Accepted Manuscript Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data analysis
Wenfeng Liu, Xingping Zhang, Sida Feng PII:
S0960-1481(18)31468-X
DOI:
10.1016/j.renene.2018.12.037
Reference:
RENE 10912
To appear in:
Renewable Energy
Received Date:
20 March 2018
Accepted Date:
09 December 2018
Please cite this article as: Wenfeng Liu, Xingping Zhang, Sida Feng, Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data analysis, Renewable Energy (2018), doi: 10.1016/j.renene. 2018.12.037
This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
1
Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data
2
analysis
3
Wenfeng Liua, b, Xingping Zhanga, c, , Sida Fenga
4
a
5
China
6
b
7
Power University), Changping Beijing, 102206, China
8
c
9
Abstract
School of Economics and Management, North China Electric Power University, Beijing, 102206,
Beijing Key Laboratory of New Energy and Low-Carbon Development (North China Electric
Research Center for Beijing Energy Development, Beijing 102206, China
10
This paper develops a fixed effect model to evaluate the effect of renewable energy policy using
11
a panel dataset covering 29 countries during the period of 2000 to 2015. The renewable energy
12
policy system in this paper includes seven aggregate policies and twelve specific ones. The
13
empirical results indicate that four of seven aggregate policies, including fiscal and financial
14
incentives, market-based instruments, policy support, and research, development and deployment,
15
are demonstrated to be significant to the improvement of renewable energy capacity. Meanwhile,
16
three of twelve specific policies, including price policy, grants and subsidies, and strategic planning,
17
have positive effects on renewable energy development. This paper assesses the aggregate and
18
specific policies in the same analysis framework, and the empirical results determined that synergy
19
effects existed among specific policies. The empirical results also indicate that the implementation
20
of the Kyoto Protocol in 2005 has had positive impacts on renewable energy development in typical
Corresponding author: Tel.: +86 10 61773096; fax: +86 10 61773311.
E-mail address:
[email protected] (X. Zhang). 1
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 21
countries.
22
Keywords: Renewable energy policy; Policy effect assessment; Panel data model
23
1. Introduction
24
Climate change has become more pronounced in recent years, as CO2 emissions have continued
25
to grow worldwide. The countries researched in this paper emitted more than 70% of the entire
26
world carbon emissions in 2016 [1], and they have set quantitative targets for renewable energy
27
development, which is a key option to mitigate the climate change. Based on this background, public
28
renewable policies have been components of national planning agenda for many developed and
29
several large developing countries over the past several decades.
30
There is broad consensus in the literature concerning the need for public policy to promote
31
renewable energy development. First, the renewable energy policies are aimed at promoting the
32
development and deployment of renewable energy, which provides a sustainable and stable
33
domestic renewable energy market [2]. Second, the development of renewables that internalize the
34
costs of no pollution deserves incentives from public policies. Third, reducing energy dependence
35
is an important factor in introducing the public policy [3]. Finally, the compliance of international
36
agreements, such as the Kyoto Protocol, European Union directives or a long-term development
37
plan for renewable energy, are also indicated as other factors requiring the design of public policy.
38
Hence, many countries and international organizations view renewables as important elements of
39
energy security, dynamic economic development, environmental protection and greenhouse gas
40
emissions reduction efforts [4]. There are a variety of incentives and regulations to choose to support
41
renewables development; therefore, it is vital to assess the effectiveness of public policies for
42
renewables. A majority of published studies have qualitatively or theoretically discussed the 2
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 43
effectiveness of RE policies in the US or EU [5,6,7], while a minority present quantitative analyses.
44
Menz and Vachon [8] was the pioneering study to quantitatively assess the effectiveness of different
45
state policies that promote wind power, and several scholars have attempted to quantify the impacts
46
of renewable energy policies in different directions subsequently. First, many studies have focused
47
on analyzing the effectiveness of renewable energy policies at the state or provincial level. Several
48
state level studies have reached a positive conclusion. For instance, Menz and Vachon [8] assessed
49
the policies' relative effectiveness in terms of their impact on the level of wind capacity existing in
50
states of the US, finding a positive relationship between the renewable portfolio standard (RPS) and
51
wind power development. While others found mixed results, Carley [9] evaluated the effectiveness
52
of state energy programs with an empirical investigation of the linkage between state RPS policy
53
implementation and the percentage of renewable energy electricity generation across states in the
54
US, and the results indicate that RPS implementation is not a significant predictor of the percentage
55
of renewable energy generation in the total generation mix but increases the total amount of
56
renewable energy generation. Against this background, researchers have started to question whether
57
the effectiveness of renewable energy policies is conditional on the social, natural and institutional
58
environment. For instance, Delmas and Montes-Sancho [10] argued that a large presence of non-
59
governmental organizations, democratic representatives, and green residential customers facilitate
60
the transmission of renewable energy policies in the US.
