. payments collection. and maintenance in existing housing provision. for example, the superimposition of resident participation at its various levels and in its different degrees can only further complicate the problem of coordination. This, however, is not to say CP is undesirable. but that it presents difficulties which should be anticipated.
CITIES
November
1984
569
The question of coordination is partly ;I question of control: any multifaceted project will be coordinated by relatively few lx~plc and these. as such. exercise control. A problem hcrc is N*/I~ these should be. It remains a paradox that even in countries where CP is propounded vigorously it is controlled with minimal participation of the community. This means that CP is far from exhibiting the ‘optimal’ characteristics of level, degree and model referred to above. What tends to happen is that residents’ views and activities are channelled through go\,crnmentcontrolled bodies. such as the project agency or the hingle political party. The limits on potential for participation arc obvious. All the above points to the fact that CP. desirable as it undoubtedly is, produces problems as well as solutions and costs as well as bcncfit$. In addition to the costs referred to above. one can make rcferencc to two others which are not al~vays taken into account as IIILICII as they should be. The first is cost in terms of labour and efficiency. Rarely is self-help labour free: if it were not employed in the project it might bc LISCC~ to earn income; in any case. effort mcan5 the expenditure of calorica on the part of residents. Or it might be that collective Iabour tc:lms t;tkc several times as long as a contractor’s gang to deli\cr ;I product which is technically inferior. Secondly. some CP projects fail to include the cost of technical assistance in their accounting and tvhere this is subst;rntial. as is not unlikely in comprehenaivc schemes. the financial benefits arc greatly overstated.
Proposals for CP programmes It is clear that Cl’ is potentially potential depends, however, upon and degrees of CP stimulated. Even CP itself or the way in which it Ways of overcoming these have indirectly in the preceding sections. are reiterated here. and some not rized.
valuable. The realization of that the models adopted and the levels then difficulties arise, either out of is treated in a particular project. been suggested either directly or Some of the more important ways previously mentioned arc summa-
(1) CP should be conceived of as a process which will ultinzutel~~ rdqfi~rc relationships betlrvetz cornrmnities mtl the state. R&dents. through their own independent organizations. should be encouraged (not implementation and postforceti) to take part in the planning, implementation stages of a project with negotiation and agreement at all stages based upon ;I linking of residents’ needs and desires and the agency’s technical skills. The agency is. however. servant to the community. (3) The fulfilment of the above goal is not easy. It will often be and programmes Lvhich ITKJLYJ necessary to formulate projects toi~wds this gotrl gruiud!\~. (3) From the above it follows that CP is neither to be conceived of as an individual nor purely physical activity, though these are part of the picture. CP can take place at an individual, group and settlement level and incorporates mental as well as physical effort. Planning ‘echo dors trhar’ needs to take this into account. Whctl who does what depends on decisions taken regarding point (2). (4) However a project is formulated. following the above guidelines, it must consider the degree of htc~rdeprnclrrl(.c~of planning, impleof mentation and post-implementation stages. and the components each. if successful CP in any of them is expected.
570
CITIES
November
1984
(5) CP implies a revision of existing practices urzd organization in low-income housing delivery. New staff skills will need to be developed, rigid time schedules cannot be universally enforced, standards of construction and materials used must be relaxed, and project design should avoid the delivering of a ‘finished product’. (6) fnternational aid agencies can play a more active role in promoting CP. This assumes that CP is envisaged as an integral part of housing programmes for the poor on a par with financial and institutional considerations, which has not been the case to date. Such support will often find sympathetic groups among the range of domestic decision makers. To adopt a ‘neutral’ position instead is, in effect, to support the status quo against CP. (7) CP programmes should be elaborated with the active participation of all agencies, who might be expected to play a part in programme implementtion. This will help reduce the frictions and problems of institutional malcoordination which often accompany CP programmes. It may even be a means of healing old wounds in this respect. (8) CP is incompatible with one-sided, stare control. While the state will. through its various agencies, assume ultimate control of certain parts of the programme, so too must the community itself (eg in determining and, to a certain extent. implementing, local priorities for development). What these spheres of control are must be agreed upon by both state and community or CP will be impossible in the real sense of the term. (9) CP produces costs as well as benefits. The costs may include efficiency and technical assistance, though neither need always be great. For financial purposes, however, these costs must be taken into account. But benefits (which may well be financial also) will include social and political components. One should take both costs and benefits into account in order to avoid the two evils of utopianism (‘CP can never do any harm’) and technocracy (‘CP is financially and technically inefficient’).
