Economics
Letters
14 (1984)
173
173-178
North-Holland
COMPARING The Limitations
Received
21 March
Marshallian Hicksian ing
1983
consumer’s compensating
variation
cannot
STOCHASTIC PRICE REGIMES of Expected Surplus Measures
is not
he Jutified
surplus variation.
a generally
can
often
Under valid
as an approximation
price
welfare
he
defended
as
uncertainty. measure.
to a rigorous
3 useful
however. and
approximation
expected
expected
to
compensat-
consumer‘s
surplus
construct.
1. Introduction
Although consumer’s surplus is not generally an exact representation of utility loss or gain, Willig (1976) has shown that it often closely approximates Hicksian compensating (or equivalent) variation: it is therefore a valuable practical tool for welfare analysis under conditions of certainty. When variability of supply generates price instability, many authors have used the expected value of consumer’s surplus as a measure of the benefits of some form of government intervention in the market. ’ We seek to determine whether, as has been commonly supposed, the rationale of consumer’s surplus approximating a rigorous Hicksian measure can be extended to expected consumer’s surplus in this case of stochastic prices.
’ See. e.g.. Waugh (1944) Samuelson (1977), and Wright (1979). 0165-1765/84/$3.00
1’: 1984,
Elsevier
(1972).
Science
Turnovaky
Publishers
(1976).
Bradford
B.V. (North-Holland)
and
KeleJ&m
L-l.
174
2. Conditions
Helm
/
Comparrng
stochustrc
for the validity of expected
prrce regtme.,
compensating
variation
Consider an individual with income >;I making consumption choices over good x and n - 1 other goods. Under the usual assumptions, ’ if only the price, p, of good x is variable, the utility maximization problem generates demand, expenditure, and indirect utility functions which may be written as x = _x( p. .v,,), y = e( p, u). and u = c( p. .r(,), respectively. If the price of good x changes from y top. the Marshallian consumer’s surplus
from
that
price
change
is
It is well known that A( 4, p. y(,) is a rigorous change in utility only if the marginal utility respect
to the
price
of X. Nonetheless,
monetary of income
even
when
equivalent of the is constant with
P,,, f 0. the
use
of
consumer’s surplus as a practical tool has been justified by Willig’s result that A is approximately equal to Hicksian measures such as compensating variation.
under
typical
circumstances.
If uncertainty on variation in the price
’
the supply side of the market of good X, the prices before and
induces random after the change
will be random variables. 4 In this case it is common to use the expectation of consumer’s surplus, EA(q, p. >i,). as a welfare measure. Rogerson (1980) has shown that the necessary and sufficient conditions for EA to represent
consumer are
- EP(~,J;,)]] underlying
the consumer’s
It is therefore _a We
assume
’ ,411 results
tempting
that
differentiable,
the
strtctly and
[i.e.. to have the same sign as [ Ev(q, .r;,) same in this case as the assumptions
preferences exactly the surplus
measure
to conclude
consumer
maxunizes
increasing
van
rcmarkr
below
that
under
conditions
a strictly
quasiconcave,
Neumann-Morgenstern
are equally
of certainty. of A as an
the justification
applicable
utility to Hickbian
twcc
contlnuoubl)
function. equivalent
variation.
nllltutl~ nzutumh. 4 These
random
government he related average’.
variables, interventmn
q and
p.
might
to (partialI>)
to q by the requirement
represent
stabilize that
price
the price
the government’s
distributions of good sale\
hefore
.x. In that and
purchaw
and
after
C:IX. p would cancel
‘on
175
L.J. Helms / Comparing stochrrstlc prrce regimes
approximation to the rigorous measure C also carries over when expectations are taken in the stochastic case. Unfortunately, the conditions under which expected compensating variation. (3) represents consumer preferences when prices are random are quite restrictive. We begin by noting that (3) depends on the joint distribution of q and p. It is conceptually troublesome that the covariance of the results of two mutually exclusive policy alternatives, or any information beyond the marginal distributions, would affect the welfare comparison. But even in the absence of such correlations, EC can produce paradoxical results, as exemplified by the following Lemma: Lenmu. Suppose thut the prices for all but the first good ure fixed und thut income is constant at Jo,. Consider tM!o non-degenerate identicul!v und itldependently distributed rundom vuriubles q und p representing ulternutive price distributions for the first good. Then, if thut good is strictly normul Msithprobability one. EC(q.P,.h,)>O
Proof. random
Let F( q, p) be the joint cumulative variables q and p. Then
Ec(q,p,:,,)=/
function
for the
is zero for p = q, we can break the integral
up into
{e(p,
v(q.y,,))-e(q,
distribution
~‘(q..h)))dF(q~P).
P-q
Because the integrand two components:
Ec(q.p,_v,,)=J {e(P,v(q,~~:,,))-e(q.V(q,.~,,))}dF(q,p) P(Y
-tj
{e(p,u(q,.y,y,,))--e(q,v(q.~~,))}dF(q,p). Y (P
Now because q and p are identically and independently distributed. F(q, p) is identical to F( p, q). Rewriting the second integral by making
176
L.J.
this substitution the same integral
and then leaves
Helms
+/ PC4
/
Compurrng
stochastrr
interchanging
price regimes
the variables
of integration
in
b+b d~d’o?o))-e(~. hu,))}dF(q.p).
Using the property that Hicksian demand at price 5 and utility level 11can be written as A([. rl) = e,,({. u) and recombining the integrals, the expression is equivalent to
Since h({.
h(.t,
u(q,
,v(,))
=
x({,
e(l,
u(q.
