G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/qref
Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions Tai-Hsin Huang a,∗ , Ming-Tai Chung b a b
Department of Money and Banking, National Chengchi University, Taiwan, R.O.C. Taiwan Academy of Banking and Finance, Taiwan, R.O.C.
a r t i c l e
i n f o
Article history: Received 13 January 2016 Received in revised form 5 September 2016 Accepted 26 September 2016 Available online xxx JEL classification: D24 G21 G28 Keywords: Technical efficiency Directional technology distance function Undesirable outputs Public banks Private banks Financial holding company
a b s t r a c t This paper aims to gain further insights into whether the First Financial Restructuring (FFR) policy improves the technical efficiency of Taiwan’s banks during the period 1999–2012, using the directional technology distance function (DDF). DDF simultaneously allows for the expansion of the desirables and the contraction of the undesirables, which is able to depict a bank’s true production activities. We find that the banks have a lower technical inefficiency with the preferred model compared to the other models. Before 2002, the technical inefficiency exhibits a gradual upward trend and then posts a downward trend during the FFR period, due to enhanced banking and benefits obtained from compliance with FFR. The inefficiency scores deteriorate sharply, during the “credit card and cash card crisis” in 2006 and “the subprime mortgage crisis” in 2008. Public and financial holding company (FHC) banks are respectively more efficient than private and non-FHC banks. © 2016 Board of Trustees of the University of Illinois. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction There has been increasing interest in the relationship between regulatory reforms and technical efficiency of the banking industry. To enhance the banking industry’s competitive viability and to restructure the financial system, Taiwan authorities launched a series of financial reforms, referred to as “First Financial Restructuring (henceforth, FFR)” from 2002 to 2003. The current study adopts the parametric stochastic frontier approach (SFA) in the context of the directional technology distance function (DDF) to examine the production efficiency of Taiwan’s banks. We then investigate whether the FFR policy does improve the technical efficiency of banks in Taiwan. In particular, we split the sample period into four sub-periods: pre-reform period (1999–2001), reforming period (2002–2003), post-reform period I (2004–2007), and postreform period II (2008–2012). In our research case, during the process of granting various loans to their customers, banks some-
∗ Corresponding author. E-mail addresses:
[email protected] (T.-H. Huang),
[email protected] (M.-T. Chung).
times experience loan defaults that result in non-performing loans (NPLs), which are a form of undesirable outputs. We include undesirable outputs in DDF to depict a bank’s true production activities along with environmental variables to account for the impacts from various macro- and micro-factors, as proposed by Battese and Coelli (1995). This allows one to estimate the shadow price of the nonmarketable bad output. For the purpose of comparison, we also estimate a stochastic DDF without environmental variables. To further highlight the role of the undesirable outputs in the application of the banks’ frontier model emphasized herein, we simultaneously subsume the estimation results of the stochastic DDF, which ignores the undesirable outputs as the comparison group. Moreover, the conventional stochastic input distance function is estimated with and without connecting a set of environmental variables with the inefficiency term. It is well-known that the standard input and output distance functions are unable to consider bad outputs. Consequently, their efficiency estimates may fail to reflect the real managerial abilities of bank managers. Desirable and undesirable outputs are jointly produced. The former are often marketable, but the latter are not, and their disposal is frequently subject to regulation. Thus, it is necessary to explicitly
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007 1062-9769/© 2016 Board of Trustees of the University of Illinois. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18 2
ARTICLE IN PRESS T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
model the effects of producing both forms of outputs. Since there are, in general, no markets for undesirables, their (shadow) prices must be estimated and contain valuable information. The estimation of DDF allows us to calculate the shadow price of undesirables. Färe, Grosskopf, Noh, and Weber (2005) are the first to use DDF to measure environmental efficiency and estimate the shadow price of the undesirable output. Fukuyama and Weber (2008) and Ke, Li, and Chiu (2011) employ the method of Färe et al. (2005) to estimate the shadow price of problem loans via a parametric DDF. This paper follows these previous works to examine the shadow price of NPLs using the stochastic DDF. About three decades ago, banks in Taiwan were rigorously regulated by the government with total assets of state-owned banks taking up more than three quarters of the entire banking industry. At the outset of the 1990s, Taiwan’s government took steps to privatize public banks and liberalize the financial market by allowing the new entry of private and foreign banks. As a result, the degree of competition in the industry largely intensified, which is expected to prompt the performance of domestic banks. These policies appear to have helped Taiwan’s banking sector successfully weather the Asian financial crisis in 1997–1998, but over-banking has caused excessive competition and lowered interest margins, such that the existing banks suffer from a low level of profits. Even worse, the quality of loans has deteriorated in order for the banks to seize and keep a larger market share. The aftermath of the Asian crisis saw soaring NPLs and declining capital adequacy ratios, hurting asset quality and profitability within the banking sector. Among them, high NPLs are thought to be the most serious problem, substantially reducing the liquidity of some banks and bringing them to the edge of insolvency. The major target of the FFR aims to write off the NPLs of financial institutions. Many important laws on regulating financial institutions were legislated and revised at the same time, which are designed to enhance the performance of commercial banks. The ratio of NPLs to total loans largely dropped after the enforcement of the “2-5-8 policy”.1 A bank is said to be technically efficient if it can produce maximum output from a given set of inputs (an output-oriented measure) or can employ a minimum input mix to manufacture the same output level (an input-oriented measure). SFA and the nonparametric data envelopment analysis (DEA) are two major frontier techniques suitable for measuring the efficiency and productivity change of firms. However, there is no consensus on the preferred method (Berger & Humphrey, 1997). Frontier efficiency is useful for financial institution managers and industry consultants to assess performance. Many researchers apply either SFA or DEA to study the effects of financial deregulation on the efficiency and productivity gains of banks and insurance firms, as well as the effects of mergers and acquisitions and capital regulations on banks’ profitability and performance. The results may provide valuable policy implications to regulatory analysis. A bank has to spend additional resources to disentangle itself from these NPLs. This lowers either its input-oriented efficiency score due to the fact that the extra input usage curtails the amount of undesirable NPLs, instead of raising quantities of desirable outputs, or cuts its output-oriented efficiency score since parts of input quantities are used toward the disposal of the undesirables. The implication is that the conventional radial measures of technical efficiency may not be able to reflect the true managerial abilities of banks due to the presence of undesirables that are not freely disposable. In other words, undesirable outputs are not allowed to be
1 The Taiwan government enacted the 2-5-8 policy, which requires all banks within 2 years to reduce their NPL ratio to be less than or equal to 5% and to maintain a capital adequacy ratio above 8%.
disposed of costlessly. “Cleaning up” these outputs requires a reallocation of inputs away from the production of desirable outputs. To date, the recently developed DDF appears to be the sole model that is useful to explicitly model the effects of producing both desirable and undesirable outputs, taking into account their characteristics and their interactions. Specifically, DDF allows one to measure a firm’s technical efficiency along with a given direction that measures how much quantities of outputs (desirables and/or undesirables) and inputs should be increased and decreased, respectively, to reach the efficient frontier. The Shephard’s (1953) input and output distance functions can be viewed as special cases of DDF. Dorfman and Koop (2005) point out that the undesirable output is one of the major issues in the field of the measurement of efficiency and productivity growth under the framework of multiple inputs and outputs. The first research utilizing DDF is attributed to Chambers, Chung, and Färe (1996) who generalize the model of Luenberger (1992, 1995) to a benefit function. DDF has three salient features. First, in contrast to Shephard’s (1953) output distance function that seeks to increase both desirable and undesirable outputs, DDF simultaneously allows for the expansion of the desirables and the contraction of the undesirables (and/or inputs). Second, DDF has an additive structure such that the efficiency indices of individual firms can be aggregated into the industry level. Third, when a functional form is required to be specified for DDF neither the dependent nor the explanatory variables have to be transformed by taking the natural logarithm, which avoids the calculation with respect to non-positive entries for some observations. So far, most empirical studies employ DEA, except for Feng and Serletis (2014) and Huang, Chiang, and Tsai (2015), to estimate efficiency in the context of DDF. See, for example, Färe, Grosskopf, and Hernandez-Sancho (2004), Färe et al. (2005), Färe, Grosskopf, and Weber (2006), Hsiao, Chang, Cianci, and Huang (2006), Koutsomanoli-Filippaki, Margaritis, and Staikouras (2009b), and Park and Weber (2006). DEA is function-free and hence is advantageous in that it does not suffer from the possible specification error on the production frontier. Nevertheless, the main shortcoming of DEA comes from its omission of the random disturbance, so that the resulting efficiency estimates tend to be confounded with noises (Berger & Humphrey, 1997; Das & Ghosh, 2006; O’Donnell & Coelli, 2005). Conversely, a particular functional form has to be specified to represent the production technology if SFA is employed. This approach is able to separate the effects of noises on estimated efficiency scores and, more importantly, environmental variables can be easily incorporated and linked with technical efficiencies. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the literature. Section 3 introduces the background of Taiwan’s banking industry. Section 4 specifies a parametric DDF to be estimated, and Section 5 describes the data set. Section 6 discusses the empirical findings, while the last section concludes the paper.