61
There are also studies analyzing the effectiveness of renewable energy policies at the country
62
level. Johnstone et al. [11] examined the effect of environmental policies using panel data for 25
63
OECD countries during the period of 1978 to 2003 and found that public policy plays a significant
64
role in different renewable technological innovation. Based on this, Zhao et al. [12] evaluated the 3
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 65
effects of renewable electricity policies on renewable electricity generation using a large panel
66
dataset that covers 122 countries including developed, developing, and emerging market countries
67
during the period of 1980 to 2010. The results suggest that renewable electricity policies play a
68
crucial role in promoting renewable electricity generation, but their effectiveness is subject to
69
diminishing returns as the number of policies increases. In addition, there are several cross-country
70
studies investigating the relative effectiveness of different policy mechanisms. For instance, Dong
71
[13] examined the relative effectiveness of feed-in tariff (FIT) and RPS in promoting wind capacity
72
development using panel data covers 53 countries including the US, China, Germany, Spain, India
73
etc. Fiscal and financial incentives were demonstrated to accelerate the development of renewable
74
energy projects [14,15]; furthermore, mandatory requirements, quota, and obligation schemes do
75
exhibit a positive influence on renewable energy application in the US [8].
76
This study attempts to quantitatively assess the effectiveness of renewable energy public policies
77
on renewable energy and extends previous studies in two ways. First, empirical analyses of the
78
combination of aggregate and specific policies effectiveness remain scarce. The few existing studies,
79
such as that of Zhao et al. [12], primarily focus on aggregate renewable energy policies, while Polzin
80
et al. [16] mainly focus on specific renewable energy policies across OECD countries. In this paper,
81
we assess the effectiveness of aggregate and specific policies in the same analysis framework, which
82
can provide notable policy implications. Second, the Kyoto Protocol, a key international milestone,
83
has experienced an important impacts on the formulation of renewable energy policies in various
84
countries, we therefore incorporate it into model in the form of dummy variable. In addition, several
85
control variables are introduced into the model to reduce the deviations of missing variables in this
86
paper. 4
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 87
The remaining sections of this paper are structured as follows: Section 2 presents the data and the
88
analytical method. Section 3 presents the results and discussion, while section 4 presents the study’s
89
conclusion and policy implications.
90
2. Methods and Data
91
2.1 Variables and data sources
92
As dictated by the availability of data, 29 countries from the EU, the OECD, the signatories of
93
the Kyoto Protocol and two developing countries (China and India), are the study sample in this
94
paper. The reason for choosing these countries is that these countries have great support for
95
renewable energy policies and the scale of renewable energy in these countries has increased stably.
96
Fig. 1 shows the growing trend of renewables installation and the reduction of carbon dioxide
97
emissions following the time that the Kyoto Protocol entry into force in the sample countries.
98 99
Fig. 1 Total installed and new added capacity of renewable energy 5
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 100
Specifically, the sample countries in this paper include Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada,
101
China, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, India, Ireland,
102
Italy, Japan, Mexico, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, South Korea, Spain,
103
Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the United States of America. Many
104
countries have generally focused on the question of the development of renewable energy from
105
approximately 2000. Hence, we consider the data index of the stability and availability, and
106
therefore choose 2000 as the starting year and 2015 as the ending year.
