Journal Pre-proof Cooperative R&D investments and licensing breakthrough technologies: International environmental agreements with participation game Nobuyuki Takashima PII:
S0959-6526(19)34103-4
DOI:
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.119233
Reference:
JCLP 119233
To appear in:
Journal of Cleaner Production
Received Date: 24 July 2019 Revised Date:
5 November 2019
Accepted Date: 8 November 2019
Please cite this article as: Takashima N, Cooperative R&D investments and licensing breakthrough technologies: International environmental agreements with participation game, Journal of Cleaner Production (2019), doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.119233. This is a PDF file of an article that has undergone enhancements after acceptance, such as the addition of a cover page and metadata, and formatting for readability, but it is not yet the definitive version of record. This version will undergo additional copyediting, typesetting and review before it is published in its final form, but we are providing this version to give early visibility of the article. Please note that, during the production process, errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain. © 2019 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
1
Cooperative
R&D
investments
and
licensing
breakthrough
2
International environmental agreements with participation game
technologies:
3 4
Nobuyuki Takashima
5
Kyushu University Platform of Inter / Transdisciplinary Energy Research (Q-PIT)
6
744 Motooka, Nishi-ku, Fukuoka 819-0395, Japan
7
Tel: +81-92-802-5501; Fax: +81-92-802-5501
8
E-mail:
[email protected]
9
10
JEL Classification: Q54; Q52; D64; C72
11 12
1
13
Abstract
14
This study examines international environmental agreements (IEAs) with cooperative
15
R&D, which can bring about a substantial reduction in greenhouse gas emissions. To
16
achieve a large IEA size consisting of more than four countries, we propose a novel
17
method of cooperative R&D investment and recovery and a licensing fee for the
18
adoption of advanced technology, by applying the mechanism of a joiner’s gain function.
19
The core findings of this study reveal that: (i) a large agreement can be achieved by
20
considering R&D investment, R&D recovery, and a licensing fee; (ii) the diffusion
21
process of advanced technology is clarified; (iii) non-investors’ adoption of an advanced
22
abatement technology can be prevented by setting a licensing fee and instead, they
23
participate and invest in R&D via agreement; (iv) a full participation state can be more
24
easily sustained than any other number of participants. Our approach shows the
25
diffusion process of advanced abatement technology after R&D. Consequently, this
26
paper fills a research gap in cooperative R&D methods and the diffusion process of
27
advanced technologies and provides a hopeful prospect for achieving full participation
28
in IEAs and a large reduction in GHG emissions by way of cooperative R&D.
29
30
2
31
Keywords: international environmental agreements; environmental R&D; breakthrough
32
technology; participation game; investment
33
34
Abbreviations
35
CR: collective response
36
GHG: greenhouse gas
37
IEA: international environmental agreement
38
R&D: research and development
39
UA: unilateral action
40
UNFCCC: United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
41
WRP: weakly renegotiation-proof
42
3
43
1. Introduction
44
Broad, international cooperation is required to ensure that the global temperature
45
increase during this century is far less than 2 °C above pre-industrial levels, and to
46
encourage countries to limit temperature increases to 1.5 °C. Countries generally
47
participate and meet their commitments to global agreements such as the Kyoto
48
Protocol and Paris Agreement. In 2015, all parties to the United Nations Framework
49
Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) Paris Agreement agreed to uphold and
50
promote international cooperation to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions
51
(UNFCCC, 2016).
52
There is a rapidly expanding body of literature on transboundary pollution at local
53
and global scales. At local scale, the latest literature addresses climate change mitigation
54
by focusing on various factors. Ma et al. (2019) assessed the intensity and total values
55
of CO2 mitigation in the residential building sector of China, at household scale. Qiao et
56
al. (2019) investigated peak coal consumption, using cases of CO2 emissions in China,
57
at national, regional, and individual provincial levels. Sedghamiz et al. (2018)
58
developed a conjunctive use model to optimize water allocation to different agricultural
59
sectors, considering the virtual water concept and game theory simultaneously. Wahba
60
et al. (2018) examined the energy reduction advantages of adding greenery atop
4
61
buildings in the hot, arid climate of Egypt. Striebig et al. (2019) investigated GHG
62
emissions caused by food transport and compared GHG emissions owing to local and
63
non-local food production. Pash et al. (2017) identified the main and sub-indices in
64
assessing the environmental impact of ports, to set goals for reducing pollution in ports.
65
Battaglia et al. (2018) investigated the relationship between adoption of domestic
66
environmental agreements and their stimulus to a green economy and green jobs
67
creation.
68
The results of these studies are helpful in updating the policymakers’ knowledge, to
69
improve decision-making regarding domestic or regional environmental plans. These
70
recent papers provide fundamental insights and methodologies for climate change
71
mitigation at domestic or regional level. It is expected that greater effects of climate
72
change prevention can be obtained if many countries abate GHG emissions by applying
73
these fundamental methodologies and insights. Carrascal Incera et al. (2017) explored
74
the determinants of gray water increases, which were only analyzed at local level, in an
75
international context and provided insights into water pollution dynamics worldwide.
76
To achieve global cooperation for climate change, countries have ratified
77
international environmental agreements (IEAs), such as the Kyoto Protocol and Paris
78
Agreement. Barret (2006) stated that effective IEAs for climate change must promote
5
79
the joint supply of two global public goods: climate change mitigation and knowledge
80
of new abatement technologies. In the 21st Session of the Conference of the Parties to
81
the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change in 2015, it was agreed to
82
enhance climate technology development and transfer (UNFCCC, 2016). Technological
83
innovation is a critical accelerator and enhancer of efforts to implement national action
84
for climate change and to achieve the Paris Agreement goals (UNFCCC, 2017).
85
Reflecting the aim of the Paris Agreement, Japan’s Ministry of the Environment (2017)
86
stated that diffusion of Japanese technologies, know-how, and findings within and
87
outside of the country is important for international cooperation and contributing to
88
global improvement. It is essential for countries to promote technological innovation by
89
investing cooperatively in R&D via global climate change treaties aimed at the
90
development and diffusion of breakthrough technologies.
91
Several papers have presented important findings on the development of abatement
92
technologies through R&D efforts and diffusion of advanced abatement technologies
93
among countries using an IEA framework and a participation game model. Barrett
94
(2006) presented pioneering work on IEA models in which each country can choose
95
novel or existing abatement technologies in the context of IEAs. However, it is assumed
96
that the breakthrough level is sufficiently large that the costs function changes from
6
97
quadratic to linear, and all countries choose their R&D level before the coalition is
98
formed. Following Barrett (2006), Hoel and de Zeeuw (2010) considered that each
99
country chooses its R&D investment level collectively (cooperatively) or individually
100
(non-cooperatively); however, their analysis was conducted under the case where
101
non-cooperative R&D is beneficial for all.
102
Karp and Simon (2013) showed that IEAs consisting of more than four countries are
103
possible by lowering the slope of the marginal abatement costs function. However, in
104
their model, R&D costs for technological innovation were not considered. El-Sayed and
105
Rubio (2014) examined IEAs in which countries decide their investment levels, to
106
minimize the agreement costs of controlling emissions. Those authors reported
107
relatively pessimistic results regarding the effect of R&D on IEA size; the maximum
108
participation in agreements with R&D consisted of six countries. Rubio (2017) showed
109
that full participation can be sustained if marginal damages are large enough to justify
110
development of a breakthrough technology that completely eliminates emissions and if
111
technology spillovers are not very large. However, such drastic change in abatement
112
technology seems unrealistic, and even if it were possible, it is expected that enormous
113
costs are needed to achieve such change.
114
Through the review of the existing literature, thus, little consideration has been
7
115
given to obtaining investment levels for innovation of abatement technologies, to
116
achieve broad participation in IEAs, considering methods to recover countries’ R&D
117
expenditure. Additionally, little work has been done on revealing the mechanism by
118
which advanced technology diffuses inside and outside of a coalition. Therefore,
119
without assuming non-cooperative R&D and unrealistic (excessively drastic) innovation
120
of abatement technologies, the following three questions are proposed for the success of
121
IEAs with R&D and technological innovation.
122
Q1: How should countries invest in R&D and how much R&D investment is
123
needed to sustain IEAs in which many countries participate and invest in R&D
124
without assuming non-cooperative R&D and excessively drastic (unrealistic)
125
abatement technology innovation?