2. Literature review 2.1. Effects of regulation on banking efficiency Many researchers have investigated the nexus of deregulation and banking efficiency, but the results are mixed (Berger & Humphrey, 1997). Das and Ghosh (2006) find that medium-sized Indian public banks performed reasonably well and the efficiency scores of the banking sector are quite high during the period 1992–2002. Isik and Hassan (2003) conclude that the performances of all types of Turkish banks, with the exception of state-owned banks, have recorded significant improvements after deregulation,
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
ARTICLE IN PRESS T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
driven mainly by efficiency gains rather than technical progress. Sturm and Williams (2004) explore the effect of foreign bank entry on Australian bank efficiency during the post-reform period 1988–2001 and find an increase in technical efficiency after the financial reform. Hasan and Marton (2003) attain the same conclusion for Hungarian banks that experienced a similar deregulation process as in Australia. Some researchers contrarily claim that financial deregulation has uncertain effects on banks’ technical efficiencies, because the financial industries of different countries face heterogeneous environments that affect, e.g., market competition and the decision-making of bank managers. Specifically, deregulation in Spain has led to a negative impact upon savings banks’ efficiency (Grifell-Tatjé & Lovell, 1996), while Elyasiani and Mehdian (1995) conclude that banking efficiency in the United States is unchanged after the deregulation of the early 1980s. Halkos and Salamouris (2004) apply DEA to study the performance of Greek commercial banks and point out that the mean efficiency level fluctuates over time. Many other studies attain similar results to the above works, such as Fukuyama and Weber (2002) for Japanese banks and Fu and Heffernan (2009) for Chinese banks. Several investigators have applied DDF to measure efficiency and productivity in the banking industry. Park and Weber (2006) show that the efficiency score of Korean banks decreases from 1992 to 1998, rises in 1998 and 1999, and declines from 2000 to 2002. Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al. (2009a, 2009b) note that the bank efficiency and productivity of 10 Central and Eastern European countries rise in the period 1998–2003, using SFA and DEA, respectively. They argue that the highest proportion of profit inefficiency is attributed to allocative inefficiency and productivity change, driven by technological change. Hsiao et al. (2010) appear to be the first to apply DDF to explore the efficiency of Taiwan’s banking industry using DEA. They find that banks present a lower operating efficiency during the FFR reform period compared to the pre-reform period, but have a higher operating efficiency in the post-reform period. Koutsomanoli-Filippaki, Margaritis, and Staikouras (2012) present estimates of profit efficiency in the 25 European Union (EU) member states over the period 1998–2008. DDF has been employed to evaluate other industries than banking, such as airports (Yu, 2004), paper (Chung, Färe, & Grosskopf, 1997), electric utilities (Färe et al., 2005; Lee, Park, & Kim, 2002), and manufacturing (Zaim, 2004), as well as multiple industries (Watanabe & Tanaka, 2007). These articles are primarily concerned about the production process that transforms a range of inputs into several desirable outputs, together with polluting by-products. Because the disposal of these undesirables consumes resources, they should be explicitly considered in the model insofar as to correctly measure a firm’s performance. This is particularly important for heavily pollutant industries; or the resulting efficiency estimates are apt to be overestimated arising from the omission of undesirables. 2.2. The input- and output-oriented distance functions The distance function has been widely applied in the past literature of banking performance. Färe and Primont (1995) provide a detailed survey on the use of this function to estimate banking efficiency. English, Grosskoft, Hayes, and Yaisawarng (1993) employ the translog output distance function to calculate the output allocative and technical efficiencies of small U.S. banks in 1982 and find that these banks are output inefficient. Subsequently, several studies choose the deterministic output distance frontier to estimate technical efficiency. For instance, Iqbal, Ramaswamy, and Akhigbe (1999) show that minority-owned banks in the U.S. produce less output quantities than non-minority-owned banks, when they employ the same input mix. Kumbhakar and Wang (2007)
3
use the input distance function to examine the impact of financial deregulations on banking efficiency and total factor productivity change in China. The evidence exhibits that joint-equity banks are more efficient than wholly state-owned banks. Li, Hu, and Chiu (2004) employ a similar method to English et al. (1993) to estimate the technical efficiency of 43 Taiwan banks over the period 1997–1999. Their results support that public banks are more efficient than private banks and mixed ownership helps improve the technical efficiency of public banks. Li, Hu, and Liu (2009) apply the output distance function to examine the relationship between banks’ efficiency and non-performing loans in Taiwan. They argue that new banks consume almost twice as much resources to reduce the same amount of NPLs in comparison with old banks established before 1991. 2.3. Regulatory changes in Taiwan’s banking industry East Asian countries have achieved remarkable economic success in the 1980s and 1990s, as their governments undertook the major responsibility for the promotion of economic growth (Stiglitz, 1996). Starting from 1980 to 1990, Taiwan’s government implemented a series of financial modernization aiming at the removal of some restrictions on its financial market so as to strengthen the competition and efficiency of the market. The deregulation policies liberalized the settings of foreign exchange rates and interest rates, capital inflow and outflow, and the establishment of financial institutions (Chuang & Hölscher, 2008; Liu & Hsu, 2006; Yang, 2001). In 1991 there were 11 state-owned banks and 11 private banks—i.e., 50% of banks were owned by the government. New banks were not allowed to enter and the establishment of new branches by existing banks was also under government control. The lack of competition appeared to result in poor operations for the state-owned banks. That same year in 1991, the New Banking Law was passed and enacted. Sixteen new commercial banks were launched to compete with state-owned and original private banks in the period 1991–1993. In addition, the government permitted the transformation of a few investment and trust companies and a number of credit co-operative associations into commercial banks. The financial reform successfully enhanced the performance of Taiwan’s banks, which weathered the Asian financial crisis that erupted in mid-1997 and suffered smaller losses than other Asian countries (Liu & Hsu, 2006). The deregulation policy, however, caused a rapid increase in both the number of banks and bank branches, which intensified the degree of competition and largely lowered interest margins and profitability. The problem of “over-banking” curbs the operational scale of banks such that they are unable to reduce average costs by enjoying economies of scale and product diversification (scope economies). In addition, due to keen competition in the financial industry, local companies that may not earn profits find it easier to obtain loans from banks. Consequently, the ratio of non-performing loans (NPLs) to total loans for banks in Taiwan soared swiftly from 3.82% in 1997 to 4.88% in 1999 and reached a maximum value of 11.74% in March 2002. Taiwanese banks are facing harsh challenges from their rivals and from clients who fail to repay their loans. In order to solve the over-banking problem, the government of Taiwan passed “the Financial Institutions Merger Act” in December 2000 and “the Financial Holding Company Act” in July 2001.2 To
2 At the same time, the government passed the “Act for the Establishment and Administration of the Financial Restructuring Fund”, “Act Governing Bills Finance Business”, and “Value-added and Non-value-added Business Tax Act” and revised the “Deposit Insurance Act” and “Insurance Act”. See, for example, Chuang and Hölscher (2008) and Yeh (2005).
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
4
shrink the amounts of NPLs, the authorities revised the Business Tax Act to reduce the business tax rate from 5% to 2%. Banks can use this tax cut to write off their NPLs. The government also established a financial restructuring fund in July 2001 for the purpose of integrating and stabilizing the financial market. As a result, the overall ratio of NPLs fell from 8.85% at the end of 2002 to 2.24% at the end of 2005. 3. Methodologies 3.1. The DDF and the shadow prices of undesirables N denote an N-vector of inputs employed Let x = (x1 , ..., xN ) ∈ R+ M by a bank to jointly produce desirable outputs y = (y1 , ..., yM ) ∈ R+ I . We define the techand undesirable outputs b = (b1 , ..., bI ) ∈ R+ nology as:
T (x, y, b) =
P(x) =
u = z + W ≥ 0.
(3)
Here, W is assumed to be a normal random variable with mean zero and constant variance u2 , is a vector of unknown coefficients to be estimated, and z is a vector of environmental variables that affect banks’ efficiency. The estimated coefficients of Eq. (2) can then be used to calculate the shadow prices of undesirables using formula (A10) in Appendix A. 3.2. The input distance function To highlight the importance of undesirables on examining banks’ performance, we alternatively estimate the translog input distance function with M outputs and J inputs. After imposing symmetry and homogeneity restrictions, the following translog input distance function is estimated:
(x, y, b) : x can producey and b
and the output set can be expressed as:
See Appendix A for detailed derivation of Eq. (2). Following Battese and Coelli (1995), the inefficiency term of u can be related to a set of exogenous variables as:
(y, b) : x can produce y and b .
We define the directional technology distance function as3 :
T (x, y, b; gx , gy , g ) = sup ˇ : (x − ˇgx , y + ˇgy , b − ˇg ) ∈ T , D b b
−ln x3 = a0 +
J−1
aj ln xj /x3
N, g ∈ where the directional vector is g = (gx , gy , gb ) with gx ∈ R+ y M , and g ∈ RI . If g = 0, then DDF reduces to the directional outR+ x b + put distance function, whereas DDF reduces to the directional input distance function, provided gy = 0. Following Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al. (2009a), we specify g = (gx , gy , gb ) = (1, 1, 1), which implies that the bank under study should simultaneously decrease inputs and undesirable outputs by ˇ ≥ 0 units and increase desirable outputs by ˇ ≥ 0 units along with the specified direction g. Therefore, ˇ measures the gap between the efficient frontier and the bank’s actual production level and reflects the bank’s technical inefficiency. The larger the value of ˇ is, the less efficient the bank is. A value of ˇ = 0 means that the bank is already producing on the production frontier. To empirically gauge technical (in)efficiency under the framework of the stochastic frontier approach, we choose to estimate the quadratic directional distance function as follow4 :
−x3 = ˛0 +
N−1
˛n (xn − x3 ) +
n=1 N−1 N−1 1
+
2
1 2
I I
+
n=1
m=1
(xn −
x3 ) (xn
− x3 ) +
ii (bi − x3 ) (bi − x3 ) +
M M 1
2
M N−1
n=1
ni (bi − x3 ) (xn − x3 ) +
nt n=1
(xn − x3 ) +
M
m=1 l=1
j=1 k=1 J−1 M
+
M
cjm ln xj /x3 ln ym + j0 t
j=1 m=1
1 jt t ln xj /x3 + mt t ln (ym ) + V − U + j00 t 2 + 2 J−1
M
j=1
m=1
(4)
which is illustrated by Appendix A. Here, U is a truncated normal random variable,5 reflecting technical inefficiency of a bank and it is independent of the disturbance term of V. Following Battese and Coelli (1995), we specify the inefficiency term is as: U = z + W ≥ 0,
0, U2
(5)
, is a vector of unknown parameters to be where estimated, and z is a vector of environmental variables.
i (bi − x3 )
4. Data description ˇmm
(ym +
x3 ) (ym
+ x3 )
M
I
m=1
i=1
M
m=1
mn (ym + x3 ) (xn − x3 )
m=1
i=1 N−1
++
W ∼N +
m=1 m =1
I
1 + ı2 t 2 + 2
I
1 1 ajk ln xj /x3 ln xk /x3 + bml ln ym ln yl 2 2 J−1 J−1
i=1
i =1
i=1 N−1
ˇm (ym + x3 ) +
n =1
n=1
+
˛nn
M
bm ln ym
m=1
j=1
(1)
M
mi (bi − x3 ) (ym + x3 ) + ı1 t
m t (ym + x3 ) +
I
i t (bi − x3 ) + v − u. (2)
i=1
3 Chambers, Chung, and Färe (1996) and Färe and Grosskopf (2004) give a thorough discussion on the properties of the directional technology distance function. 4 Chambers (2002) suggests using this functional form, followed by Färe et al. (2005), Fukuyama and Weber (2008), Feng and Serletis (2014), Huang et al. (2015), and Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al. (2009a).
4.1. Input and output variables We compile a total of 52 commercial banks in Taiwan spanning 1999–2012, before the enforcement of IFRS, based on the Taiwan Economic Journal database and Financial Institutions Major Business Statistics. The resulting unbalanced panel data contain 589 bank-year observations. We identify three inputs, three outputs, and an undesirable according to the intermediation approach that views banks as financial intermediaries employing labor, capital, and deposits (borrowed funds) to produce loans, other earning assets (investments), and non-interest revenue. Input borrowed funds (x1 ) include various deposits and borrowed money, capital (x2 ) is defined as the value of net fixed assets, and labor (x3 ) is defined as the number of full-time equivalent employees. The three
5 This paper also estimates the specification of Uit = Ui exp [− (t − T )] for the ith bank in period t, as proposed by Battese and Coelli (1992).