1
Appendix Peru and Chile
For the Peruvian case of overt incorporation of low-income residential mobilization into national politics, see Collier,’ and Skinner.’ Collier shows how national governments or opposition parties have, since the 193Os, attempted to create alliances with squatters. By the period of the military government of Velasco (196%75), this had become comprehensive, systematic and part of an overall strategy purported to ‘transfer power’ to the organized masses at some unspecified
CITIES November
1984
future date. In this way, low-income residents would be equal to industrial and rural workers in a ‘non-capitalist. non-communist’ society. Skinner’ refers to a specific sites and services style of settlement, Villa
El Salvador,
which epitomized
the
above policy. Established in May 1971 by the government, it was soon heralded by the authorities as exemplifying both the progress which could be achieved by state-community cooperation and the new ‘autonomy’
of settlements in determining their priorities for development. Implicit in this was an invitation to participation in national politics: although in practice this was little more than a ploy (see Skinner’). the community organization actively strove to make it a reality. For example, in January 1976, by which time it had grown to some 130000 inhabitants, it convened the First Convention of P~ehlos Jo\~r~r.s of the Southern Core of Lima (p~rehlo joven = young town; this was the
571
government’s euphemism for squatter and similar low-income fringe ncighhourhoods). The Convention WIS highly critical of government scttlement pcjlicv and of its economic strategy. and this was the start of ;I political pi-ocesz which wah to produce the National Federation of f’~rch/o., .lo\,c,r~c,.s(FEDEPJOV) with ;I similarly broad and combative perspective on development issues.
Chile Pastrami and Threlfall’ explain most clearly the WI\; in which Chilean squatters acted collectivclv to make their \,oices heard at national level. While scluatters had (like the pcasantr\) undertaken land invasions under pi’cviou\ governments. such as that of Eduardo Frei (lY6-C70). it wa’r only when Salvador Allcnde was elected president that it was felt squatting would be protected ;ib an implicit principle of the left-wing Popular un-
ty coalition. but. more squatters limits
of
Invasions then increased significantly. claima 1,)
went beyond the traditional petitioning
for
service
in-
5talLition
and embraced demands for go\~ernment intervention in the supply of c\\ential commodities and the partial takeover of pri\ate production: squatters even participated in thcsc tal;co\.er\ before official any inter\,cntions.” While the government did not officialI> welcome \uch ationx. It was often forced to accept and legitimize them ~ the alternative of i-eprcssion was politically not feasible. Vantlerxchuer-cii~ similarly recounts squatter xttwt~s although hc is more interested in identifying which segments of the squatter population were at the forefront of this participation in tit\ antI national level politics. (‘astclls” i\ another important soui-cc for the analysis of the political significance of the squatter movcmcnt at this time.
References ‘D. Collier, Squatters and Olrgarchs: Authoritarian Rule and Policy Chanqe in Peru, Johns Hopkins Uniiersity Press, Baltimore, MD, 1976. pp 4G54. ‘R. Skinner, Community Organization, Collective Development and Politics KJ Se/f-/-/e/p Housing: Villa N Salvador, Lima (1977-7976), unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of Cambridge, 1981, DP 37-39: R. Skinner, ‘Self-helo. communit; organization and politics: Villa El Salvador, Lima’, In P. Ward (ed), Self-Help Housing: A Critique, Mansell, London, 1982. %kinner, 1981, op cif, Ref 2. %kinner, 1982, op cif, Ref 2. ‘E. Pastrana and M. Threlfall, Pan, Techo y Poder: N Movimienfo de Pobladores en Chile 197&73, Ediciones Nueva Vision. Buenos Aires, 1974. “Ibid, pp 10&104, 112-I 13. 7F. Vanderschueren, ‘The political signiflcance of neighbourhood committees In the settlements of Santiago’, in D. Johnson (ed), The Chilean Road to Socialism, Anchor Books, New York, 1973, pp 25G 283. ‘M. Castells, The Urban Question, Edward Arnold, London, 1977.