126
Q2: What kind of process can be used to diffuse advanced abatement technologies?
127
Q3: Can we design IEAs that motivate non-investors to participate in agreements
128
and invest in R&D?
129
The present study addresses above the questions by applying a joiner’s gain function.
130
More precisely, we provide new R&D methods that integrate: (i) a cooperative R&D
131
effect; (ii) a method of recovering R&D investment; (iii) a licensing fee under an IEA
132
framework, applying a joiner’s gain function. For (i), we assume that the efficiency in
8
133
R&D costs works if countries cooperatively invest in R&D. That is, the investment in
134
R&D decreases if countries cooperatively invest in R&D. This assumption is based on
135
Bosetti et al. (2008) who considered that international knowledge spillovers tend to
136
decrease R&D investment. Applying the joiner’s gain function and cooperative R&D,
137
we consider that signatories who receive a joiner’s gain equally share the R&D costs, as
138
a rule of R&D expenditure. For (ii), we consider a method of recovering R&D
139
investment via improved abatement technologies. For (iii), payment of a licensing fee is
140
needed if countries that have not invested in R&D adopt the new advanced technologies.
141
These three mechanisms are considered by applying the mechanism of a joiner’s gain
142
function.
143
The key distinguishing features of our model are as follows. First, we propose a
144
novel R&D method by applying the mechanism of a joiner’s gain function. Second, this
145
study is the first to reveal a process of technology diffusion by applying the joiner’s gain
146
function. Regarding IEAs with R&D for climate change, to the author’s best knowledge,
147
such analytical methods have not been proposed (see Table 1).
148
The following results are obtained: (i) a large IEA size consisting of more than four
149
countries can be achieved by considering R&D investment and R&D recovery; (ii) the
150
diffusion process of advanced technology is clarified; (iii) adoption of advanced
9
151
abatement technology by non-investors is prevented by setting a licensing fee and
152
instead, non-investors participate and invest in R&D by agreement; (iv) a full
153
participation state can be more easily sustained than any other number of participants.
154
Integration of the joiner’s gain function and methods of R&D investment, R&D
155
recovery, and a licensing fee represent a hopeful prospect for achieving participation in
156
agreements by all countries and a large reduction in GHG emissions through
157
cooperative technological innovation with collective R&D.
158
The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the
159
participation game model and joiner’s gain function. Section 3 introduces our model
160
and game stages when considering R&D. Section 4 presents the conditions for R&D
161
expenditure and R&D efficiency for a larger number of participating countries. Section
162
5 introduces the licensing fee by which non-investors in R&D can adopt new advanced
163
technologies and shows the ease of achieving a full participation agreement. In Section
164
6.1, we confirm whether our results completely answer the questions raised in Section
165
1; in Section 6.2, we examine whether our results can be explained using a different
166
approach. Section 7 provides our conclusions, including core findings, policy
167
implications, and upcoming studies. Figure 1 illustrates the flowchart of the present
168
study.
10
169
Insert Table 1
170
Insert Figure 1
171
172
2. Participation game and joiner’s gain function
173
This section introduces the concept of the participation game and joiner’s gain function.
174
As no supranational authority exists for resolving transboundary environmental
175
problems such as climate change, each country has to negotiate emissions reductions
176
and ratify IEAs. To achieve the long-term low carbon vision of the Paris Agreement,
177
cooperation by all countries is essential. Every country benefits from other countries’
178
abatement of transboundary pollutants in a non-exclusive and non-competitive manner.
179
Because of the public nature of transboundary pollutant abatement, the effectiveness of
180
IEAs depends on the number of participating countries and level of public good
181
provision. However, each country can free ride on others’ abatement efforts. Therefore,
182
the design of IEAs should prevent free riding and sustain a larger number of
183
participating countries.
184
Several studies have analyzed the design of a grand coalition in which all countries
185
participate, using a participation game model. A participation game model depicts
186
formation of an IEA in a one-shot game where a game represents any situation in which
11
187
countries negotiate and decide their pollution abatement levels, typically focusing on
188
participation. However, in early studies of IEAs, Barrett (1994) and Carraro and
189
Siniscalco (1993) showed that an agreement that substantially improves global welfare
190
is sustainable only if a few countries join. Those authors thus provided a pessimistic
191
view of cooperation in solving global environmental problems.
192
In the framework of a participation game model, a coalition is stable if it satisfies
193
conditions of internal and external stability. First, no signatory should have an incentive
194
to withdraw from the agreement (internal stability). Second, no non-signatory should
195
have an incentive to join the agreement (external stability). Later studies aimed to
196
increase the size of agreement by considering different policies such as trade sanctions
197
(Barrett, 1997), matching schemes (Fujita, 2013), and altruism (van der Pol et al., 2012)
198
to increase the number of countries participating in IEAs. However, an increase in
199
coalition size as well as in the total abatement are important dimensions of climate
200
change mitigation.
201
Applying the concepts of internal and external stability, Karp and Simon (2013)
202
introduced a novel decomposition of the gains from participation in IEAs. Those
203
authors expanded on the pessimistic results of Barrett (1994) and Carraro and Siniscalco
204
(1993) related to the size of sustainable IEAs. A joiner’s gain function merges the
12
205
external and internal stability conditions into one condition, that is, whether a joiner can
206
gain from the agreement. Thus, countries participate as long as they can gain from
207
participation. Karp and Simon (2013) revealed how many countries participate in
208
agreement under a certain abatement technology and what kind of process is needed for
209
countries to participate in agreement.
210
The present research, based on the joiner’s gain function, takes a different approach
211
toward formation of IEAs with R&D in comparison with previous studies of the
212
participation game model. Generally, the literature on IEAs with a participation game
213
model aimed to determine the number of participating countries obtained endogenously
214
as a stability condition of IEAs, i.e., the number of participating countries when a stable
215
coalition is obtained. However, our model can reveal the R&D investment levels needed
216
to sustain a larger number of participating countries by applying a joiner’s gain function.
217
Additionally, our approach leads to better understating of the process of participation in
218
agreement.
219
220
221
222
13
223
3. Model and stages of a participation game with R&D
224
Below, we summarize the notations used in this section:
225
: total number of countries;
226 227
228
229 230
231 232 233
234
235
: number of signatories in an agreement; = + − ,
where : total abatement level,
: abatement level of a signatory,
: abatement level of a non-signatory;
= : benefits that each country receives from total abatement ;
= ⁄2 = ⁄2: costs owed by a signatory (non-signatory), depending on its individual abatement level ( ), under abatement technology M; : payoff of a signatory;
: payoff of a non-signatory;
236
= ∑ : total payoff of the coalition of signatories;
237
E: level of innovation of an abatement technology;
238
: R&D efficiency;
239
I: R&D expenditure per signatory.
240
14
241
3.1. The model
242
Consider a world with = 1, ⋯ , ! identical countries. The benefit of reducing
243
emissions in a single country is proportional to its abatement and affects all countries’
244
benefits whereas the abatement costs are proportional only to its abatement level. When
245
≥ 2 countries participate, under the current abatement technology, the payoff
246
functions for the signatories and non-signatories are, respectively,
247
248
249
250
251
252
253
= − ,
(1)
= − ,
(2)
and
where denotes the abatement levels of the signatories, the abatement levels of the non-signatories, and equals + − . Each country receives benefit from total abatement , and owes a cost depending on its individual abatement
level . The subscripts $ and % denote the signatories and non-signatories, respectively, and the superscript the number of signatories. Each signatory selects
as an optimal solution that maximizes the coalition payoffs and each non-signatory
254
selects as the optimal solution that maximizes its individual payoff. As in Karp and
255
Simon (2013), we assume that a country chooses to join if it is indifferent regarding
256
joining an IEA.
15
257
We consider that = and = ⁄2 for ∈ ℝ( , respectively. As
258
per Karp and Simon (2013), we use a non-parametric expression to avoid specific
259
functional forms and reliance on parametric examples; additionally, this provides
260
simplicity and mathematical convenience. In terms of the cost function, the marginal
261
cost to reduce emissions is thought to increase as environmental quality improves and
262
treatment activities progress. Let be the total payoff of the coalition of signatories,
263
that is, = ∑ from (1). Differentiating with respect to , the first-order
264
condition for maximizing total payoff is ) ⁄) = ) ⁄) − ) ⁄2 = 0.