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
5
Table 1 Variable definitions and descriptive statistics. Variables
Definitions
Mean
Standard deviation
Inputs Borrowed funds (x1 ) Physical capital (x2 ) Labor (x3 )
Total deposits, money market funding and other funding (million NTD) Fixed assets minus accumulated depreciation (million NTD) Number of full-time equivalent employees
536,244.82 11,567.88 3042.95
594,308.96 15,147.36 2351.76
Desirable outputs Investments (y1 ) Loans (y2 ) Non-interest revenues (y3 )
Total of other earning assets minus deposits with banks (million NTD) Total loans plus deposits with banks (million NTD) Fee income plus commission income (million NTD)
110,224.08 409,099.65 2704.73
149,784.48 454,003.29 3623.01
Undesirable outputs Non-performing loans (b1 )
Non-performing loans (million NTD)
11,028.86
16,224.98
Environmental variables Real GDP per capita (z1 ) Population density (z2 )
Ratio of GDP to the number of inhabitants (million NTD) Ratio of inhabitants per square kilometer (person/km2 )
0.55 629.73
0.04 10.33
Bank-specific factors Deposits per branch (z3 ) Average return on equity (z4 ) Herfindahl-Hirschman index (z5 )
Total deposits to the number of branches (million NTD) Average return over equity (%) Herfindahl–Hirschman index of total assets
6236.97 4.64 504.38
722.35 4.67 41.17
Note: All dollar-valued variables have been deflated by the consumer price index with base year 2011.
desirable outputs are investments (y1 ), composed of government and corporate securities, the sum of short- and long-term loans (y2 ), and non-interest revenues (y3 ), comprising services charges on loans, transactions, and income from renting and fiduciary activities, and commissions. Moreover, we classify non-performing loans (b) as the single undesirable output that is a by-product of various forms of loans granted by the bank to its customers. All of the above variables, except for labor, are measured in terms of millions of New Taiwan dollars (NTD) and are deflated by the GDP deflator of Taiwan with the base year of 2011. 4.2. Environmental variables Following Allen and Rai (1996), Dietsch and Lozano-Vivas (2000), Huang, Shen, Chen, and Tseng (2011), Lozano-Vivas, Pastor, and Hasan (2001), and Lozano-Vivas, Pastor, and Pastor (2002), this study identifies macroeconomic variables, regulatory conditions, as well as the availability of bank services as environmental variables that affect banks’ efficiency. Specifically, we associate five environmental variables with the inefficiency term as follows. 4.2.1. Real GDP per capita (IC) Ratio of Taiwan’s real GDP to its population. This macroeconomic variable serves as an indicator of overall economic conditions, influencing deposits, loans, and off-balance activities. Therefore, it may contribute to an increase or decrease in bank efficiency. A higher IC value shows that banks are facing a favorable atmosphere, because the demand for banks’ services and supply of loanable funds are increasing, prompting interest and profit margins of the banks and managerial efficiencies as well. Conversely, banks in countries with higher IC usually face fiercer competition in charging interest rates and profit margins, which incur higher operating costs and lower efficiency. Thus, the expected sign of IC on efficiency is ambiguous. 4.2.2. Population density (PD) Inhabitants per square kilometer. Lozano-Vivas et al. (2001, 2002) assume that a higher PD value tends to lower banks’ operating costs, prompting a bank’s efficiency. 4.2.3. Deposits per branch (DB) Ratio of total amounts of deposits to the number of branches. The expected sign of DB on efficiency is mixed. Lozano-Vivas et al. (2001, 2002) assume that a higher DB implies higher banking effi-
ciency levels. However, a higher DB level tends to lower a bank’s profit due to higher interest expenditures and/or lower interest rate spreads, which in turn reduce technical efficiency. For example, Rojas-Suarez (2001) argues that low spreads in developing countries may signal risky institutions.
4.2.4. Average return on equity (ROE) This variable is calculated across all sample banks for each year, which exhibits the profitability of the entire banking industry in that year, arising possibly from higher technical efficiency. Therefore, this indicator is expected to be positively correlated with banks’ efficiencies.
4.2.5. Herfindahl–Hirschman index (HHI) This standard HHI reflects the degrees of market competition and is calculated with respect to total assets. It can have either a positive or negative effect on technical efficiency. If market concentration reflects consolidation through the survival of more efficient banks and markets remain contestable, then market concentration should be associated with higher efficiency (Fries & Taci, 2005; Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al., 2009a). Conversely, if market concentration reflects market power for some banks, then it may increase the costs of the sector due to slack and inefficiency. The negative relationship between market power and efficiency is known as the “quiet life” hypothesis.6 In sum, variables IC, DB, and HHI exert ambiguous effects on banks’ efficiency, while positive effects are expected for the remaining variables of PD and ROE. Table 1 provides variable definitions and their descriptive statistics. Since most of these variables have relatively large standard deviations, the scale of sample banks differs substantially.
6 Hicks (1935) first stressed the “quiet life” hypothesis, and it means that firms with higher market power put less effort at pursuing cost efficiency. The evidence of some empirical studies provides support for this hypothesis, e.g., Berger and Hannan (1997, 1998), whereas some studies are contrary to those of Berger and Hannan’s, e.g., Fu and Heffernan (2009) and Maudos and de Guevara (2007).
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
6
Table 2 Parameter estimates with undesirable outputs. Variable
Parameter
Model I
Model II Coefficient
t-ratio
Intercept x1 x2 x3 x12 x22 x32 x1 x2 x1 x3 x2 x3
˛0 ˛1 ˛2 ˛3 ˛11 ˛22 ˛33 ˛12 ˛13 ˛23
−44.909 −0.004*** −0.007 – 0.006*** 7.7E − 05 – −0.303*** – –
−0.477 −3.650 −0.489 – 4.356 0.065 – −11.676 – –
391.693*** −0.004*** −4.7E − 04 – 0.006*** −9.7E − 05 – −0.312*** – –
4.729 −4.639 −0.038 – 4.823 −0.109 – −14.528 – –
Desirable outputs
y1 y2 y3 y12 y22 y32 y1 y2 y1 y3 y2 y3
ˇ1 ˇ2 ˇ3 ˇ11 ˇ22 ˇ33 ˇ12 ˇ13 ˇ23
−0.009 1.4E − 08*** −3.0E − 08 5.2E − 07 −2.3E − 10 1.6E − 08*** −2.7E − 08 2.0E − 08*** −1.5E − 07*
−1.396 3.972 −0.755 0.833 −0.029 3.544 −0.344 5.536 −1.881
−0.010* 7.6E − 09*** 3.3E − 08 −1.5E − 07 8.4E − 09 1.9E − 08*** −1.6E − 07*** 1.2E − 08*** −2.8E − 07***
−1.799 3.156 1.148 −0.340 1.479 6.132 −2.772 4.924 −5.034
Undesirable output
b1 b21
1 11
1.8E − 05*** −1.0E − 07
7.396 −0.692
1.5E − 05*** −1.5E − 07
9.114 −1.308
Inputs–outputs
y1 x1 y1 x2 y1 x3 y2 x1 y2 x2 y2 x3 y3 x1 y3 x2 y3 x3 b1 x1 b1 x2 b1 x3 b1 y1 b1 y2 b1 y3
11 12 13 21 22 23 31 32 33 11 12 13 11 12 13
−1.3E − 08*** 5.9E − 08* – −1.6E − 08*** 4.3E − 08 – 1.2E − 07 −2.1E − 06* – 2.6E − 08 2.8E − 07 – −1.3E − 07*** −1.9E − 08 −2.4E − 08
−2.756 1.835 – −4.798 1.244 – 1.488 −1.653 – 0.969 1.141 – −3.454 −0.631 −0.026
−1.6E − 08*** 4.8E − 08*** – −9.1E − 09*** −2.4E − 08 – 2.8E − 07*** −3.6E − 06*** – −1.8E − 09 6.3E − 08 – −6.5E − 08*** −3.9E − 09 3.6E − 06***
−4.997 2.140 – −4.030 −0.963 – 4.856 −3.836 – −0.095 0.324 – −2.396 −0.189 4.100
Technical change
t t2 tx1 tx2 tx3 ty1 ty2 ty3 tb1
ı1 ı2
1 2 3 1
−45.588* 7.890** 3.3E − 04*** −0.003** – −2.1E − 04 −2.1E − 04 −0.015*** 0.003***
−1.699 2.053 2.477 −2.044 – −1.549 −1.534 −4.681 2.973
−100.244*** 11.535*** 1.7E − 04* −0.001 – −1.5E − 04 −8.2E − 05 −0.009*** 0.002***
−5.493 4.761 1.719 −0.882 – −1.531 −0.847 −4.015 2.474
Constant IC PD DB ROE HHI
z0 z1 z2 z3 z4 z5
4.186*** 21.499*** −9.606*** 0.437 −66.127* 5.895
2.825 2.771 −3.296 0.687 −1.938 0.682
2
200,000.050*** 0.228***
1,314,726.200 3.873
100,226.080*** 0.286*** 0.076***
255.766 8.499 7.381
Inputs
Zs
Other ML parameters
1 2 3
Coefficient
t-ratio
Number of observations Log-likelihood function * ** ***
589 −4365.048
589 −4270.939
Denotes significance at the 10% level. Denotes significance at the 5% level. Denotes significance at the 1% level.