Appendix 2 Zambia, Papua New Guinea and Nicaragua The programme of squatter upgrading in Lusaka, Zambia (1971-78) did not reach the limits of CP as discussed under the headings of ‘conceptions’. ‘degrees’ and ‘levels’; it did, however. make substantial progress in these directions. Although decision making was ultimately in the hands of the state. as represented by the Housing Project Unit (HPU). this power was avoided as much as possible. Martin.’ shows how residents’ for example, leaders were responsible for the routing of roads rather than the following of predetermined, grid-iron plans. Leaders were also involved in management.’ As for degrees of CP. not only were the leaders instrumental in planning and management. but the population as a whole was expected to participate in other aspects of implementation. Here collective self-help was seen by one evaluator as ‘low‘ level. but the same writer pointed out that projects completed included mar-
572
kets. party offices. emergency drainage 1 infill of old quarry pits, and blockmaking.’ As implied here. most decisions were in the hands of leaders rather than individuals. but it can be argued that this is an advance on state control and. in any case. there is an ‘enormous degree of delegation implicit throughout the African tradition in decision-making and politics’.’ Where the Lusaka projects can be said to have fallen down is in the sphere of CP in maintenance, but this seems to have been the case mainly when the population was not involved in implementation such as with standpipes and multipurpose community centres ~ precisely what I have argued as a feature of interdependency of project components in the ‘degrees’ section above.’
decision making and residents having the final say on issues under discussion. Similarly. communities have taken part in the planning process through the negotiation of plans themselves coupled, for example, with onthe-ground decision making by means of a ‘walkabout’ to see the propok routing of a new road.’ Implementation provided for the employment of residents without jobs in infrastructural activities such as footpath and retaining wall construction. the placing of pit-latrine slabs and clearing and levelling of spaces for community facilities.’ Thus in conception and degree CP has been quite advanced; information on ‘levels’ is less readily available to the author.’
Nicaragua PNG In Papua New Guinea upgrading has included the conception of collective
Self-help housing is an integral part of an Urban Reform Programme in Nicaragua; but. even more than this.
CITIES
November
1984
CP can he regarded as integral to the concept of revolution since organized residents who had been active in the overthrow of the Somoza dictatorship in 1979 were now called upon to continue their activities in the process of reconstruction. In upgrading, this was initially envisaged as starting with decision making on overall project plans by community members in discussion with representatives of the housing ministry’s Department of ‘Social Promotion’. Settlement level organization would then be established with work brigades and subcommittees to cover savings, maintenance and ‘discipline’. The work itself would include training and study groups from leadership level down-
wards and encompassing administration and construction. House building was to be collective. Although in pratice there have been bureaucratic delays and some friction between the various actors, there is evidence to suggest that the programme sketched above, with a far-reaching ‘degree’, high ‘level’ and broad ‘conception’ of CP, has indeed been seen to operate.”
References ‘R. Martin, ‘Upgrading’, in R. Skinner and M. Rodell teds), Peopte, Poverty and Shelter: Pfobfems of Serf-yelp Housing in the Third Worid, Methuen, London, 1983. *M. Hoek-Smit, Community Parficipafion in Squatter Upgrading in Zambia, American Friends Service Committee. Philadelohia. PA, 1982, pp 70-71.
31bid, p 76. 4R. Martin, ‘The formulation of a self-help proiect in Lusaka’. in P. Ward led\. Selfkelp Housing: A Crifique, Ma&elij London, 1982, p 268. ‘Hock-Smit, op cif, Fief 2, pp 11 l-l 13. ‘Shankland Cox Partnership, Third World Urban Housing: Aspirations, Resources, Programmes, Pfojecfs, Building Research Establishment, Watford, 1977, pp 17s 180. 71bid, p 186. *See also, for the Papua New Guinean cases, H. Norwood, ‘People’s participation in urban settlement upgrading: three experiences in Papua New Guinea’, in P. Swan fed), The Practice of People’s Parficipafion: Seven Asian Experiences in ffousjng the Poor, Asian Institute of Technology, Bangkok, 1980, pp 89-l 28. ‘1. Vance, unpublished doctoral research manuscript, School of Social Sciences. University of Sussex, Hove, UK, 1983.