(3)
265
Differentiating with respect to in (2), and the assumption of an interior solution,
266
the first-order condition for maximizing an individual country’s payoff is ) ,) = ) ⁄) − ) ⁄2 = 0.
267
268
269
270
271
272
(4)
From (3) and (4), solves = and solves 1 = . Therefore,
is independent of k, and we define as . Additionally, under abatement technology , we have = and = . Under = and = ⁄2 , the unique stable equilibrium is = 3 (see Remark 2 in Karp and Simon (2013)).
Additionally, an agreement with ≥ 4 is achieved if abatement costs are reduced by kinking the slope of .
16
273
3.2. Stages of game
274
Formally, we have the following four-stage game:
275
Stage 1. Individual countries choose whether to join the coalition.
276
Stage 2. If some countries accede to the agreement, signatories choose R&D
277
expenditure levels for developing abatement technologies.
278
Stage 3. The coalition chooses whether to adopt the new technology.
279
Stage 4. Non-investors individually choose whether to adopt the advanced technology.
280
281
Signatories collectively choose the abatement levels that maximize the coalition
282
payoff whereas non-signatories choose the abatement levels that maximize each
283
country’s individual payoff. As in Hoel and de Zeeuw (2010) and El-Sayed and Rubio
284
(2014), signatories choose R&D expenditures after the participation stage. That is, once
285
a coalition forms in Stage 1, it remains a coalition after the investment decision in Stage
286
2. Stage 2 reflects signatories’ cooperative R&D efforts toward innovation of abatement
287
technologies. We consider a trade-off between R&D and marginal abatement costs, as in
288
Hoel and de Zeeuw (2010). That is, countries reduce their marginal abatement costs by
289
investing in R&D.
290
We adopt the following assumption for countries’ R&D investment:
17
291
Assumption 1.
292
The signatories that accede to the agreement in Stage 1 decide the lowest R&D level
293
at which the th joiner’s gain with R&D costs is equal to 0.
294
295
The logic behind this assumption is as follows. Signatories in Stage 1 decide on the
296
improvement levels for the abatement technology, to make the IEA with R&D profitable.
297
Even if they expect their payoffs to increase with future participation by non-investing
298
countries, each country would not likely participate in such an agreement because the
299
“loss” could negatively affect the nation, even if temporarily. Hence, each country
300
participates in an IEA where investing countries can immediately and definitely recover
301
their R&D costs. In Stage 3, signatories (i.e., investors) collectively choose the
302
abatement levels that maximize the coalition payoff, including R&D costs, after
303
advanced abatement technology development if they adopt the advanced technology.
304
Adoption means that signatories invest in R&D and improve abatement technologies
305
based on R&D expenditure levels decided in Stage 2. If the new technology is not
306
adopted, the agreement consisting of countries is not sustained.
307
We allow non-investors to adopt the advanced technology in Stage 4, following
308
Hoel and de Zeeuw (2010). In Stage 4, those countries that adopted the new technology
18
309
(i.e., investors in Stage 3 and non-investors that adopt the advanced technology in Stage
310
4) collectively choose those abatement levels that maximize the increased coalition
311
payoff if non-investors adopt the advanced technology. Non-investors who do not adopt
312
the advanced technology choose the reduction levels that maximize each country’s
313
individual payoff. Therefore, this study adopts the following assumption.
314
315
Assumption 2.
316
A non-investor is a “new participant” in an IEA with advanced abatement technology if
317
it adopts the advanced technology in Stage 4.
318
319
The rationale behind this assumption is as follows. Non-investors have an incentive
320
to adopt advanced technology because they can receive the joiner’s gain. Moreover,
321
existing signatories have no incentive to refuse their participation. Thus, they choose an
322
abatement level that maximizes the coalition, including the non-investors. Therefore, we
323
consider non-investors to be new participants in the IEA with advanced abatement
324
technology if they adopt the advanced technology in Stage 4. The number of
325
participants equals the sum of the original participants in Stage 1 (i.e., investors) and
326
new participants (i.e., non-investors) that adopt the advanced technology in Stage 4.
19
327
3.3. Joiner’s gain function with R&D cost
328
Karp and Simon’s (2013) joiner’s gain function represents the incremental increase (or
329
decrease) in a non-signatory’s payoff if it joins the agreement as the kth member. We
330
consider that signatories choose R&D expenditure I to improve abatement technology.
331
Let / denote the abatement costs after innovations in emission abatement
332
technology and 0 ≥ 0 denote the signatory’s investment in R&D to change to
333
/ . The joiner’s gain function with advanced abatement technology and with R&D
334
costs is 1 = + − − / − 2 −
335
134
(5)
+ − + 1 − 5 − 0,
Rearranging (5), we have 1 = − 34 + 34 −
− 2/ − 34 + 34 − 5 − 0.
(6)
336
From (3) and (4), solves = and solves 1 = . We can
337
decompose (6) into 1 = 6 − 78 − 0,
338
(7a)
where
20
78 = 34 − − 34 − > 0 339
(7b)
and 6 = − 34 − 2/ − 34 5 > 0.
(7c)
340
UA (unilateral action) denotes the utility loss of a non-signatory if it increases its
341
abatement from to 34 , which the signatories to an agreement with − 1
342
members produce, and other countries maintain their abatement levels. Because is
343
individually optimal and independent of the number of participating countries , the
344
increase in cost is greater than that in benefits for unilateral action, as (7b) states.
345
Additionally, we know that 78 2 = 0 when = 2 because = 4 .
346
CR (collective response) denotes the utility gain of the signatory when all
347
signatories to the coalition with an additional member increase their abatement levels
348
from 34 to , as in (7c). Because is collectively optimal for this enlarged
349
350 351
352
353
coalition with members, the increment in benefits owing to the aggregate reduction
level is greater than the cost increment. Additionally, when = 2, 6 2 ≥ 0 because = 4 .
The joiner’s gain function with R&D costs shows that each country has an incentive to participate as long as 6 − 78 − 0 ≥ 0.
354
21
355
4. R&D and technological innovation
356
We examine levels of R&D improvement and R&D costs to satisfy the condition that
357
0 = 6 − 78 .
358
359
4.1. R&D efficiency and recovery
360
Our model considers that the sum of the signatories’ joiner’s gain will recover the R&D
361
costs and that R&D investment works effectively if countries collectively (i.e.,
362
cooperatively) develop the abatement technology (i.e., R&D efficiency).
363
Let us consider an IEA in which ≥ 4 countries participate by considering that
364
they (i.e., investors) invest in R&D and improve abatement technology. To recover
365
; , which is larger than :, R&D costs, we consider an improved abatement technology :
366 367
368 369
; to sustain the number of by paying additional R&D costs. That is, : is extended to : participants ≥ 4. Let < > 0 be the level of abatement technology innovation, ; and :; that is, : ; − : = <, and let parameter denoted by the difference between :
> 0 denote R&D efficiency. We assume that the effect of results only if countries
370
cooperatively invest in R&D. A lower level of denotes higher R&D efficiency. This
371
effect is similar to that of Bosetti et al. (2008) where international knowledge spillovers
372
tend to decrease investment in R&D. Therefore, we express the change in R&D costs
22
373
; = : + < as = − 2 − 1> + <. from to :
374
The logic behind R&D efficiency is as follows. Efficient cooperative R&D can
375
result from cooperating countries taking full advantage of the latest technologies.
376
Additionally, we assume that : − = ∞ when the abatement costs function changes
377
from quadratic to linear. Therefore, such drastic improvement in abatement technology
378
is impossible.
379
As a rule of R&D expenditure, we consider that signatories who receive the joiner’s
380
gain equally share the R&D costs. For joiner’s gain of the first and second participants,
381
we set the following assumption.
382
383
Assumption 3.
384
First and second participants simultaneously receive the same level of joiner’s gain.
385
386
This is because a coalition consisting of a single country is not considered an
387
agreement. Therefore, we consider that two countries (i.e., the first and second
388
participants) simultaneously participate in agreement. After that, other countries join the
389
agreement in order. Thus, all participants can receive the joiner’s gain and pay the R&D
390
cost from their joiner’s gain. This assumption does not affect the third and later
23
391
participants’ joiner’s gain because UA occurs from the third participant (see Section
392
3.3).