5. Empirical results 5.1. Efficiency estimates We estimate the quadratic form of DDF that includes the undesirable output, under the framework of Battese and Coelli (1992, 1995), respectively. The former is referred to as Model I and the
latter as Model II. Models III and IV are similar to the first two models, but exclude the undesirable output from DDF. Using Frontier 4.1 software (Coelli, 1996), we estimate (6) and (15). Table 2 presents the parameter estimates of the stochastic DDF of (6). More than one half of the parameter estimates attain statistical significance at least at the 10% level.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
ARTICLE IN PRESS T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
The coefficient of the variable IC has a positive sign, implying that a large IC deteriorates banking efficiency. This may be attributed to the fact that the more developed the economy is, the higher the operating and financial costs banks incur when supplying a given level of services (Dietsch & Lozano-Vivas, 2000). The variable of population density (PD) is found to be significantly and negatively correlated with technical inefficiency, which is consistent with Lozano-Vivas et al. (2001, 2002). Deposits per branch (DB) have a positive effect on technical inefficiency. A higher amount of deposits per branch reduces banking efficiency, due possibly to the substantial decrease in the interest rate spreads in Taiwan during the sample period. The net interest margin in Taiwan is quite stable and ranges from 2.90% in 1997 to 2.99% in 2000. It reaches a maximum value of 3.15% in 2002, but then descends swiftly to 1.23% in 2009. ROE is significantly and negatively correlated with the inefficiency term, implying that higher profitability causes higher efficiency. Moreover, HHI is positively associated with inefficiency, suggesting that banks in a more concentrated market are operating less efficiently, which supports the quiet life hypothesis. The evidence is not consistent with Fu and Heffernan (2009) and Maudos and de Guevara (2007), who claim that an increase in the degree of market concentration leads to market selection and consolidation through the survival of the most efficient financial institutions. However, this finding is consistent with Berger and Hannan (1997, 1998). Table B1 in Appendix B presents coefficient estimates of Models III and IV. Two-thirds of the parameter estimates are significant, and the signs of the environmental variables in Model III are the same as those in Model I. Table 3 presents technical inefficiency scores for each sample T (x, y, b; 1, 1, 1) is equal to year. The estimated mean value of D 70.91 in Model I. Given our directional vector g = (1, 1, 1), this mean inefficiency value indicates that desirable outputs should be expanded by 70.91 units (measured by number of employees), while inputs and the undesirable output should be contracted by 70.91 units, if the representative bank operates efficiently. It is apparent that the average inefficiency estimates of Models I and II are lower than those of Models III and IV, respectively, implying that the exclusion of economic bad outputs from DDF tends to overestimate the inefficiency scores. In addition, the average inefficiency measure of Model I is less than that of Model II, implying that the omission of environmental variables is apt to exaggerate managerial inefficiency. The foregoing reflects the importance of including both undesirables and the environment in DDF. Fig. 1 draws those average inefficiency measures for the four models. Models I and III show that the average technical inefficiency peaks in 2002, 2006, and 2009. The ratio of NPLs to total loans of Taiwan’s banking sector rose from 0.93% in 1990 to 7.48% in 2001, due to the domestic financial crisis in 1999 and the dot-com bubble in 2001. To boost the performance of banks, Taiwan’s authorities launched “FFR” from 2002 to 2003, which appears to help reduce the inefficiency measure from 2003 to 2005. During 2005–2006, a number of private banks encountered serious bad debts due to the over-issuance of credit cards and cash cards to unqualified people. This eroded those banks’ profits and deteriorated efficiency. The increase in inefficiency level from 2007 to 2009 reflects the subprime mortgage crisis.7 Models II and IV reveal that average technical inefficiencies are decreasing over time, while Models I and III show reverse trends. In 2006, the average inefficiency scores of Models II and IV peaked at 318.65 and 481.11, respectively. FFR (2002–2003) appears to have
7 These banks are almost all private, medium, or large and FHC banks (e.g., Taishin and Chinatrust).
7
Table 3 Average inefficiency scores by year. Year
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 1999–2012
With undesirable outputs
Without undesirable outputs
Model I
Model II
Model III
Model IV
40.39 39.70 39.36 85.35 44.83 30.85 42.51 101.14 98.16 138.95 154.46 80.93 81.65 69.96 70.91
565.96 457.90 411.68 352.35 339.18 293.42 302.70 318.65 261.34 232.14 202.20 157.14 158.44 153.54 315.86
164.44 157.88 151.39 214.98 175.75 145.76 194.44 291.45 270.90 295.26 320.77 268.78 290.71 281.13 221.75
520.98 433.78 409.26 381.87 402.16 370.82 426.68 481.11 417.42 388.11 352.67 294.37 318.71 318.72 399.13
a beneficiary effect on technical efficiency in the short run, except for Model IV. 5.2. The input distance function To highlight the advantage of DDF, we estimate the conventional input distance frontier of (13) with the results shown in Table 4.8 Most of the coefficient estimates are accurately estimated. As far as the environmental variables are concerned, the signs of variables IC, PD, DB, and HHI differ from those of DDF, and the coefficient of DB is found to be insignificant. The effect of ROE on technical inefficiency is significantly negative, which is consistent with Cavallo and Rossi (2002) for German and Italian banks. This suggests that in these countries higher profitability improves efficiency. These figures indicate two empirical implications. One is associated with the model specification. In contrast to the conventional output distance function that seeks to increase both desirable and undesirable outputs (if any), DDF simultaneously allows for the expansion of the desirables and the contraction of the undesirables. The other one is that the omission of an important explanatory variable, i.e., the undesirable output, may bias the parameter estimates (Chen, 2012). The overall average values of technical efficiency for Models V and VI are equal to 0.9034 and 0.8461, respectively, and the annual average efficiency scores are reported in Table 5. These two models give somewhat close mean efficiency measures, as opposed to the DDF Models I and II. To be fully efficient, sample banks are suggested to reduce 10.69% and 18.19% of their current input mix. Similar to Hsiao et al. (2010), the mean efficiency value of Model V during the pre-reform period is equal to 0.9033, worsens to 0.8771 during the reform period, and improves to 0.9064 and 0.9151 during the post-reform periods I and II, respectively. Fig. 2 draws the annual average technical efficiency scores for Models V and VI. The average efficiency scores of Model V oscillate in a wide scope between 0.8614 in 2001 and 0.9428 in 2007 over the transition period without a clear trend. Conversely, the efficiency scores of Model VI show a gradually increasing trend. Since estimates in Tables 3 and 5 are not directly comparable, we transform the average inefficiency scores implied by Table 5 into the same units as in Table 3, i.e., the number of employees.9 Table 6
8 We also estimate the output distance frontier, but the results are not shown due to their similarity to the input distance frontier. 9 Battese et al. (2000) and Kumbhakar et al. (2002) adopt a translog stochastic frontier labor-use model to estimate the labor-use requirements. They find that the technical inefficiencies of labor use in Swedish banks are apparent, and the overall mean inefficiency is estimated to be about 12–16%.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
8
Model I
Model II
Model III
Model IV
600 500 400 300 200 100 0 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Fig. 1. Average inefficiency estimates over time.
Table 4 Stochastic input distance function estimations. Variable
Parameter
Coefficient
t-ratio
Coefficient
t-ratio
Intercept ln x˜ 1 ln x˜ 2 2 (ln x˜ 1 ) 2 (ln x˜ 2 ) (ln x˜ 1 ) × (ln x˜ 2 )
a0 a1 a2 a11 a22 a12
−4.473*** 0.181 −0.451* 1.221*** −0.654*** −0.589***
−3.861 0.549 −1.655 9.702 −2.672 −3.413
−10.962*** −1.232*** −0.022 0.150 1.847*** −0.581***
−11.274 −4.368 −0.101 1.536 8.378 −4.204
Outputs
ln y1 ln y2 ln y3 2 (ln y1 ) 2 (ln y2 ) 2 (ln y3 ) (ln y1 ) (ln y2 ) (ln y1 ) (ln y3 ) (ln y2 ) (ln y3 )
b1 b2 b3 b11 b22 b33 b12 b13 b23
0.335*** 0.057 −0.144*** 0.141*** −0.118*** −0.005 −0.096*** 0.153*** −0.115***
5.933 1.043 −2.831 10.028 −5.013 −0.410 −2.536 5.600 −5.712
0.170*** −0.005 −0.068* −0.012 0.050*** −0.004 −0.434*** 0.118*** −0.060***
4.284 −0.119 −1.837 −1.226 2.826 −0.525 −12.501 5.858 −3.947
Inputs–outputs
(ln (ln (ln (ln (ln (ln
x˜ 1 ) (ln x˜ 1 ) (ln x˜ 1 ) (ln x˜ 2 ) (ln x˜ 2 ) (ln x˜ 2 ) (ln
c11 c12 c13 c21 c22 c23
−0.247*** 0.189*** −0.077** 0.007 0.036 −0.028
−8.519 4.058 −2.037 0.314 1.060 −1.171
−0.141*** 0.263*** −0.073*** 0.023 0.011 −0.037***
−6.708 6.640 −2.621 1.614 0.421 −2.228
Technical change
t t2 (ln (ln (ln (ln (ln
x˜ 1 ) t x˜ 2 ) t y1 ) t y2 ) t y3 ) t
j0 j00 1 2 1 2 3
−0.128*** 3.3E − 04 −0.009 −0.004 −0.004* 0.025*** −0.014***
−4.275 0.335 −1.241 −1.007 −1.897 5.713 −4.964
−0.115*** 0.003*** −0.004 0.005 2.0E − 04 0.013*** −0.009***
−5.609 3.545 −0.791 1.531 0.107 4.179 −4.512
Constant IC PD DB ROE HHI
z0 z1 z2 z3 z4 z5
−98.021*** −38.232*** 0.209*** −1.4E − 04 −0.034*** −0.028***
−3.757 −3.349 3.685 −0.915 −3.173 −2.992
2
0.298*** 0.951***
4.608 83.931
0.038*** 0.788*** 0.013***
23.159 81.749 2.253
Inputs
Zs
Other ML parameters
Number of observations Log-likelihood function * ** ***
y1 ) y2 ) y3 ) y1 ) y2 ) y3 )
Model V
588 250.757
Model VI
588 411.450
Denotes significance at the 10% level. Denotes significance at the 5% level. Denotes significance at the 1% level.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
9
Fig. 2. Average technical efficiency in Models V and VI.