Appendix 3 Philippines,
Sri Lanka, Tanzania, Malawi and Indonesia
In the Philippines the most publicised and best known ‘participatory’ project is that of upgrading the Tondo Foreshore in Manila. The official commitment to popular wishes can be gauged by the fact that Tondo’s upgrading was started by the National Housing Authority in 1977 only after pressure from the World Bank which supported residents’ protests against eradication and relocation. With a population of over 2~~~,’ Tondo became a showpiece for the Philippines government and featured prominently in its exhibitions at the 1976 Vancouver Conference on Human Settlements (Habitat). The veracity of claims to be promoting CP can be questioned on numerous points: for example, the most active Tondo residents’ organization (ZOTO) had its leaders imprisoned for the duration of the Vancouver conference to prevent their presenting their views on the programme. Second, when alternative plans were presented to the residents’ groupings regarding upgrading, residents tended to select those plans requiring most relocation (NHA, internal survey) - a choice untypical of most squatter com-
ClTlES
November
1984
munities and smacking strongly of misinformation on the part of the planners ‘discussing’ options with the community. It also appears that very little organization for improvement. or even assistance in relocation, exists beyond the family unit. Finally, and in conjunction wifh the above, decisions in general have been made from the planning to maintenance stages by the NHA and/or World Bank whether or not they are then submitted for community ‘approval’. Families are only further involved in their house improvement and are expected to keep streets clean (personal observations).
Sri Lanka Self-help housing in Sri Lanka is a recent development: it was not until 1978 that ‘Slum and Shanty Improvement’ became a feature of policy statements.’ Despite good intentions on the part of some members of the Urban Development Authority’s Slum and Shanty Division what emerged was a very top-down approach which overlapped with earlier policies. Here one can compare the settlements of
Summitpura and Hennamulla, both in Colombo, with the former being of the ‘pre-self help’ era and the latter straddling this and the new ‘CP period’. Summitpura was a relocation scheme in which residents were allocated plots, and from then no participation in decision making was ever invited (the area became poorly maintained, refuse widely scattered, and houses located in flood zones). Hennamulla, on the other hand, was initially an upgrading scheme planned solely by central authorities but after the 1978 policy statement, incorporated the idea that residents ought to be ‘involved’. Unfortunately, this amounted to little more than abandoning government-built row houses in favour of shell and core structures. My own investigations, together with a Sri Lankan colleague in 19X2, found that virtually no decisions were made locally: there were contractors offering dwelling units for often unofficial modification, common facilities such as washrooms and toilets were inadequate, inconveniently located and in disrepair. and finally, post-implementation
upkeep
intended
573
for
residents
rather off
was
‘dumped
public
negotiated
in to
daytime.
public
involvement
such
found.
Finally.
in
residents’
priorities
better
standpipc
facilities instead
new
most
and
iramme
is its apparent
formal
structure
cipation the
grouping
households
quarter
w:i\
~Iccommod~rtetI
indi-
were
for
which
they
of
approxiniatcly
of popular
party
;I\ well
is
exi4t5.
there-is
quite
tasks
and receive
organi7;ltion; making
has
I.;ind\.
and
party
organs block
of
therefore,
interests their
house
oi- scllng
groups
them
~ and
more
than
evidence
making
;I passive
beyond
i5 conccntratcd Ministry) colverl
from
stages
(pcr\onal
574
first
priority
exprascd
and tor
facilitks,
refuse communitv
found
with
that
with
plot
little
applic;lnts,
oi
which
toilets total
and
Imigct.
I0
is
residents‘
public These
in
of
the
IS%
niaintt‘nance
considered
by tit!
to be the responsihilit\z organizations
do not
wit\ water
electricity
centres. than
of
as ;I
iiced
buildings.
Infrastructure
roads)
survey (70%
drinking
disposal.
less
for
Jakarta
or bridges
a strong
health
claimed
for
than
better
supply,
areas.
particip:lte
the responsibility government
while in this as that
the ;irc;i,
of the
as it is in other
city
”
References
cii-
a140 suggests
changes
choice
could
wcrc
popular
residents
decision
nianageni~nt
such
arrears
that
in
he i-educed if more
offered
arc nior6
and
actively
after
propost involved
in
allocation.
of
Indonesia The
Kampun~
ramme
sia in IYhY.
(‘Kampungs’
What.
ing
indi-
KIP
rcntins
to
them
the
;irc‘;i\
million
party
is little
however.
is
decision
and cant
(‘P
(cg the
appear
to
Malalvi
of Jakarta
Its
and
in
implementation.
without
beyond
that
KIP
hierarchical any
signifi-
individual ;ilthough
effort\.
The
absence
house it
has been popular of
participation
in two major
and maintenance. yeai-\.