393
Figure 2, adapted from Karp and Simon (2013), shows that the number of investors
394
in R&D (participants) increases if marginal costs curve is kinked. In Figure 2, we
395
396
denote the R&D expenditure per country with the dotted area in blue, < ⁄2; that is, 0 = < ⁄2. We confirm that countries can owe an R&D cost of < ⁄2. From (7a), (7b),
397
; , as also shown in and (7c), = , 34 = − 1, and = 4 = . Under :
398
Karp and Simon (2013), the magnitude relationship among each signatory in the k
399
members’ coalition’s joiner’s gain is 1 + 1 < 0 ≤ 1 < 1 − 1 < ⋯ < 1 2.
400 401
402
(8)
If the th participant can owe R&D costs, then the other countries can also owe R&D costs. For R&D cost and efficiency, we provide the following proposition.
403
404
Proposition 1.
405
The agreement consisting of ≥ 4 countries with R&D costs is sustained by
406
advanced technology : + < if
24
<=
= − 2 − 1> and < . 2 2−
407
Proof. Let us confirm each signatory’s joiner’s gain when they owe R&D costs and
408
recover them. By investing in R&D, parameter in the abatement costs function,
409
410
411 412
413
; > : > . From Karp and Simon (2013), : − is = ⁄2 , changes to : ; − : = <, the cost to equal to − 2 − 1 when 6 = 78 . Assuming :
; is = − 2 − 1> + < . If 6 − 78 = = − 2 − change to : 1> + <, then the R&D costs are recovered and the kth joiner’s gain equals 0. ; = : + < is The R&D cost change from to :
= − 2 − 1> + < = < ⁄2.
(9)
414
From condition (8), we know that all signatories can invest in R&D if the above
415
equality is satisfied.
416 417
418
419
420 421
As shown in Figure 2, and as in Karp and Simon (2013), 78 is represented by
the area under the marginal cost curve between and 34 minus the area
represented by the rectangle with boundaries and 34 and height 1. 6 is the
area of the rectangle with boundaries 34 and and height minus the area under the marginal cost curve between 34 and . Rearranging (9) with E, we have
25
<= 422
In (10), < is positive if
= − 2 − 1> 2−
(10)
. ∎ 2
(11)
<
423
; = : + < = − 2 + = − 2 − 1>⁄ ⁄2 − . Therefore, we have :
424
425 426
; , the level of R&D Proposition 1 yields following results. To change to : expenditure is 2 = = − 2 − 1>⁄2 ⁄2 − . Additionally, we have the
427
technological innovation level to sustain number of participants . That is,
428
technological development levels are decided depending on the number of participants,
429
meaning that is an exogenous variable. The result provides an accurate level of the
430
R&D expenditure that is needed to yield a profitable agreement with advanced
431
technology consisting of countries. In other words, this result denotes that the
432
number of signatories in Stage 1 is decided depending on the amount that each country
433
can invest in R&D. Proposition 1 also shows that R&D efficiency, , must be below ⁄2. From Figure
434 435
2,
we
obtain
436
; = − 1 + − 2 + = − 2 − 1>⁄ ⁄2 − . = 34 + :
437
Therefore, introducing R&D costs promotes the development of reduction technology 26
438
and increases abatement levels by <, as shown in Figure 2. Additionally, for / ′ , we
439
have / H = IJ + ⁄ : + < if > − 1,
440
441
where : > and the y-intercept at 0, IJ , equals − 1 1 − ⁄ : + <
because 34 = − 1 and / H 34 = − 1 from Figure 2.
442
Insert Figure 2
443 444
445
4.2. The additional participation of non-investors
446
We examine the possibility that non-investors adopt the advanced technology. After
447
improving the abatement costs, for M = + 1, ⋯ , NOP, non-investor j can gain by
448
449
adopting the advanced technology if 6 M ≥ 78 M. For O ∈ ℝ( , we denote as NOP
the greatest integer weakly less than O and as QOR the smallest integer larger than O.
450
Therefore, QOR > O ≥ NOP > . Regarding the number of original and new
451
participants (investors and non-investors), the following proposition is obtained.
452
453
Proposition 2.
454
The number of participating countries,NOP, is sustained if there exists an O such that
27
O = 2 + S − 2 +
2= − 2 − 1> > . − 2
455
Proof. We seek the condition for 6 O = 78 O, where O ≥ NOP ≥ , under the
456
advanced abatement technology. In this case, non-investors have an incentive to adopt
457
the advanced technology. Therefore, we have O − 2 1 = − 2 − 1> = T − 2 + U. 2 2 2−
458
Rearranging (12) with regard to O, from ≥ 4 and − 1⁄2 > , we obtain O = 2 + S − 2 +
459
460
(12)
2= − 2 − 1> . − 2
(13)
Therefore, NOP countries, the greatest integer weakly less than the right-hand side of the condition (13), participate. ∎
461
462
Proposition 2 indicates the condition where no non-investors have an incentive to
463
adopt the advanced technology (i.e., additional participation). Even if non-investors
464
adopt the new technology, : + < , the abatement technology remains unchanged
465
466
467
468
because the members have already made the R&D investment.
From (13), we know that O ≥ . If O ≥ + 1 (or NOP > ), then there is room
for additional non-adopters to adopt the advanced technology whereas if + 1 ≥ O ≥ (or NOP = ), then there is no room for additional adoption.
28
469
470
We first look at the condition that O ≥ + 1. Let us confirm the condition
that O ≥ + 1:
2 + S − 2 +
471
2= − 2 − 1> ≥ + 1. − 2
(14)
Rearranging (14) with regard to , because k is an exogenous parameter, we obtain
472
≥ 2 − 3⁄2 − 2 . From ≥ 4 , we have ⁄2 > 2 − 3⁄2 − 2. From
473
Proposition 1, we obtain
2 − 3 ≥≥ . 2 2 − 2
(15)
474
If (15) is satisfied, then non-investors adopt the advanced technology as long as they
475
receive the joiner’s gain.
476
477
We have + 1 > O ≥ if
2 − 3 > > . 2 2 − 2
(16)
If (16) is satisfied, no non-investors adopt the advanced technology.
478
479
480
481
The number of investors in R&D is and the total number of countries that adopt
the advanced technology is NOP. The QORth country will not participate because 6 QOR − 78 QOR < 0.
482
From the condition in Proposition 2, we obtain the following results. After
483
improving the abatement costs, if O ≥ + 1 (or NOP > ), then non-investors have 29
484
an incentive to adopt the advanced technology as long as 6 M > 78 M for
485
non-investor j. From (1), we know that the original participants have no reason not to
486
refuse adopt the advanced abatement technology because their payoffs increase as
487
cooperators increase. Whether O ≥ + 1 or + 1 ≥ O ≥ depends on the
488
parameter values (see Proof of Proposition 2). If + 1 ≥ O ≥ (or NOP = ), then
489
no non-investors adopt the new technology; therefore only investors adopt the advanced
490
technology.
491
492
493
We seek the condition that )< ⁄) <0. From Proposition 1, the condition that
)< ⁄) <0 is
)< ⁄) = − 4 + 8 − 3 < 0.
Rearranging the inequality (17) with respect to , from ≥ 4, we have >
494
495
(17)
− 3 . 4 − 8
(18)
Thus, from (11) and (18), the R&D cost per country decreases as increases if − 3 >> . 4 − 8 2
(19)
In (19), from ≥ 4, we can easily obtain − 3⁄ 4 − 8 < ⁄2 . Thus, upon
496
condition (19), the R&D expenditure per signatory decreases as rises. Additionally,
497
non-investors have an incentive to participate because condition (15) is satisfied if
498
condition (19) is satisfied.
30
499
However, an unfair imbalance exists between investors and non-investors in terms
500
of R&D expenditure because non-investors adopt the technology innovation funded by
501
investors without having to pay any R&D costs. To address this problem, we consider
502
implementing a licensing fee, described below.
503
504
5. Full participation IEAs
505
5.1. Licensing fee
506
We aim to prevent non-investors from adopting the new advanced technology and force
507
non-investors to participate in Stage 1 rather than allowing non-investors to pay a
508
licensing fee to IEA members when they adopt the advanced technology developed
509
through the investment of countries. As shown in Section 4.2, for M = + 1, ⋯ , NOP,
510
non-investor j has an incentive to adopt the advanced technology to reduce emissions if
511
O ≥ M.