Table 5 Average technical efficiency estimates by year. Year
Model V
Model VI
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) FFR period (2002–2003) Post-FFR period I (2004–2007) Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Whole period (1999–2012)
0.9259 0.9239 0.8614 0.8650 0.8901 0.8939 0.8804 0.9158 0.9428 0.9167 0.9010 0.9292 0.9167 0.9118 0.9033 0.8771 0.9064 0.9151 0.9034
0.8294 0.8330 0.8346 0.8351 0.8421 0.8484 0.8480 0.8467 0.8530 0.8547 0.8581 0.8598 0.8614 0.8630 0.8324 0.8385 0.8489 0.8594 0.8461
Table 6 Average technical inefficiency over time. Year
Model I
Model II
Model V
Model VI
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 1999–2012
40.39 39.70 39.36 85.35 44.83 30.85 42.51 101.14 98.16 138.95 154.46 80.93 81.65 69.96 70.91
565.96 457.90 411.68 352.35 339.18 293.42 302.70 318.65 261.34 232.14 202.20 157.14 158.44 153.54 315.86
149.20 163.45 294.21 309.89 298.73 313.55 401.28 280.22 205.82 299.51 390.88 281.71 312.12 340.64 284.85
365.50 369.57 370.76 389.63 433.71 471.97 539.91 562.43 599.15 577.80 569.98 587.31 596.21 590.00 488.06
lists the average technical inefficiency measures in terms of number of employees for Models I, II, V, and VI. On the basis of Models V and VI, the average technical inefficiency scores are respectively 284.85 and 488.06, which exceed the corresponding mean values of 70.91 and 315.86 from Models I and II, respectively. Again, the stan-
dard input distance function is inclined to overestimate technical inefficiencies, due partially to its failure to allow for the expansion of desirable outputs and the contraction of undesirable outputs. 5.3. Efficiency scores for various classifications To gain further insights into the impact of a bank’s ownership and organizational structure on efficiencies, we classify the entire sample into two different forms of ownership and organizational structure, respectively.10 5.3.1. Ownership effects on efficiency To eliminate the size effect, we translate the inefficiency value to the efficiency score, which is calculated as one minus the ratio of inefficiency value to labor. Fig. 3 shows the average efficiency scores over time for different types of ownership. Both models of I and III show that public banks are more efficient than private banks, especially during the post-FFR II period, and their differences are statistically significant, as shown in Table 7. Our results are congruent with Huang et al. (2011), Li et al. (2004), Liang, Yao, Hwang, and Wu (2008), Peng and Wang (2004), and Wu (2008). Li et al. (2004) and Liang et al. (2008) indicate technical efficiencies of (completely or partially) government-owned banks are higher than those of purely private-owned banks. Peng and Wang (2004) and Wu (2008) show that government-owned or controlled banks are the most cost efficient. Huang et al. (2011) also find similar evidence in East European (transition) countries. 5.3.2. The effect of organizational structure on efficiency On the basis of organizational structure, we split our sample banks into two groups: financial holding companies (FHC) and nonfinancial holding companies (non-FHC). Banks belonging to FHC are expected to operate more efficient than those of non-FHC, since the former belongs to a large conglomerate. Table 8 confirms the above expectation. The average efficiency measure of the FHC banks is significantly higher than that of the non-FHC banks. Fig. 4 shows the efficiency scores over time across different forms of banking organizational structure. The time patterns of efficiency scores for the two types of banks nearly synchronously move
10 We do not list the sample banks by bank ownership and organizational structure. The lists are available upon request from the authors.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18 10
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
Table 7 The efficiency scores and bank ownership. Period
Model I with undesirable output
Model III without undesirable output
Public
Private
Public
Private
Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) Mean No. of banks t-test: Public vs. Private
0.9868 39 5.31*** [0.00]
0.9606 111
0.9492 39 5.57*** [0.00]
0.8478 111
FFR period (2002–2003) Mean No. of banks t-test: Public vs. Private
0.9794 26 3.62*** [0.00]
0.9410 72
0.9422 26 4.27*** [0.00]
0.8257 72
Post-FFR period I (2004–2007) Mean No. of banks t-test: Public vs. Private
0.9835 48 3.81*** [0.00]
0.9557 117
0.9462 48 4.57*** [0.00]
0.8508 117
Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Mean No. of banks t-test: Public vs. Private
0.9756 55 4.52*** [0.00]
0.9275 121
0.9332 55 4.77*** [0.00]
0.8003 121
Whole period (1999–2012) Mean Std. dev. No. of banks t-test: Public vs. Private
0.9810 0.0208 168 7.69*** [0.00]
0.9464 0.0568 421
0.9420 0.0544 168 9.08*** [0.00]
0.8312 0.1544 421
t-test: Pre-FFR vs. FFR t-test: FFR vs. Post-FFR I t-test: Post-FFR I vs. Post-FFR II
3.27*** [0.00] −2.15** [0.03] 3.37*** [0.00]
1.16 [0.25] −1.33 [0.18] 2.14** [0.03]
Note: The figures in the brackets stand for p-value. * Denotes significance at the 10% level. ** Denotes significance at the 5% level. *** Denotes significance at the 1% level.
Table 8 The efficiency scores and organizational structure. Period
Model I with undesirable output
Model III without undesirable output
Non-FHC
FHC
Non-FHC
FHC
Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) Mean No. of banks t-test: non-FHC vs. FHC
0.9674 147 0.03 [0.97]
0.9669 3
0.8745 147 0.30 [0.77]
0.8560 3
FFR period (2002–2003) Mean No. of banks t-test: non-FHC vs. FHC
0.9451 70 −1.98* [0.05]
0.9665 28
0.8385 70 −2.24** [0.03]
0.9018 28
Post-FFR period I (2004–2007) Mean No. of banks t-test: non-FHC vs. FHC
0.9566 106 −2.87*** [0.00]
0.9767 59
0.8571 106 −2.93*** [0.00]
0.9171 59
Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Mean No. of banks t-test: non-FHC vs. FHC
0.9226 99 −4.60*** [0.00]
0.9682 77
0.7890 99 −4.62*** [0.00]
0.9097 77
Whole period (1999–2012) Mean Std. dev. No. of banks t-test: non-FHC vs. FHC
0.9505 0.0553 422 −4.38*** [0.00]
0.9709 0.0377 167
0.8441 0.1490 422 5.16*** [0.00]
0.9100 0.1127 167
t-test: Pre-FFR vs. FFR t-test: FFR vs. Post-FFR I t-test: Post-FFR I vs. Post-FFR II
3.27*** [0.00] −2.15** [0.03] 3.37*** [0.00]
1.16 [0.25] −1.33 [0.18] 2.14** [0.03]
Note: The figures in the brackets stand for p-value. * Denotes significance at the 10% level. ** Denotes significance at the 5% level. *** Denotes significance at the 1% level.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
Model I_Public
Model I_Private
Model III_Public
Model III_Private
11
1.00
0.95
0.90
0.85
0.80
0.75
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Fig. 3. Average efficiency scores by ownership in Models I and III.
1.00
Model I_Non-FHC
Model I_FHC
Model III_Non-FHC
Model III_FHC
0.95
0.90
0.85
0.80
0.75 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Fig. 4. Average efficiency scores by bank organizational type in Models I and III.
together, and the difference in average efficiency score becomes broader after the FFR period in both models.
5.4. The shadow price The shadow price of NPLs can be viewed as the cost that the bank has to spend to deal with the NPLs, measured by the same unit as either Pm or Wn (see Eq. (12)). A higher value of the shadow price leads to a higher cost of NPL disposal, which tends to hurt banks’ performance. We use the price of loans, P2 , to calculate the shadow price of the bad output.11 Table 9 shows that the average shadow prices during the four periods are equal to 0.0019, 0.1310, 0.2882, and 0.3602, respectively. The average shadow price in the pre-FFR period is the lowest among the four periods. Since we do not impose the monotonicity T /∂b1 ≥ 0 for each observarestriction on the bad output, i.e., ∂D T /∂b1 takes tion, as Färe et al. (2005) do, the partial derivative of ∂D
11 We also apply other output and input prices to calculate the shadow price, based on (12). The results are not shown in order to save space.
negative values for a few observations.12 In these cases the ratio of T /∂b1 /∂D T /∂y2 is set to be equal to zero, which leads the shadow ∂D prices of the undesirables to be equal to zero. Moreover, there are T /∂y2 ≤ 0, where the corresponding several observations with ∂D values of the shadow prices are also set to be equal to zero. Since the zero shadow prices mainly occur between 1999 and 2001, we will not discuss the pre-FFR period (1999–2001). Taiwan underwent its own domestic financial crisis in 1999, joined WTO, and then faced the challenges of international competition in financial markets and the dot-com bubble in 2001. The ratio of NPLs to total loans in Taiwan’s banking industry rose rapidly during this time. After that, the “Financial Holding Company Act” was implemented, and the government revised the “Value-added and Non-value-added Business Tax Act”, cutting the business tax from 5% to 2%. Moreover, the government enforced negotiations between banks and
12 Fukuyama and Weber (2008) also do not impose this non-negativity restriction on bad outputs, i.e., they allow their output frontier to be either positively or negatively sloped with respect to b1 . Feng and Serletis (2014) impose the monotonicity and curvature conditions on the directional output distance function, which is commonly estimated by Bayesian stochastic frontier approach.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
12
Table 9 Estimates of the shadow price and its components. Period
Shadow price
P2
Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) FFR period (2002–2003) Post-FFR period I (2004–2007) Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Whole period (1999–2012)
0.0019 0.1310 0.2882 0.3602 0.2037
0.0883 0.0641 0.0548 0.0387 0.0610
/∂b ∂D T 1 /∂y ∂D T 2
−0.0246 −2.1821 −5.5385 −10.1609 −4.7491
shadow price
T /∂y2 ∂D
y2
T /∂b1 ∂D
b1
−0.0002 −0.0009 −0.0009 −0.0018 −0.0010
278,837 292,681 362,850 469,464 357,529
3.84E − 05 0.0025 0.0079 0.0171 0.0074
17,987 16,132 7764 3440 10,775
P2
0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 -0.10 Fig. 5. The shadow price and price of loans (P2 ).
debtors, aiming at reducing the operating risk and technical inefficiency of banks. These policies helped banks have more resources to eliminate NPLs and promote their managerial abilities. The implementation of these policies is likely to hinder the estimated values T /∂b1 from being non-negative. of ∂D T /∂y2 , Note that the shadow price consists of three items: P2 , ∂D and ∂DT /∂b1 . Table 9 shows the individual estimates. From the FFR T /∂y2 remains constant, ∂D T /∂b1 period to post-FFR period I, ∂D enlarges around three times, while P2 decreases slightly. Summing up the three components, we see that the average shadow price T /∂y2 rises sharply in post-FFR period I. In the last period, both ∂D and ∂DT /∂b1 go up more than twice as much as the former period, accompanied by a decrease in P2 . The overall effect is that the average value of the shadow price increases from 0.2882 to 0.3602. We conclude that the main source stimulating the shadow price comes T /∂b1 , rather than ∂D T /∂y2 . from ∂D Fig. 5 shows that the average price of loans is around 5% and decreases over time. Conversely, the average shadow price of NPLs grows with time until 2008 and then decreases sharply. During the FFR period (2002–2003), the shadow price increases from 0.1087 in 2002 to 0.1553 in 2003. After that period, the shadow prices continue to climb and reach another peak in 2006 due to the “credit card and cash card crisis”. The “credit card and cash card debt crisis” was the result of the over-issuance of credit cards and cash cards by Taiwan banks since 2004, arising from fierce competition in the industry. The bad debts of credit cards and cash cards amounted to NT$800 billion in 2005 and 2006. The average shadow price of NPLs peaks in 2008 and is equal to 0.6587, and then drops to 0.2972 in 2012. The subprime mortgage crisis in the U.S. is the major reason for the rise of the shadow prices, and this has affected Taiwanese banking sectors greatly. When these external events happen, the shadow prices of NPLs could accurately reflect the cost of NPLs.