The
(10’%, of
does with
r&dents.” eniplificd
observations).
over
has hccn very
paternalistic
building
arc uniii-
arca
hous-
cities).
at upgrading
pa~plr.~
p0wc1
planning
arts the infor-
low-income
Indonesian
urbanized
Prog-
in Indone-
that city alone had by IY78 reached 7.3
income There
of
aimed
hiphcr
centi-e
was started
is that
labour
in any
Improvement
(KIP).
mal and unplanned
their
residents
tifteen
roads
in all respects
is undertahcn
has supposedly than
placed
local
plot
Malawi F-orniorc
residents
of
Crooks
the indi\ idual. the
lY7-1 a lY73
fewer
~~dministr~ltors
representing
entitv.
of (‘P in
and
niaintcnance
local
the
scant
to
and
that
improvement.
an
any.
hiring
lY6Y
budget
indicated
to
bridges
accounted
KIP
is low
the
Ministry
to
to
I .5
between
roads.
channels
of the
is deli-
corrrspond
while
house
C’rooke’
no consultation
picture.
families.’
~ from
(‘P
example,
for such
in pi-actice
act according
improve out
ten
happens
residents vidual
those
Hut
individual
projects
;ll’l”.“xirn~ltel);
by powcr4
defunct)
than
million.” except
these
gov-
drainage
Evidence
what
alwavs
wishes:
X6.6’%
(except
1lousing ;ind Llrhan Develop, at ;I political Icvel. higher
ment
for
to
British
party
bodies
by higher-level
(rcccntly
alone
amounted
IYXI
howc\-
if
nullified
aid
to
the
the
promote
been
IJp
Lilongwe.
and
not
that
;I system
grass-roots
exercised
and
pur-
producing
little.
to
repre-
sphere.
arc‘ not trained
couragenient
were
areas.
seeing
;I diffcrcnt
officials
people
in these
for
In practice.
Party
million
raidcnts’
latter
in
such
and
a
ten
procesx
inbuilt
niachinrrv
the
that
about
package.
however.
does
;I gi-ass-
member
ways for
lYX1
improvement
vered
Housing
and 51’!4, of the two main
resptzctivelv.’
;illocation
suggests.
unit
I>!
participatory
concept
as the
ten-cell
mobilization
It would appear
By
Blaltyre
ernment
own
parti-
as the political
is ideal in many organked
of ;I
37%
cities.
‘Traditional
;I
sites loca-
of providing
in pcri-urban
THAs).
of
senting
For
prop-
integration
represented
elected
cr.
upgrading
the
roots
phyGcal
of l‘antania’s
on
post‘s
~
that
of community
hased
(called
had
aspect
sites and services
tions.
means
house.’
notable
plots
Areas’
Tanzania The
a policy
The
and home
of
haa followed and 4ervices
taps).
survey
cated
received
having
upkeep
an internal
improvement
but
(eg switching
Iack of discussion
earlier ii0
lights
made
repairs
not
on them
each kanipung
areas:
is cxpl~inninp
In the former been about
negotiation the nature
ther: in ot its
‘W. Keyes, ‘Case study: Metro-Manila, Philippines’, in M. Sarin (ed), Policies Towards Urban Slums: Slum and Squatter Settlements in the ESCAP Regron, United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific, Bangkok, 1980, p 50. ‘M. Fiodell. ‘Case study: Colombo, Sn Lanka’, Ibid, p 35. 3Personal communication, Mr L. William, Urban Development Authority. “B. Nnunduma, Policies of Low-income Shelter in Tanzania: Some Reflections from Manzese Squatter Upgrading and S/nza-Kijifonyama Sites and Services Prolecfs, Institute for Housing Studies, Rotterdam, Report No 1064, May 1984. “P. Crooke, ‘Popular housing supports and the urban housing market’, in R. Skinner and M. Rodell (eds), People, Poverty and Shelter: Problems of Se/f-He/p Housing m the Th/rd World, Methuen. London, 1983, p 183. 6P. Crooke, Low-Income Housrng in Malawi: an Evaluation of British-Aided Programmes, Overseas Development Administration, London, 1981, p 11. 71bid, pp 52-53. “L. Erni and Bianpoen, ‘Case study: Jakarta, Indonesia’, in Sarin, op cif, Ref 1, p 69. 9N. Devas, Indonesia’s Kampung Improvement Programme: An Evaluative Case Study, Development Administration Group, Institute of Local Government Studies, University of Birmingham, 1980. Occasional Paper 10. “Ernie and Bianpoen, op tit, Ref 8, p 71. “Devas, op cit. Ref 9, p 48.
CITIES
November
1984