512 513 514
Non-investor M = + 1, ⋯ , NOP pays a licensing fee if they adopt the advanced
technology, after k countries fund R&D for the innovation. We set the licensing fee for j, WX , as
WX = 6 − 78X ,
515
(20)
where 6 denotes non-investor country j’s collective response and 78X denotes its
31
516
unilateral action. The subscript of 78X denotes that the size of unilateral action
517
increases as the number of joiners increases; the size of CR does not change if
518
non-investors participate because only R&D investment can change the size (see
519
Section 4.1). Additionally, (20) denotes that the levels of licensing fee vary by country,
520
depending on their joiner’s gain. Thus, for all M = + 1, ⋯ , NOP , country M
521
participates in agreement, even though the participant’s joiner gain is 0 when it pays a
522
licensing fee, because of our assumption in Section 3.1 that a country chooses to join if
523
it is indifferent about joining an IEA.
524
For example, we consider the Y th ( + 1 ≤ Y ≤ NOP) country’s joiner’s gain
525
function with advanced technology under two cases. In case (i), a country adopts the
526
advanced technology by paying licensing fee shown in (20), as the Yth member of NOP
527
members with no R&D expenditure, after the technology innovation has been
528
developed through R&D investment by the original participants (Proposition 2) in Stage
529
4. In case (ii), a country participates as the Yth member and invests in R&D in Stages 1
530
and 2. It is obvious that the joiner’s gain in case (i) is always less than or equal to that in
531
case (ii) because non-investors cannot obtain a joiner’s gain when they adopt the new
532
technology from (20).
533
Next, we see the effectiveness of the licensing fee shown in (20) for NOP countries’
32
534
choosing the case (ii). If the licensing fee is less than (20), the NOPth participant has an
535
incentive to choose case (i) when NOP < O because its joiner’s gain with R&D costs in
536
case (ii) is 0 and that in case (i) is greater than 0.
537
Finally, we note the possibility of additional participation by non-investors when
538
NOP countries participate in agreement and investment in R&D. In case (ii),
539
non-investors (NOP + 1th and later countries) may have an incentive to adopt the
540
advanced technology developed from NOP countries’ R&D. In this case, new
541
participants must also pay a licensing fee. Thus, the number of countries that participate
542
and invest in R&D is decided at the level of no additional participation (i.e., the
543
condition that + 1 ≥ O ≥ is satisfied or full participation). We discuss a state of
544
full participation below.
545
546
5.2. R&D efficiency for full participation
547
Herein, we describe the condition that minimizes the R&D costs per signatory if all
548
countries participate and invest in R&D. Under this condition, all countries choose to
549
participate in the IEA and invest in R&D in Stage 1 if non-investors must pay a
550
licensing fee to adopt the advanced technology, as described in Section 5.1.
551
From
≥4
and
condition
(19)
in
Section
4.2,
we
have
33
552
553
554
555
) − 3⁄ 4 − 8⁄) = − 3 − 1⁄4 − 2 , and ) ⁄2⁄) = 1⁄2. From − 3 − 1⁄4 − 2 < 1⁄2 , the range between the upper and lower
bounds of according to (depicted as a vertical line according to the number of countries in Figure 3) expands as increases. Moreover, the lower bound of
556
increases as increases. In other words, the condition of R&D efficiency becomes
557
relaxed as the number of signatories increases. In particular, we show that the value of
558
< is smallest if all countries participate in the range of − 3⁄ 4 − 8 < < ⁄2
559
from (19).
560
From Section 4.2, if + 1 ≥ O ≥ , then no non-investors adopt the new
561
technology and only investors adopt the advanced technology; if O ≥ + 1, then
562
non-investors have an incentive to adopt the new emissions abatement technology. In
563
the former case (i.e., + 1 ≥ O ≥ ), it is easier to achieve full participation rather
564
than any other participation level because an IEA with more participating countries
565
requires less R&D expenditure and lower R&D efficiency. In the latter case (i.e.,
566
O ≥ + 1), it is also easier to reach full participation than any other level of
567
participation if the licensing fee is set as in Section 5.1.
568
569
Insert Figure 3
34
570
In conclusion, a larger number of participants (countries that adopt the advanced
571
technology) can not only expand the range between the upper and lower bounds of the
572
levels of R&D efficiency , this can also decrease the lower bound of the level of R&D
573
efficiency. Surprisingly, the full participation and adoption states tend to occur as levels
574
of R&D efficiency decrease (i.e., levels of become larger) under condition (19) if the
575
licensing fee is set as in (20).
576
577
6. Results and Discussions
578
6.1. Sustainability of IEAs with R&D investment
579
In this section, we confirm whether our results answer the questions posed in Section 1.
580
From Section 4.1, a larger IEA consisting of more than four countries can be achieved
581
with recovery of each signatory’s R&D expenditure via abatement technology
582
innovation. We also revealed accurate R&D investment levels and the range of R&D
583
efficiency, as shown in Proposition 1. These results completely answer question 1 in
584
Section 1.
585
By applying the concept of a joiner’s gain function, the process of advanced
586
abatement technology diffusion after R&D investment is clarified, as shown in Section
587
4.1. Additionally, after R&D investment in abatement technology by the signatories, we
35
588
revealed that non-investors may have an incentive to adopt advanced abatement
589
technologies, as shown in Section 4.2. These results completely answer question 2 in
590
Section 1.
591
If countries can adopt advanced technologies without incurring R&D costs, there is
592
an unfair imbalance between investors and non-investors. To address this issue, we
593
considered a method to prevent adoption of new advanced technologies by
594
non-investors. We showed that it is better for non-investors to choose to participate and
595
invest in R&D from the beginning than to pay a licensing fee to adopt new technology
596
developed by other countries. The results obtained in Section 4.2 completely answer
597
question 3 in Section 1.
598
During the process of our analysis to answer the above questions, we obtained
599
several new and important results. In Section 5, we identified the condition under which
600
the R&D expenditure per signatory decreases as the number of signatories increases. In
601
addition, we revealed that the range between the upper and lower bounds of R&D
602
efficiency increases and the condition of R&D efficiency becomes relaxed as the
603
number of signatories increases. At these points, a full participation state can be more
604
easily sustained than any other number of participants.
605
36
606
6.2. Can a full-participation state with an increased abatement level be achieved
607
through a different approach?
608
This study showed that a state of full participation with increased abatement levels can
609
be achieved by considering cooperative R&D, R&D recovery, and a licensing fee.
610
Through our analysis, the following question is raised: which of our results is achieved
611
that cannot be obtained using a different approach? We discuss this below using the
612
approach of game theory.
613
Generally, as introduced in Asheim et al. (2006) and Hovi et al. (2015), two
614
theoretical models are used to analyze the formation of an IEA: a participation game
615
model or a compliance model. A compliance model is also called a repeated game
616
model. A compliance model assumes that the game is repeated infinitely and that
617
countries agree during the first period of the game (i.e., pre-play communication), which
618
must be enforced in subsequent periods under threat of punishment. In a compliance
619
game model, punishment denotes that some of the signatories to the IEA abandon their
620
abatement action because their abatement action is the provision of public goods.
621
In a compliance model, before the game begins, countries are assumed to enter into
622
an agreement that participants must enforce throughout the game using the punishment
623
(credible threats) prescribed in the strategy. This means that an agreement is enforced
37
624
using a strategy that specifies the countries’ behavior. That is, the compliance model
625
analyzes the conditions under which countries that are participating in an agreement will
626
meet their commitments as prescribed in the strategy.
627
The stability concept of the compliance model is referred to as a weakly
628
renegotiation-proof (WRP) equilibrium (Farrell and Maskin 1989, pp. 330–331), where
629
participants meet their commitments under a punishment clause. Most recent
630
compliance model literature ensures WRP equilibrium by considering a strategy based
631
on the “grim trigger” strategy, typically one that prescribes punishment for
632
noncompliance, as introduced in Hovi et al. (2015) and Takashima (2018). For example,
633
the “regional cooperative” strategy (Takashima, 2017b) and “regional penance” strategy
634
(Asheim et al., 2006) consider the formation of regional agreements. In the “getting
635
even” strategy (Barrett, 1999, 2003), only a limited number of participants is possible if
636
the agreement substantially improves social welfare. The “consensus treaty” (Barrett,
637
2002) achieves full participation in an IEA but where the abatement level of each
638
country is low.