5.4.1. Ownership effects on the shadow price We classify the sample banks on the basis of ownership (private vs. public) and members of a financial holding company (FHC) to see
their differences in average shadow prices. Fig. 6 draws the average shadow prices across time for these two forms of banks. The average shadow prices of private banks are more stable and higher than those of public banks, except in 2008 when the U.S. subprime crisis happened. Table 10 shows that the highest average shadow price of private banks is equal to 0.3330 in post-FFR period I, meaning that the “credit card and cash card crisis” hit private banks severely. Post-FFR period II has the second highest shadow price for private banks with a slightly lower average value of 0.3201, while the highest average shadow price for public banks is equal to 0.4954. The average shadow price is lower for public banks, except for post-FFR period II. Our findings are not consistent with the previous findings of Li et al. (2009), who note that public banks have to spend more resources than private banks to cut their NPLs. A possible reason is that public banks have already operated for a long time and have great credit, and so they have to compete for loans. They pay a lower cost for NPLs and have better operating efficiency. Moreover, public banks have a longer operating life, having abundant experiences to achieve their maximum profit target and to lower shadow price. Based on the above discussion, an increase in the ratio of T /∂b1 to ∂D T /∂y2 would result in an enhancement of the shadow ∂D T /∂b1 /∂D T /∂y2 price. In the FFR period, the absolute value of ∂D is equal to 1.3087 for public banks, which is notably lower than 2.4896 for private banks. Consequently, the shadow price for public banks is about 0.0671 that is significantly lower than 0.1535 for private banks. Similar results are found in post-FFR period I. However, the reverse results are reached in post-FFR period II. The T /∂b1 /∂D T /∂y2 for private banks increases to absolute value of ∂D 8.2584, and that of public banks rises substantially to 16.5751. This raises the shadow price of public banks. Table 11 presents the testing results for the differences in the shadow price between private and public banks. It shows that there is no significant difference in the entire period of 1999–2012. However, the same tests attain at least the 10% significance level in the first three sub-periods. One is led to conclude that the “credit card and cash card crisis” did exert a significant impact on shadow prices.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
Public
13
Private
Fig. 6. Shadow price by ownership.
Table 10 Estimates of the shadow price and its components by ownership. Period
Shadow price
P2
Public banks Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) FFR period (2002–2003) Post-FFR period I (2004k2007) Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Whole period (1999–2012)
0.0064 0.0671 0.1594 0.4954 0.1857
0.0808 0.0487 0.0424 0.0275 0.0503
Private banks Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) FFR period (2002–2003) Post-FFR period I (2004–2007) Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Whole period (1999–2012)
0.0003 0.1535 0.3330 0.3201 0.2096
0.0908 0.0695 0.0592 0.0420 0.0645
Table 11 Tests for the differences in shadow prices between public and private banks. Period
t-test
Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) FFR period (2002–2003) Post-FFR period I (2004–2007) Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Whole period (1999–2012)
1.73* [0.09] −3.10*** [2.57E − 03] -3.73*** [2.73E − 04] 1.09 [0.28] −0.50 [0.62]
Note: Figures in the brackets stand for p-value. Denotes significance at the 10% level. Denotes significance at the 5% level. *** Denotes significance at the 1% level. * *
/∂b ∂D T 1 /∂y ∂D T 2
T /∂y2 ∂D
y2
T /∂b1 ∂D
b1
−0.0846 −1.3087 −4.3895 −16.5751 −5.7365
0.0006 −0.0002 0.0007 0.0002 0.0004
704,773 708,782 810,042 1,164,943 852,722
0.0001 0.0019 0.0042 0.0114 0.0045
41,503 34,383 15,587 8547 24,343
−0.0040 −2.4896 −5.9382 −8.2584 −4.4207
−0.0004 −0.0011 −0.0015 −0.0024 −0.0014
133,021 146,167 207,304 263,178 192,863
0.0000 0.0027 0.0092 0.0188 0.0083
9936 9706 5043 1925 6263
5.4.2. The effect of organizational structure on the shadow price Fig. 7 displays that the average shadow prices of banks belonging to non-FHC are higher than those of banks belonging to FHC. Table 12 exhibits that the average shadow price of non-FHC banks is equal to 0.2183 that is higher than 0.1647 for FHC banks. This outcome is similar to Ke et al. (2011), who explore the relationship between profit efficiency and shadow prices of NPLs for Taiwan’s banking sector spanning 1999 to 2007. Their estimates of the average shadow prices of non-FHC and FHC banks are 0.223 and 0.119, respectively. After the enforcement of the Financial Holding Act in 2001, financial institutions have been allowed to operate their business in the fields of banking, insurance, and securities. The member bank of a financial holding company is able to create greater synergy through the efficient mobilization of abundant internal resources
Table 12 Estimates of the shadow price and its components by organizational structure. /∂b ∂D T 1 /∂y ∂D T 2
T /∂y2 ∂D
y2
T /∂b1 ∂D
b1
0.0884 0.0665 0.0554 0.0438 0.0667
−0.0251 −2.5528 −7.1226 −12.1747 −4.8904
−0.0002 −0.0012 −0.0014 −0.0026 −0.0012
277,199 253,407 248,213 212,310 251,670
3.92E − 05 0.0031 0.0102 0.0211 0.0077
17,776 18,683 7367 2216 11,921
0.0824 0.0582 0.0538 0.0316 0.0458
0 −1.2817 −2.7380 −7.3605 −4.3728
−0.0004 0.0001 −0.0001 −0.0008 −0.0003
358,537 388,062 565,511 827,069 639,353
0 0.0010 0.0039 0.0116 0.0065
28,211 9937 8467 5142 7723
Period
Shadow price
P2
Non-FHC banks Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) FFR period (2002–2003) Post-FFR period I (2004k2007) Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Whole period (1999–2012)
0.0019 0.1519 0.3689 0.4566 0.2183
FHC banks Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) FFR period (2002–2003) Post-FFR period I (2004–2007) Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Whole period (1999–2012)
0 0.0803 0.1456 0.2261 0.1647
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18 14
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
Non-FHC
FHC
Fig. 7. Shadow price by organizational structure.
Table 13 Tests for the differences in shadow prices between non-FHC and FHC banks. Period
t-test
Pre-FFR period (1999–2001) FFR period (2002–2003) Post-FFR period I (2004–2007) Post-FFR period II (2008–2012) Whole period (1999–2012)
0.18 [0.86] 2.63** [0.01] 5.52*** [1.45E − 07] 1.69* [0.09] 1.15 [0.25]
Note: Figures in the brackets stand for p-value. * Denotes significance at the 10% level. ** Denotes significance at the 5% level. *** Denotes significance at the 1% level.
and can diversify its array of financial products. A lower value of the average shadow price for FHC banks implies that these banks can lower their operating costs. Moreover, FHC banks can easily diversify their financial products and enjoy scale economies in order to reduce production costs and improve operating performance. We next carry out the t-test for the differences in the shadow prices between the two types of banks. Table 13 reports the results. Although their average shadow prices are found to be close to each other in the entire sample period, they are significantly different in the latter three sub-periods at least at the 10% level. 6. Conclusion This research investigates the impact of FFR policy on the operating efficiency of banks in Taiwan during the period 1999–2012 using the stochastic directional technology distance function. Compared to the conventional distance function, DDF simultaneously allows for the expansion of the desirables and the contraction of the undesirables. Following Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al. (2009a), and differing from them, we include undesirable outputs in DDF to depict a bank’s true production activities. We estimate the quadratic form of DDF, which includes undesirable output, under the framework of Battese and Coelli (1992, 1995), respectively. We also provide the estimation results without considering undesirable output from DDF, for a comparison. To examine whether the policy does improve the technical efficiency of banks in Taiwan, we consequently divide the sample period into four sub-periods: preFFR period (1999–2001), FFR period (2002–2003), post-FFR period I (2004–2007), and post-FFR period II (2008–2012). We attain several interesting findings. First, the model specification considering an undesirable output can portray a bank’s frontier better, whereas neglecting an undesirable output might induce an overestimation of the technical inefficiency. We find that the banks
have a lower technical inefficiency on average with Models I and II compared to the other models, implying that the exclusion of economic bad outputs from DDF tends to overestimate inefficiency scores. In addition, the average inefficiency measure of Model I is less than that of Model II, implying that the omission of environmental variables is apt to exaggerate managerial inefficiency. The foregoing reflects the importance of including both undesirables and environment variables in the DDF. Second, the results of the current study have implications for the design of public policy by providing evidence to policymakers of FFR’s effectiveness. Prior to 2002, banks’ technical inefficiency exhibits a gradual upward trend, followed by a downward trend during the FFR period. These results suggest that the improved efficiency in the FFR period is possibly due to enhanced banking and benefits obtained from compliance with FFR. After the FFR period, the inefficiency scores deteriorate sharply, especially during the “credit card and cash card crisis” in 2006 and “the subprime mortgage crisis” in 2008. Third, the results in this article also report differences in the efficiency performance of banks with different ownership and organizational structures. We examine the difference of technical efficiency between public banks and private banks. Results show that public banks are more efficient than private banks, because public banks in Taiwan are older and have stronger relationships with business. Banks belonging to an FHC may operate more efficiently than those belonging to a non-FHC, since the former belongs to a large conglomerate. Finally, we also estimate the shadow price of NPLs from DDF. We classify the sample banks on the basis of ownership and members of a financial holding company in order to relate these features to average shadow prices. The empirical results demonstrate that the average shadow prices of private banks are more stable and higher than those of public banks. The average shadow prices of non-FHC banks are higher than those of FHC banks. In sum, private and nonFHC banks tend to have higher shadow prices, whereas public and FHC banks are related to lower shadow prices, except in 2008 when the U.S. subprime crisis happened. The results herein suggest three avenues for future research. First, we can further explore productivity performance of Taiwan’s banking industry. Second, we can aim to gain further insights into the operating efficiencies of FHC and non-FHC banks using the metafrontier approach under the framework of DDF. Third, while we choose to study the efficiency effects of FFR, future research can also examine the effects of such regulatory changes on accounting, i.e., IFRS, as well as mergers and acquisitions.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
15
Appendix A. Distance functions and shadow prices The DDF
−x3 = ˛0 +
= ˛0 +
N
an xn +
n=1
+
N N 1
2
˛nn xn xn +
n=1 n =1
M N
+
mn ym xn +
n=1 m=1
M M 1
2
ni bi xn +
+
n=1
I M
I I 1
2
N−1 N−1
i bi 1 2
+
I I
ii bi bi
i=1 i =1
+
I N−1
n=1
m=1
ˇm (ym + x3 ) +
(A1)
I
+
M M
ˇmm (ym + x3 )(ym + x3 )
m=1 m =1
i i (bi − x3 )(bi − x3 ) +
M N−1
n=1
ni (bi − x3 )(xn − x3 ) +
1 ı2 t 2 + 2
m=1 N−1 n t(xn
− x3 ) +
mn (ym + x3 )(xn − x3 )
m=1
I M
n=1
i tbi + v.