.k;,)))
<
-Y(l.
e(l,
rl( p.
>;,))I
square
=
for a strictly normal good when p < q. the integrand brackets in (4) is strictly negative and so the integral in braces
u( p, ytLi)))
strictly positive for p < q. Moreover, since p and q are identically independently distributed and non-degenerate. the set of values p c q has positive measure, establishing the result. Q.E.D.
The Lemma shows that, for a normal good. tion above an identical. unrelated distribution, yield the same expected utility. Moreover, always possible to find two independently and p, such that q stochastically dominates
EC ranks despite
in is
and with
a price distributhe fact that both
continuity assures that it is distributed price variables. q p and yet EC ranks q below
P. These results suggest that EC is a valid welfare extremely limited circumstances. That this is indeed the following Theorem: Theorrnl .
thut income equivalent:
criterion only under the case is proven in
Suppose thut the prices for ull hut the first c~ood are fised is constant ut .r;,. Then the following two propositions
utd are
L.J. Helms / Comparing stochastic prm
117
regmes
(i) Given any two alternative price distributions, good,
q and p, for the first
(ii) v,, =x, = 0, and v,,,,= 0 whenever demand for
the first good is
positive Proof. (i) + (ii): Suppose x,.(s, y,)) > 0 for some price s. Then by continuity x,. is strictly positive within some neighborhood of s for fixed _r,). Let q and p be non-denegerate identically and independently distributed random variables taking on positive values within this neighborhood with probability one. Then from the Lemma EC(q. p, y,)) > 0. but since Eu(q, yO) = Eu( p, yo), this contradicts (i). Similarly, x, (s. _J+)< 0 leads to a contradiction, establishing that x,. = 0. Since x,. = 0 we know from the Slutsky equation that Hicksian and Marshallian demand curves coincide, so EC(q, p, yo) = EA(q, p, y,)). Rogerson’s (1980) Theorem 1 shows that EA, and hence EC, represents consumer preferences in this case only if differentiating Roy’s identity, x(s, _r,,) = - ~;~(.s,.1;,)/ u,,,, = 0. Finally, I), (s, yU). with respect to y yields L’,./,= -xv,, - xp, which. together with x = 11,,, = 0, establishes the result. ’ (ii) + (i): R o ge rson’s Theorem demonstrates that u,.,, = 0 is sufficient to establish that EA represents consumer preferences. This, together with the equivalence of EC to EA implied by x,. = 0 and the Slutsky equation, completes the proof. Q.E.D. In order to ensure that EC provides the same ranking of two alternative price regimes as does expected utility, we must assume not only that the marginal utility of income is constant with respect to changes in the price of good x (as required for the validity of EA), but also that the marginal utility of income is invariant to changes in income (i.e., that the consumer is risk neutral). Thus only in these extremely restrictive circumstances, when income effects are nil and EC coincides with EA, is EC a valid welfare measure. ’
’
If
we consider
questions relaxed Helms welfare
of
only the
somewhat. (198321) indicator.
cases
welfare See
indicate
where effects
Helms that
p 1s subject
to stochastic
of complete
price
(1983b). EC
(as well
However. as EA)
variation
stabilization). even
in these
can be qwte
but these
cases, misleading
q is comtant restrictions
numerical
(i.e.. can
results
as a quantitative
be in
L.J. Helms / Comparrng stochcrstlc price regimes
178
3. Conclusion
In a non-stochastic setting, compensating variation provides a rigorous measure of the willingness to pay for a change in price. As a result. Marshallian consumer’s surplus, which is approximately equal to compensating variation in many cases, may be useful as an approximately correct welfare measure. When prices are uncertain, however. no such reassurances can be made. The expectation of compensating variation can rank alternative price distributions perversely and will always rank some distributions above others which provide greater expected utility except when the marginal utility of income is constant and income effects are nil. Because expected compensating variation is a valid welfare measure only under conditions which are even more restrictive than those required for the validity of expected consumer’s surplus. the usefulness of the latter in more general cases cannot be justified by arguments that it is an approximation to the former.
References Bradford,
David
forecasting
F.
and
Harry
in a market
H.
system:
1977.
KeleJian,
Some
theoretical
The issues.
value
of
Review
information
of Economic
for Studies
crop 44.
519-531. Helm.\.
L. Jay,
tion.
1983a.
University
Helms.
L. Jay.
1983b.
stabilization. Rogerson,
William
Turnovsky.
P.. 1980. Aggregate
Stephen Frederik
Journal
A.,
Robert
of the benefits
surplus
and
working
paper
consumer
Econometrica does benefit
of price
stahilira-
no. 217. the
welfare
effects
of
prxc
index
with
no. 202.
surplus
as a welfare
48, 423-436. from
feaxble
price
stability.
Quarterly
86. 476-493. disturbances.
1944.
of Economics
paper
expected
stabilization.
J.. 1976. The distribution
case of multiplicative
Willig.
consumer’s
of California-Davis
to price
of Economics
assessment
working
Paul A.. 1972. The consumer
Journal
Waugh.
in the numerIcal
Expected
University
an application Samuelson.
Errors
of California-Daws
Does
of welfare
International
the consumer
gains
Economic benefit
from
from
price
Review price
stabilization:
The
17, 133-148.
instability?.
Quarterly
5X, 602-614.
D.. 1976. Consumer’s
surplus
without
apology.
Amervzan
Economic
Review
A welfare
analysts
66. 5X9-597. Wright. under
Brian
D..
rational
1979. behavior.
The
effects Journal
of ideal of Political
production Economy
stabilizatwn: X7. 1011~1033.