639
Let us discuss whether full participation with an efficient abatement level is
640
achieved using a repeated game approach. The “penance-m” strategy, adopted by
641
Asheim and Holtsmark (2009), Froyn and Hovi (2008), and Takashima (2017a), reaches
38
642
the conclusion of IEA with full participation. That is, in terms of full participation, our
643
results can be obtained using a compliance model approach. However, to the author’s
644
best knowledge, our findings are the first to show that full participation is more easily
645
sustained than any other number of participants.
646
Additionally, there is a possibility that an IEA is not sustained if technological
647
innovation occurred in a compliance model. IEA investigations that use a repeated game
648
obtain conditions for WRP equilibrium as the number of punishing countries is decided
649
by lower and upper bounds of the number of punishing countries.
650
As explained above, in many studies of IEA with a compliance model, the number
651
of punishing countries is decided by the lower and upper bounds of the number of
652
punishing countries. Thus, the signatories cooperate in accordance with the strategy for
653
fear of the punishment decided before the agreement begins (or the first period of the
654
game). If the abatement cost function is changed by R&D investment in the middle of
655
the periods, these lower and upper bounds of number of punishing countries can be
656
changed. This means that the WRP condition can be broken and thus, the IEA can be
657
collapsed. If innovation in abatement technology is considered, the hopeful prospect for
658
full participation is not observed using existing compliance model approach. Our
39
659
discussion herein further strengthens the importance of considering the formation of
660
IEAs with R&D using the concept of joiner’s gain.
661
662
7. Conclusion
663
Below, we describe our core findings, policy implications, and upcoming studies.
664
665
7.1. Core findings
666
According to our findings, we reached the following conclusions.
667
A large size IEA consisting of more than four countries is sustainable with
668
cooperative investment in R&D and recovery of R&D expenditures.
669
By applying a joiner’s gain function and considering R&D for technological
670
innovation, we could achieve a large sized agreement including more than four
671
countries with increased abatement levels, as in Proposition 1. Karp and Simon (2013)
672
achieved a large IEA by innovation in abatement technology, but they did not consider
673
R&D costs. To address the problem of R&D cost, we considered a method to recover
674
R&D expenditure. Proposition 1 also indicates the condition of R&D efficiency. In this
675
proposition, accurate levels of R&D expenditure per country and condition of R&D
40
676
efficiency are obtained. We also showed that the R&D level and the R&D expenditure
677
level owed by each signatory are decided depending on the IEA size. These results were
678
not obtained in other previous studies such as Barrett (2006) and Hoel and de Zeew
679
(2010), Karp and Simon (2013).
680
The diffusion process of advanced technology is clarified.
681
As introduced in Section 2, the joiner’s gain function focuses on the order of
682
participation in agreement. This study revealed that the mechanism of joiner’s gain
683
clears the diffusion process of advanced abatement technology developed through the
684
effort of signatories’ R&D. This study is the first to clarify this process by applying a
685
joiner’s gain function. Diffusion will be stopped when the joiner’s gain of the country
686
that adopts a new advanced technology is zero. However, this result leads to the
687
possibility of adoption of advanced technologies by non-investors, as described in
688
Section 4.2.
689
690
Non-investor’s adoption of advanced technology is prevented if they must pay a licensing fee to adopt the advanced technology.
691
Proposition 2 reveals the possibility of additional participation by non-investors.
692
Countries have an inventive to participate in an IEA if they can gain by participating.
41
693
However, there is an unfair imbalance between investors and non-investors in terms of
694
R&D expenditure. As a solution to this issue, we considered the concept of a licensing
695
fee with a joiner’s gain function and adapted it in an IEA model. Applying the
696
mechanism of a joiner’s gain, we set a licensing fee for adopting the new technology;
697
the fee is set to equal each non-investors’ joiner’s gain (see condition (20), Section 5.1).
698
As a result, non-investors tend to have an incentive to participate in IEAs and invest in
699
R&D to avoid paying licensing fees to adopt advanced abatement technologies.
700
Full participation and adoption states may be more achievable than any other sized
701
agreement.
702
In Section 5, we revealed that a state of full adoption can be easily achieved. More
703
precisely, the R&D cost per country decreases and the condition of R&D efficiency for
704
full participation become relaxed with an increasing number of participating countries.
705
One might expect more efficient R&D investment to facilitate the diffusion of advanced
706
technologies; however, our results show that lower R&D efficiency tends to lead to all
707
countries participating in agreement and investing in R&D. Technological innovation
708
and licensing fees are key factors to achieving full participation in an IEA with R&D.
709
Overall, this result appears to indicate that prospects are good for global innovation and
42
710
diffusion of advanced technologies.
711
Lastly, we mention limitation of our approach. First, participants’ joiner’s gain
712
depends on their order of participation in agreement; participants can receive higher
713
levels of joiner’s gain if they participate at earlier orders. The participation order might
714
affect the success of such agreements. Our current approach using a joiner’s gain
715
function involves some uncertainty at this point. Second, our analysis is based on a case
716
of symmetric countries. When considering the case of asymmetric countries, our R&D
717
methods should be modified. We discuss the possibility of further analysis to address
718
these limitations in Section 7.3.
719 720
7.2. Policy implications
721
Based on the aforementioned core findings, we describe the following policy
722
implications. The UNFCCC describes that developing and transferring technologies to
723
support national action on climate change has been an essential element since the
724
beginning of the UNFCCC process.1
725
From our results, R&D cost per country can decrease as the number of participating
726
countries increases. Thus, a cooperative framework for technological innovation should 1
See the UNFCCC website (https://unfccc.int/topics/climate-technology/the-big-picture/what-is-technology-development-and-tr ansfer). 43
727
be discussed more in negotiations, such as the Paris Agreement, where broad
728
participation is achieved. Considering technological innovation in abatement
729
technologies, countries should invest in R&D cooperatively, not individually, via a
730
climate treaty. Our findings support that these activities should be conducted
731
cooperatively, in combination with climate change treaties.
732
Our results also indicate that licensing fees are needed to promote participation in
733
IEAs and investment in R&D by all countries. The countries participating in climate
734
treaties need to set fees for non-investors and non-participants in agreement who wish to
735
adopt the advanced technology. As described in Section 1, the UNFCCC emphasizes the
736
importance of technology transfer to support climate action. Our results suggest that a
737
technology transfer scheme with a licensing fee should be introduced in treaties.
738
However, in reality, countries can be divided into two types: developing (or less
739
developed) and developed countries. Thus, an application of our new R&D methods to
740
asymmetric countries’ case is interesting challenge that we leave for future research.
741
742
7.3 Upcoming studies
743
The directions for future research seem promising. First, we must consider the case in
744
which R&D efficiency increases as the number of countries that invest in R&D
44
745
increases, by applying the concept of returns to scale (Barret, 2006). Second, as
746
mentioned in Section 7.1, we must focus on the order of participation in an IEA because
747
this influences the level of joiner’s gain. A method to determine the order of
748
participation can further expand our analysis.
749
Third, as also mentioned in Sections 7.1 and 7.2, our analysis should be considered
750
in the case of asymmetric countries. Biancardi and Villani (2018) examine IEA
751
formation with R&D using a dynamic pollution abatement model in a world with two
752
asymmetric groups of symmetric countries: less developed and developed countries.
753
Considering the case of asymmetric countries and a participation game model, Barrett
754
(2001), Biancardi and Villani (2010), and Chou and Sylla (2008) used a monetary
755
transfer scheme to expand the IEA size. 2 McGinty (2007) considers transfers
756
implemented through a system of tradable pollution permits in a world with n
757
asymmetric countries. Our approach in the case of asymmetric countries can provide
758
further insights into climate change treaties with technological innovation, making it
759
possible to investigate the effects of technology transfer from developed to less
2
Chou and Sylla (2008) and Biancardi and Villani (2010), as well as Biancardi and Villani (2010), consider two types of countries: less developed and developed countries. Barrett (2001) implicitly assume less developed and developed countries in a world with two asymmetric groups of symmetric countries. 45
760
developed countries on IEAs and the link between other transfer and technology transfer
761
schemes.