1 2
˛nn (xn − x3 )(xn − x3 ) +
mi bi ym + ı1 t 2
i=1
i (bi − x3 )
I=1
i=1
+ı1 t 2 +
I
m=1
i =1
i=1
I
m tym +
M
n =1
n=1
m=1 i=1
M
n txn
I
1 2
+
I=1
ˇmm ym ym +
n=1 i=1
1 + ı2 t 2 + 2
ˇm ym +
m=1
m=1 m =1
I N
N
M
˛n (xn − x3 ) +
n=1
To empirically estimate the DDF, a quadratic DDF is commonly parameterized as follow: → D T (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb , t, )
N−1
mi (bi − x3 )(ym + x3 )
i=1
M
m t(ym + x3 )
m=1
(A5)
i t(bi − x3 ) + v − u.
i=1
Here, = (˛, ˇ, , , , , ı, , , ) is a vector of unknown parameters to be estimated and v is an error term. It is important to note that some theoretical restrictions have to be imposed on Eq. (A1). First of all, the symmetry conditions on the second-order terms require: (i) ˛nn = ˛n n , n = / n (ii) ˇmm = ˇm m , m = / m (iii)ii = i i , i = /
(A2)
−
N
˛n +
n=1
(ii) −
N
M
We define the profit function as:
mn +
−
ii −
n n=1
+
ˇmm −
in +
M
n=1
m=1 I
m −
→
(x − DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb )gx , y + DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb )gy ,
n.
→
b − DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb )gb ) im = 0,for all
m.
(A3)
i=1
M m=1
→
in = 0, for all
I
im = 0, for all
is feasible, we have: → R(w, p, q) − (py − qb − wx) ≥ DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb ). wgx + pgy + qgb
i.
i = 0,
→
DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb ) = inf p,q
The translation property is described as follows: →
DT (x − ˇgx , y + ˇgy , b − ˇgb ; gx , gy , gb ) = DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb ) − ˇ, ˇ ≥ 0.
(A7)
If T is a closed, non-empty convex set, then the DDF can be obtained from the profit function as (Färe & Grosskopf, 2005):
i=1
→
(A6)
where w is the vector of input prices, p is the vector of desirable output prices, and q is the vector of undesirable output prices. Since R(w, p, q) ≥ py − qb − wx for all feasible (x, y, b) ∈ T and
i = −1,
I
R(w, p, q) = max{py − wx − qb : (x, y, b) ∈ T },
i=1
m =1 N
i =1 N
(v)
mn −
m=1 M
n=1 I
(iv) −
I i=1
n =1 N
(iii) −
ˇm −
m=1 M
˛nn +
The shadow price of undesirable outputs
i .
Second, we impose the following conditions to meet the translation property of DDF:
(i)
Here, u is a one-sided error, which reflects the technical inefficiency of a bank and is assumed to be independent of v, and the composite error is defined as ε = v − u. Note that other inputs, or outputs, or undesirable outputs can be chosen to be equal to ˇ.
(A4)
R(w, p, q) − (py − qb − wx) . wgx + pgy + qgb
(A8)
Assuming Eq. (A8) is differentiable, we apply the envelop theorem to yield the shadow prices. Suppose that the mth desirable output price and the nth input price are known (or equal to the shadow price). The shadow pricing formulae then take the form: →
Eq. (A4) says that if we translate the input, desirable output, and undesirable output vector (x, y, b) into (x − ˇgx , y + ˇgy , b − ˇgb ), then the value of DDF is reduced by the scalar ˇ. We have to impose the symmetric and translation properties into Eq. (A1) to yield the estimable regression equation. After set-
pm = −
ting ˇ = x3 and defining DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb , t, ) = u ≥ 0, Eq. (A1) can be written as:
qi =
∂DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb ) × (wgx + pgy + qgb ), ∀m. ∂ym →
∂DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb ) × (wgx + pgy + qgb ), ∀n. wn = ∂xn
(A9)
→
→
∂DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb ) × (wgx + pgy + qgb ), ∀i. ∂bi
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
16
Here, we assume wgx + pgy + qgb = / 0. Taking the ratio of qi to pm and qi to wn and rearranging terms, the shadow prices of bad outputs are computed either by: →
qi = pm ×
∂DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb )/∂bi
,∀
→
i and m.
(A10)
∂DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb )/∂ym →
qi = wn ×
→
J
aj = 1,
j
J
ajk =
, ∀ i and n.
∂DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb )/xn
j
The input distance function The standard translog input distance function with M outputs and J inputs is formulated as:
1n D = a0 +
J
aj 1n(xj ) +
j=1
1 2
+
M M
m=1
j=1
bm 1n(ym ) +
m=1
bml 1n(ym )1n(yl ) +
l=1
J
+
M
J M
−ln x3 = a0 +
j
jt = 0, ∀k, m.
J−1
aj ln(xj /x3 ) +
M
cjm 1n(xj )1n ym + j0 t +
(A12)
1 1 ajk ln(xj /x3 )ln(xk /x3 ) + bml ln ym ln yl 2 2
J−1 M
1 j00 t 2 2
bm lnym
m=1 M
+
M
m=1 l=1
j=1 k=1
k=1
cjm ln(xj /x3 )ln ym + j0 t +
1 j00 t 2 2
j=1 m=1
m=1
J−1
mt t1n(ym ) + V
J j
j=1
+
ajk 1n(xj )1n(xk )
M
jt t1n(xj ) +
cjm =
J−1 J−1
J J
j=1
j=1
1 2
J
In addition, symmetry restrictions require that ajk = akj , ∀j = / k / m. and blm = bml , ∀l = After imposing the restriction of linear homogeneity in inputs by normalizing the inputs and D by an input, say x3 , and letting 1n D = U (Färe & Primont, 1995; Karagiannis et al., 2004; Kumbhakar & Wang, 2007), Eq. (A11) becomes:
or
∂DT (x, y, b; gx , gy , gb )/∂bi
has to be linearly homogeneous in inputs, which requires Eq. (A11) to satisfy:
(A11)
m=1
where (a, b, c, j, , ) are unknown parameters and V ∼iid N (0, V2 ) denotes the error term. Readers are suggested to refer to Färe and Primont (1995) for a detailed discussion on the properties of the input and the output distance functions. An input distance function
+
jt t ln(xj /x3 ) +
j=2
M
mt t lnym + V − U.
(A13)
m=1
Appendix B.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model
ARTICLE IN PRESS
QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18
T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
17
Table B1 Parameter estimates of the stochastic DDF without undesirables. Variables
Model III
Model IV
Coefficients
t-ratio
Coefficients
t-ratio
Intercept x1 x2 x3 x12 x22 x32 x1 x2 x1 x3 x2 x3
˛0 ˛1 ˛2 ˛3 ˛11 ˛22 ˛33 ˛12 ˛13 ˛23
−72.739 −0.004*** 0.002 – 0.004*** −3.3E − 04 – −0.299*** – –
−0.640 −4.632 0.213 – 4.249 −0.379 – −14.673 – –
220.832*** −0.004*** 0.002 – 0.004*** −2.8E − 04 – −0.262*** – –
2.814 −5.391 0.149 – 4.969 −0.382 – −14.162 – –
Desirable outputs
y1 y2 y3 y12 y22 y32 y1 y2 y1 y3 y2 y3
ˇ1 ˇ2 ˇ3 ˇ11 ˇ22 ˇ33 ˇ12 ˇ13 ˇ23
1.3E − 08*** 1.2E − 09 2.6E − 07 1.5E − 08** 2.0E − 08*** −4.7E − 08 1.8E − 08*** −2.0E − 07*** 1.8E − 05***
3.868 0.032 0.483 2.264 5.041 −0.629 5.517 −2.646 8.491
6.8E − 09*** 2.7E − 08 1.5E − 08 1.8E − 08*** 2.0E − 08*** −2.0E − 07*** 9.9E − 09*** −2.9E − 07*** 1.1E − 05***
2.625 0.911 0.033 3.220 5.795 −3.262 3.840 −4.377 5.626
Undesirable outputs
b1 b21
1 11
– –
– –
– –
– –
Cross-products
y1 x1 y1 x2 y1 x3 y2 x1 y2 x2 y2 x3 y3 x1 y3 x2 y3 x3 b1 x1 b1 x2 b1 x3 b1 y1 b1 y2 b1 y3
11 12 13 21 22 23 31 32 33 11 12 13 11 12 13
−1.9E − 08*** 4.1E − 08 – −1.5E − 08*** 2.3E − 08 – 1.7E − 07** −2.4E − 06** – – – – – – –
−4.665 1.376 – −4.704 0.683 – 2.196 −2.001 – – – – – – –
−1.8E − 08*** 3.3E − 08 – −7.6E − 09*** −2.6E − 08 – 3.1E − 07*** −2.7E − 06*** – – – – – – –
−5.329 1.476 – −3.127 −0.977 – 4.503 −2.396 – – – – – – –
Technical change
t t2 tx1 tx2 tx3 ty1 ty2 ty3 tb1
ı1 ı2
1 2 3 1
10.105 0.987 3.2E − 04*** −0.004*** – −2.2E − 05 −1.7E − 04 −0.016*** –
0.444 0.277 3.178 −3.706 – −0.231 −1.625 −6.310 –
−55.632*** 7.869*** 1.0E − 04 −3.0E − 04 – −4.7E − 05 −5.6E − 05 −0.010*** –
−3.469 3.624 1.200 −0.280 – −0.650 −0.615 −4.477 –
Constant IC PD DB ROE HHI
z0 z1 z2 z3 z4 z5
−61.826 380.274 −2.444 0.160 −15.778 1.153
−0.606 0.620 −1.570 0.993 −1.427 0.758
2
190,004.260*** 0.244*
27,193.692 1.943
200,000.650*** 0.574*** 0.024***
172,373.770 22.162 2.573
Inputs
Zs
Other ML parameters
1 2 3
Number of observations Log-likelihood function * ** ***
589 −4379.504
589 −4256.692
Denotes significance at the 10% level. Denotes significance at the 5% level. Denotes significance at the 1% level.
References Allen, L., & Rai, A. (1996). Operational efficiency in banking: An international comparison. Journal of Banking and Finance, 20, 655–672. Battese, G. E., & Coelli, T. J. (1992). Frontier production functions, technical efficiency and panel data: With application to paddy farmers in India. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 3, 153–169.