762
Fourth, we must consider the case in which firms, not countries, invest in R&D for
763
innovation of emissions abatement technology, based on “environmental agreements”.
764
The concept of cooperative R&D efforts is also considered in domestic environmental
765
policies. For examples, Ouchida and Goto (2014, 2016) considered the R&D efficiency
766
in R&D expenditure at domestic firm level. For domestic policy that encourages firms
767
to engage in GHG abatement, an environmental agreement model should be considered.
768
Cabugueira (2001), Jiménez (2007), and Wakabayashi and Arimura (2016) assessed the
769
effectiveness of voluntary environmental agreements (VAs) on environmental protection.
770
Particularly, public voluntary programs, a type of VA, have characteristics similar to an
771
IEA model in that each player can decide whether to participate in agreement.3 Thus,
772
we can consider firms’ cooperative investment in technological innovation in terms of
773
local and global environmental cooperation by linking VAs and IEAs.
774
Lastly, Karimi and Nickpayam (2017) provided insight into a gamification approach
775
from the viewpoint of motivation.4 We must adopt gamification in IEAs, considering
3
VAs are classified into two categories: negotiated agreements and public voluntary programs. For details, see Wakabayashi and Arimura (2016). 4 As explained in Karimi and Nickpayam (2017), gamification is a strategy that uses game mechanics, techniques, and theory in areas that have not traditionally functioned like a game; gamification attempts to influence players’ actions by activating individual motives via game design 46
776
each country’s motivation in emissions abatement, such as rewards and reputation in
777
comparison to other countries, in cooperating with GHG emissions mitigation.
778
779
Acknowledgements
780
The author would like to thank the three anonymous reviewers for their helpful
781
comments and suggestions. The author is also grateful to Toshiyuki Fujita, Hiroshige
782
Tanaka, Tadahisa Ohno, Satoshi Honma, Yasunori Ouchida, and participants in the
783
2019 Spring Meeting of the Japan Association for Applied Economics for their
784
constructive comments. This research is partially supported by JSPS KAKENHI [grant
785
number JP19K13685].
786
787
References
788
Asheim, G.B., Froyn, C.B., Hovi, J., Menz, F.C., 2006. Regional versus global
789
cooperation for climate control. J. Environ. Econ. Manage. 51, 93–109. Doi:
790
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2005.04.004
791
792
Asheim, G.B., Holtsmark, B., 2009. Renegotiation-proof climate agreements with full participation: Conditions for Pareto-efficiency. Environ. Resour. Econ. 43, 519–533.
elements. 47
793
794
795
796
Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-008-9247-3 Barrett, S., 1994. Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 46, 878–894. Doi: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2663505 Barrett, S., 1997. The strategy of trade sanctions in international environmental
797
agreements.
798
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0928-7655(97)00016-X
799
800
801
802
803
804
Resour.
Energy
Econ.
19,
345–361.
Doi:
Barrett, S., 1999. A theory of full international cooperation. J. Theor. Politics. 11, 519– 541. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0951692899011004004 Barrett, S., 2001. International cooperation for sale. Eur. Econ. Rev. 45, 1835–1850. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00082-4 Barrett, S., 2002. Consensus treaties. J. Inst. and Theor. Econ. 158, 529–547. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1628/0932456022975169
805
Barrett, S., 2003. Environment and Statecraft. Oxford University Press, New York.
806
Barrett, S., 2006. Climate treaties and “breakthrough” technologies. Am. Econ. Rev. 96,
807
22–25. Doi: http://www.jstor.org/stable/30034607
808
Battaglia, M., Cerrini, N., Annesi, N., 2018. Can environmental agreements represent an
809
opportunity for green jobs? Evidence from two Italian experiences. J. Clean. Prod.
810
175, 257–266. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.12.086
48
811
Biancardi, M., Villani, G., 2010. International environmental agreements with
812
asymmetric
countries.
Comput.
Econ.
813
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10614-010-9197-z
36,
69–92.
Doi:
814
Biancardi, M., Villani, G., 2018. Sharing R&D investments in international
815
environmental agreements with asymmetric countries. Commun. Nonlinear. Sci.
816
Numer. Simulat. 58, 249–261. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cnsns.2017.06.034
817
Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., Masetti, E., Tavoni, M. 2008. International Energy R&D
818
spillovers and the economics of greenhouse gas atmospheric stabilization. Energy
819
Econ. 30, 2912–2929. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2008.04.008
820
Cabugueira, M.F.M., 2001. Voluntary Agreements as an environmental policy
821
instrument–evaluation
822
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0959-6526(00)00064-0
823
criteria.
J.
Clean.
Prod.
9,
121–133.
Doi:
Carraro, C., Siniscalco, D., 1993. Strategies for the international protection of
824
the environment.
J.
Public
Econ.
825
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(93)90037-T
52,
309–328.
Doi:
826
Carrascal Incera, A., Avelino, A.F.T., Franco Solís, A., 2017. Gray water and
827
environmental externalities: International patterns of water pollution through a
828
structural decomposition analysis. J. Clean. Prod. 165, 1174–1187. Doi:
49
829
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.07.200
830
Chou, P.B., Sylla, C., 2008. The formation of an international environmental agreement
831
as a two-stage exclusive cartel formation game with transferable utilities. Int.
832
Environ. Agreem. 8, 317–341. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10784-008-9082-6
833
El-Sayed, A., Rubio, S. J., 2014. Sharing R&D investments in cleaner technologies to
834
mitigate
835
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2014.07.003
836
837
climate
change.
Resour.
Energy
Econ.
38,
168–180.
Doi:
Farrell, J., Maskin, E., 1989. Renegotiation in repeated games. Game. Econ. Behav. 1, pp. 327–360. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0899-8256(89)90021-3
838
Finus, M., Rübbelke, D.T.G., 2013. Public good provision and ancillary benefits: The
839
case of climate agreements. Environ. Resour. Econ. 56, 211–226. Doi:
840
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-012-9570-6
841
842
Froyn, C.B., Hovi, J., 2008. A climate agreement with full participation. Econ. Lett. 99, 317–319. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2007.07.013
843
Fujita, T., 2013. A self-enforcing international environmental agreement on matching
844
rates: Can it bring about an efficient and equitable outcome? Strateg. Behav.
845
Environ. 3, 329–345. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1561/102.00000033
846
Hoel, M., de Zeeuw, A., 2010. Can a focus on breakthrough technologies improve the
50
847
performance of international environmental agreements? Environ. Resour. Econ. 47,
848
395–406. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-010-9384-3
849
Hovi, J., Ward, H., Grundig, F., 2015. Hope or despair? Formal models of climate
850
cooperation.
Environ.
Resour.
Econ.
851
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9799-3
62,
665–688.
Doi:
852
Jiménez, O., 2007. Voluntary agreements in environmental policy: an empirical
853
evaluation for the Chilean case. J. Clean. Prod. 15, 620–637. Doi:
854
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2005.11.025
855
Karimi, K., Nickpayam, J., 2017. Gamification from the viewpoint of motivational
856
theory. Ital. J. Sc. Eng. 1, 34–42. Doi: http://dx.doi.prg/10.28991/esj-2017-01114
857
Karp, L., Simon, L., 2013. Participation games and international environmental
858
agreements: A non-parametric model. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 65, 326–344. Doi:
859
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2012.09.002
860
Ma, M., Ma, X., Cai, W., Cai, W., 2019. Carbon-dioxide mitigation in the residential
861
building sector: A household scale-based assessment. Energy Convers. Manag.
862
Forthcoming. Doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enconman.2019.111915
863
864
McGinty, M., 2007. International environmental agreements among asymmetric nations. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 59, 45–62. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oep/gpl028
51
865
Ministry of the Environment, Government of Japan, 2017. Outline of long-term
866
low-carbon vision. https://www.env.go.jp/press/103822/713.pdf (accessed 8 July
867
2019).
868
Pash, H.S., Ebadi, T., Pourahmadi, A.A., Parhizkar, Y.R., 2017. Analysis of most
869
important indices in environmental impacts assessment of ports. Civ. Eng. J. 3,
870
868–880. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.28991/cej-030921
871
Ouchida, Y., Goto, D., 2014. Do emission subsidies reduce emission? In the context of
872
environmental
R&D
organization.
Econ.
873
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2013.10.009
Model.
36,
511–516.
Doi:
874
Ouchida, Y., Goto, D., 2016. Environmental research joint ventures and time-consistent
875
emission tax: Endogenous choice of R&D formation. Econ. Model. 55, 179–188.
876
Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2016.01.025
877
Qiao, H., Chen, S., Dong, X., Dong, K., 2019. Has China’s coal consumption actually
878
reached its peak? National and regional analysis considering cross-sectional
879
dependence
880
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2019.104509
881
882
and
heterogeneity.
Energy
Econ.
Forthcoming.
Doi:
Rubio, S.J., 2017. Sharing R&D investments in breakthrough technologies to control climate
change.
Oxf.
Econ.
Pap.
69,
496–521.
Doi:
52
883
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oep/gpw067
884
Sedghamiz, A., Heidarpour, M., Nikoo, M.R., Eslamian, S., 2018. A game theory
885
approach for conjunctive use optimization model based on virtual water concept.
886
Civ. Eng. J. 4, 1315–1325. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.28991/cej-0309175
887
Striebig, B., Smitts, E., Morton, S., 2019. Impact of transportation on carbon dioxide
888
emissions from locally vs. non-locally sourced food. Emerg. Sci. J. 3, 222–234.
889
Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.28991/esj-2019-01184
890
Takashima, N., 2017a. International environmental agreements with ancillary benefits:
891
Repeated
games
analysis.
Econ.
Model.
892
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2016.10.011
61,
312–320.
Doi:
893
Takashima, N., 2017b. The impact of accidental deviation by natural disaster-prone
894
countries on renegotiation-proof climate change agreements. Environ. Model.
895
Assess. 22, 345–361. Doi: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-016-9542-2
896
Takashima, N., 2018. International environmental agreements between asymmetric
897
countries: A repeated game analysis. Jpn. World Econ. 48, 38–44. Doi:
898
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.japwor.2018.08.001
899
900
UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change). 2016. Report of the Conference of the Parties on its twenty-first session, held in Paris from 30
53
901
November to 13 December 2015.
902
URL: http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2015/cop21/eng/10a01.pdf (accessed 9 July
903
2019).
904
UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change). 2017. TEC
905
Brief
906
URL:https://unfccc.int/ttclear/misc_/StaticFiles/gnwoerk_static/brief10/8c3ce94c2
907
0144fd5a8b0c06fefff6633/57440a5fa1244fd8b8cd13eb4413b4f6.pdf (accessed 5
908
October 2019).
909
10:
Technological
Innovation
for
the
Paris
Agreement.
van der Pol, T., Weikard, H.-P., van Ierland, E., 2012. Can altruism stabilise
910
international
climate
agreements?
Ecol.
Econ.
911
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.06.011
81,
112–120.
Doi:
912
Wahba, S. M., Kamel, B.A., Nassar, K.M., Abdelsalam, A.S., 2018. Effectiveness of
913
green roofs and green walls on energy consumption and indoor comfort in arid
914
climates. Civ. Eng. J. 4, 2284–2295. Doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.28991/cej-03091158
915
Wakabayashi, M., Arimura, T.H., 2016. Voluntary agreements to encourage proactive
916
firm action against change: an empirical study of industry associations’ voluntary
917
action
918
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.10.071
plans
in
Japan.
J.
Clean.
Prod.
112,
2885–2895.
Doi:
54
Tab. 1. Comparison of this study with other studies analyzing IEAs with R&D in a participation game model. Authors Barrett, 2006
Main features ・The required breakthrough level is that the costs function changes from quadratic to linear. ・The R&D phase precedes the coalition formation stage and technological innovation; all countries choose their R&D levels before the coalition is formed.
Karp and Simon, 2013
・A decomposition of the gains from participation, a joiner’s gain function, is introduced. ・ R&D costs of developing abatement technologies are not considered.
Hoel and de Zeeuw, 2010
・Compared with Barret (2006), an R&D phase follows coalition formation, in which abatement technologies depend on R&D investment levels. ・ Each country chooses its R&D investment level collectively (i.e., cooperatively) or individually (i.e., noncooperatively).
El-sayed and Rubio, 2014
・Countries decide on their investment levels so as to minimize agreement costs of controlling emissions.
Contributions
・IEAs with R&D and breakthrough technology perform better if the breakthrough level is sufficiently high and the breakthrough technology has increasing returns to scale.
・IEAs consisting of more than four countries are possible by lowering the slope of the marginal abatement costs function.
・Even without increasing returns to scale, the potential for a large agreement to be sustained with non-cooperative R&D is beneficial for all.
・The maximum participation in agreement with R&D consists of six countries.
controlling emissions. ・Signatories to the IEA pool their R&D efforts so as to fully internalize spillover effects. Rubio, 2017 ・Signatories not only coordinate their levels of R&D investment but also pool their R&D efforts, to fully internalize the spillovers of their investment. This paper
・The participation in agreement decreases as spillover effects increase until the minimum size of agreement (three countries) is reached. ・Full participation agreement is stable if marginal damages are large enough to justify development of a breakthrough technology that completely eliminates emissions, and if technology spillovers are not very large.
・A participation game with joiner's gain function ・The diffusion process of advanced is applied in IEAs with R&D. abatement technology is clarified. ・A new R&D method (cooperative R&D, recovery of R&D expenditure, licensing fee) is considered by applying a joiner's gain.
・A full participation state can be more easily sustained than any other number of participants by preventing non-investors' adoption of advanced technology.
Section 6.2 Section 1
Sections 3 and 4
Question 1: How should countries invest in R&D and how much R&D investment is needed to sustain IEAs in which many countries participate and invest in R&D without assuming non-cooperative R&D and excessively drastic (unrealistic) abatement
Stages of a game Stage 1: Individual countries choose
Methodology Cooperative investment in R&D
whether to join the coalition. Stage 2: If some countries accede to
Recovery of R&D investment
the agreement, signatories
technology innovation? Question 2:
Question 3:
What kind of process
Can we design IEAs that
can be used to diffuse
motivate non-investors
advanced abatement
to participate in
technologies?
agreements and invest in
choose R&D expenditure levels for developing abatement technologies. Stage 3: The coalition chooses whether to adopt the new technology.
R&D?
Applying joiner's gain function
Joiner's gain function Applying joiner's gain function
Non-investors individually
Section 6.1 Answer to Question 1 in Section 1
Answer to Question 2 in Section 1
Licensing fee
Results newly obtained in the process of answering the three questions in Section 1.
Section 7 Core findings
Answer to Question 3 in Section 1
Section 5 Stage 4:
Discussion of whether our results can be obtained using a different approach.
Policy implications
choose whether to adopt the advanced technology.
Section 2 Introduction of the concept of the participation game and joinerʼs gain function.
Fig. 1. Flowchart of this study.
Upcoming studies
K− K
E
M MC (q), IEA size k
~ C’(q)
C’(q)
k
CR(k)
1 k −1
k −2 UA(k)
1
0
qf
q ks −1
q sk
abatement level q
Fig. 2. The number of investors (participants), k, with kinked marginal costs and R&D investment.
Parameter of R&D efficiency α 100
α=k/2
80
α = (k2 −3) / (4k −8)
60
Area in which ∂E ⁄ ∂k < 0 is satisfied.
40
20
0
50
100
150
200
Fig.3. The number of countries that adopt advanced technology and R&D efficiency.
Number of signatories k
Cooperative
R&D
investments
and
licensing
breakthrough
technologies:
International environmental agreements with participation game Nobuyuki Takashima
Highlights
We examined international environmental agreements (IEAs) with cooperative R&D.
IEA signatories invest in R&D cooperatively to improve abatement technologies.
Investors’ R&D expenditure can be recovered via the advanced abatement technology.
Non-investors must pay a licensing fee to adopt the advanced technology.
Full participation IEAs can be more achievable than any other sized IEA.
1
Declaration of Interest Statement The author declares no conflicts of interest associated with this article.
Nobuyuki Takashima, Ph. D. Kyushu University Platform of Inter / Transdisciplinary Energy Research (Q-PIT) 744 Motooka, Nishi-ku, Fukuoka 819-0395, Japan Tel: +81-92-802-5501; Fax: +81-92-802-5501 E-mail:
[email protected]