Battese, G. E., & Coelli, T. J. (1995). A model for technical inefficiency effects in a stochastic frontier production function for panel data. Empirical Economics, 20, 325–332. Battese, G. E., Heshmati, A., & Hjalmarsson, L. (2000). Efficiency of labour use in the Swedish banking industry: A stochastic frontier approach. Empirical Economics, 25, 623–640.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007
G Model QUAECO-983; No. of Pages 18 18
ARTICLE IN PRESS T.-H. Huang, M.-T. Chung / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (2016) xxx–xxx
Berger, A. N., & Hannan, T. H. (1998). The efficiency cost of market power in the banking industry: A test of the ‘quiet life’ and related hypotheses. Review Economics and Statistics, 80, 454–465. Berger, A. N., & Humphrey, D. B. (1997). Efficiency of financial institutions: International survey and directions for future research. European Journal of Operational Research, 98, 175–212. Cavallo, L., & Rossi, S. P. S. (2002). Do environmental variables affect the performance and technical efficiency of the European banking systems? A parametric analysis using the stochastic frontier approach. European Journal of Finance, 8, 123–146. Chambers, R. G. (2002). Exact nonradial input, output, and productivity measurement. Economic Theory, 20, 751–765. Chambers, R. G., Chung, Y. H., & Färe, R. (1996). Benefit and distance functions. Journal of Economic Theory, 70, 407–419. Chambers, R. G., Färe, R., & Grosskopf, S. (1996). Productivity growth in APEC countries. Pacific Economic Review, 1, 181–190. Chen, K. H. (2012). Incorporating risk input into the analysis of bank productivity: Application to the Taiwanese banking industry. Journal of Banking and Finance, 36, 1911–1927. Chuang, D. H., & Hölscher, J. (2008). The changing financial system in Taiwan. In R. W. McGee (Ed.), Accounting reform in transition and developing economies. London, New York: Springer. Chung, Y. H., Färe, R., & Grosskopf, S. (1997). Productivity and undesirable outputs: A directional distance function approach. Journal of Environmental Management, 51, 229–240. Coelli, T. J. (1996). A guide to FRONTIER version 4.1: A computer program for stochastic frontier production and cost function estimation, CEPA Working Paper No. 96 /07. Australia: School of Economics, University of New English. Das, A., & Ghosh, S. (2006). Financial deregulation and efficiency: An empirical analysis of Indian banks during the post reform period. Review of Financial Economics, 15, 193–221. Dietsch, M., & Lozano-Vivas, A. (2000). How the environment determines banking efficiency: A comparison between French and Spanish industries. Journal of Banking and Finance, 24, 985–1004. Dorfman, J. H., & Koop, G. (2005). Current developments in productivity and efficiency measurement. Journal of Econometrics, 126, 233–240. Elyasiani, E., & Mehdian, S. (1995). The comparative efficiency performance of small and large US commercial banks in the pre- and post-deregulation eras. Applied Economics, 27, 1069–1079. English, M., Grosskoft, S., Hayes, K., & Yaisawarng, S. (1993). Output allocative and technical efficiency of banks. Journal of Banking and Finance, 17, 349–366. Färe, R., & Grosskopf, S. (2004). New directions: Efficiency and productivity. Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., & Hernandez-Sancho, F. (2004). Environmental performance: An index number approach. Resource and Energy Economics, 26, 343–352. Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Noh, D.-W., & Weber, W. (2005). Characteristics of a polluting technology: Theory and practice. Journal of Econometrics, 126, 469–492. Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., & Weber, W. L. (2006). Shadow prices and pollution costs in U.S. agriculture. Ecological Economics, 56, 89–103. Färe, R., & Primont, D. (1995). Multi-output production and duality: Theory and applications. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Feng, G., & Serletis, A. (2014). Undesirable outputs and a primal Divisia productivity index based on the directional output distance function. Journal of Econometrics, 183, 135–146. Fries, S., & Taci, A. (2005). Cost efficiency of banks in transition: Evidence from 289 banks in 15 post-communist countries. Journal of Banking and Finance, 29, 55–81. Fu, X., & Heffernan, S. (2009). The effects of reform on China’s bank structure and performance. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33, 39–52. Fukuyama, H., & Weber, W. L. (2002). Estimating output allocative efficiency and productivity change: Application to Japanese banks. European Journal of Operational Research, 137, 177–190. Fukuyama, H., & Weber, W. L. (2008). Japanese banking inefficiency and shadow pricing. Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 48, 1854–1867. Grifell-Tatjé, E., & Lovell, C. A. K. (1996). Deregulation and productivity decline: The case of Spanish savings banks. European Economic Review, 40, 1281–1303. Halkos, G. E., & Salamouris, D. S. (2004). Efficiency measurement of the Greek commercial banks with the use of financial ratios: A data envelopment analysis approach. Management Accounting Research, 15, 201–224. Hasan, I., & Marton, K. (2003). Development and efficiency of the banking sector in a transitional economy: Hungarian experience. Journal of Banking and Finance, 27, 2249–2271. Hicks, J. (1935). Annual survey of economic theory: The theory of monopoly. Econometrica, 3, 1–20. Hsiao, H. C., Chang, H., Cianci, A. M., & Huang, L. H. (2010). First financial restructuring and operating efficiency: Evidence from Taiwanese commercial banks. Journal of Banking and Finance, 34, 1461–1471. Huang, T. H., Chiang, D. L., & Tsai, C. M. (2015). Applying the new metafrontier directional distance function to compare banking efficiencies in Central and Eastern European Countries. Economic Modelling, 44, 188–199. Huang, T. H., Shen, C. H., Chen, K. C., & Tseng, S. J. (2011). Measuring technical and allocative efficiencies for banks in the transition countries using the Fourier flexible cost function. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 35, 143–157.
Iqbal, Z., Ramaswamy, K. V., & Akhigbe, A. (1999). The output efficiency of minorityowned banks in the United States. International Review of Economics and Finance, 8, 105–114. Isik, I., & Hassan, M. K. (2003). Financial deregulation and total factor productivity change: An empirical study of Turkish commercial banks. Journal of Banking and Finance, 27, 1455–1485. Karagiannis, G., Midmore, P., & Tzouvelekas, V. (2004). Parametric decomposition of output growth using a stochastic input distance function. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 86, 1044–1057. Ke, T. Y., Li, Y., & Chiu, Y. H. (2011). Analyzing for profit efficiency of banks with undesirable output. African Journal of Business Management, 5, 8141–8149. Koutsomanoli-Filippaki, A., Margaritis, D., & Staikouras, C. (2009a). Efficiency and productivity growth in the banking industry of Central and Eastern Europe. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33, 557–567. Koutsomanoli-Filippaki, A., Margaritis, D., & Staikouras, C. (2009b). Profit efficiency under a directional technology distance function approach. Managerial Finance, 35, 276–296. Koutsomanoli-Filippaki, A., Margaritis, D., & Staikouras, C. (2012). Profit efficiency in the European Union banking industry: A directional technology distance function approach. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 37, 277–293. Kumbhakar, S. C., & Wang, D. (2007). Economic reforms, efficiency and productivity in Chinese banking. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 32, 105–129. Kumbhakar, S. C., Heshmati, A., & Hjalmarsson, L. (2002). How fast do banks adjust? A dynamic model of labor-use with an application to Swedish banks. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 18, 79–102. Lee, J. D., Park, J. B., & Kim, T. Y. (2002). Estimation of the shadow prices of pollutants with production/environment inefficiency taken into account: A nonparametric directional distance function approach. Journal of Environmental Management, 64, 365–375. Li, Y., Hu, J. L., & Chiu, Y. H. (2004). Ownership and production efficiency: Evidence from Taiwanese banks. Service Industries Journal, 24, 129–148. Li, Y., Hu, J. L., & Liu, H. W. (2009). Non-performing loans and bank efficiencies: An application of the distance function approach. Journal of Statistics and Management Systems, 12, 435–450. Liang, C. J., Yao, M. L., Hwang, D. Y., & Wu, W. H. (2008). The impact of non-performing loans on bank’s operating efficiency for Taiwan banking industry. Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies, 11, 287–304. Liu, W. C., & Hsu, C. M. (2006). The role of financial development in economic growth: The experiences of Taiwan, Korea, and Japan. Journal of Asian Economics, 17, 667–690. Lozano-Vivas, A., Pastor, J. T., & Hasan, I. (2001). European bank performance beyond country borders: What really matters? European Finance Review, 5, 141–165. Lozano-Vivas, A., Pastor, J. T., & Pastor, J. M. (2002). An efficiency comparison of European banking systems operating under different environmental conditions. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 18, 59–77. Luenberger, D. G. (1992). Benefit functions and duality. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 21, 461–481. Luenberger, D. G. (1995). Microeconomic theory. Boston: McGraw-Hill. Maudos, J., & de Guevara, J. F. (2007). The cost of market power in banking: Social welfare loss vs. cost inefficiency. Journal of Banking and Finance, 31, 2103–2125. O’Donnell, C. J., & Coelli, T. J. (2005). A Bayesian approach to imposingcurvature on distance functions. Journal of Econometrics, 126, 493–523. Park, K. H., & Weber, W. L. (2006). A note on efficiency and productivity growth in the Korean banking industry, 1992–2002. Journal of Banking and Finance, 30, 2371–2386. Peng, Y. H., & Wang, K. (2004). Cost efficiency and the effect of mergers on the Taiwanese banking industr. Service Industries Journal, 24, 21–39. Rojas-Suarez, L. (2001). Rating banks on emerging markets: What credit rating agencies should learn from financial indicators. In R. Levich, G. Majnoni, & C. Reinhart (Eds.), Ratings, rating agencies and the global financial system. Boston: Kluwer Academic Press. Shephard, R. W. (1953). Cost and production functions. Princeton University Press. Stiglitz, J. E. (1996). Some lessons from the East Asian miracle. World Bank Research Observer, 11, 151–177. Sturm, J. E., & Williams, B. (2004). Foreign bank entry, deregulation and bank efficiency: Lessons from the Australian experience. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28, 1775–1799. Watanabe, M., & Tanaka, K. (2007). Efficiency analysis of Chinese industry: A directional distance function approach. Energy Policy, 35, 6323–6331. Wu, W. H. (2008). The second financial reform and the development of financial industry in Taiwan. Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies, 11, 75–97. Yang, Y. H. (2001). The financial system and financial reform. In C. C. Mai, & C. S. Shih (Eds.), Taiwan’s economic success since 1980. Edward Elgar. Yeh, M. F. (2005). Taiwan’s financial reforms. Taiwan Economic Forum, 3, 23–48. Yu, M. M. (2004). Measuring physical efficiency of domestic airports in Taiwan with undesirable outputs and environmental factors. Journal of Air Transport Management, 10, 295–303. Zaim, O. (2004). Measuring environmental performance of state manufacturing through changes in pollution intensities: A DEA framework. Ecological Economics, 48, 37–47.
Please cite this article in press as: Huang, T. -H., & Chung, M.-T. Do undesirables matter on the examination of banking efficiency using stochastic directional distance functions. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2016.09.007