107 Policy variables
Dummy variable
The Kyoto dummy (d_k)
Fiscal and financial incentives (pv_1) Price policy (PP) Grants and subsidies (GS) Tax (T) Market-based instruments (pv_2) GHG emissions allowances (GA) Green certificates (GC) Direct investments (pv_3) Funds to sub-national governments (FSG) Infrastructure investments (II)
Dependent variable Total capacity installed-renewable energies (in MW) RE_capacity (re_c)
Policy support (pv_4) Institutional creation (IC) Strategic planning (SP) Regulatory instruments (pv_5) Codes and standards (CS) Obligation schemes (OS) Other mandatory requirements (OMR)
Control variables
108 109
Real Gross Domestic Product (cv_gdp)
Carbon dioxide emissions (cv_co2)
Electric power consumption (cv_epc)
High-technology exports (cv_hte)
Information and education (pv_6)
Research, development and deployment (pv_7)
Fig. 2 Framework of variables
110
Fig. 2 shows the framework of variables. The data of dependent variable (renewable energy
111
capacity) is from the International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA), which is an
112
intergovernmental organization that supports countries in their transition to a sustainable energy 6
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 113
future and serves as the principal platform for international co-operation and a repository of policy,
114
technology, resource and financial knowledge on renewable energy [17]. These data include
115
information on installed electricity generating capacity, additions in renewable energy capacity and
116
renewable energy power generation at the country level.
117
We consider that the commitment to reduce greenhouse gas emissions and the emission-trading
118
scheme are substantial factors driving renewables development. The Kyoto Protocol signed in 1998
119
was a milestone in promoting carbon reduction. One of the key international steps in this direction
120
was the implementation of the Kyoto Protocol in 2005. Countries that signed this protocol are
121
expected to have great commitment to renewables deployment, as shown by Popp et al. [18].
122
Although the Kyoto Protocol was signed in 1998, there was no legal effect at that time. The Kyoto
123
Protocol entry into force in 2005, it is the first time to restrict greenhouse gas emissions in the form
124
of regulations. Therefore, this paper takes the time of 2005 to set up variable. In this paper, dummy
125
variable is used: The Kyoto Protocol dummy (variable d_k) is 1 for the implementation countries
126
after 2005 and 0 otherwise. We expect a positive relationship between renewables capacity and the
127
Kyoto Protocol variable.
128
The policy variables are drawn from the IEA/IRENA policy and measure database. These
129
indicators have been used by previous scholars to analyze the impacts of policy instruments on
130
renewable energy in OECD countries [16], Europe [3] and globally [4]. In this paper, we consider
131
the following seven aggregate and fourteen specific policy instruments: (1) Fiscal and Financial
132
Incentives, which designed to reducing the risk of investors, includes three specific instruments of
133
price policy (PP), grants and subsidies (GS), and tax (T). (2) Market-based instruments, which
134
provides a tool for trading and meeting renewable energy obligation among producers, and an open 7
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 135
fair trading platform among market subjects, include specific instruments of greenhouse gas
136
emissions allowances (GA) and green certificates (GC). (3) Direct investments, aimed at reducing
137
the capital cost of renewable energy investment, includes funds to sub-national governments (FSG)
138
and infrastructure investments (II). (4) Policy support, which seeks to define strategies and outlines
139
specific programs to promote renewable capacity inside a country, includes institutional creation
140
(IC) and strategic planning (SP). (5) Regulatory instruments, which place a requirement on the
141
minimum amount of electricity supply that comes from renewable sources, primarily include codes
142
and standards (CS), obligation schemes (OS), and other mandatory requirements (OMR). (6)
143
Information and education, which provides guidelines and obligations in regards to further
144
deployment of renewable energy installations, and provides education and trainings for the
145
workforce employed in the building sector on matters of energy efficiency and renewable energy
146
installations. (7) Research, development and deployment (RD&D), which captures effect of
147
technological progress on the promotion of renewable energy. The first 6 aggregate policy variables
148
are measured by the number of active policies in a country per year, which previous studies call
149
“accumulated number of renewable energy policies and measures (ANPM)” [4,16]. Econometric
150
model is a common method to quantitatively evaluate policy effectiveness of renewable energy,
151
such as Marques and Fuinhas [3], Aguirre and Ibikunle [4] and Polzin et al. [16]. In the process of
152
econometric analysis, a potential hypothesis is that the more policies of a specific type there are, the
153
better it is for renewable energy capacity. Following this strand, we set up policy variables and
154
evaluate the effectiveness of renewable energy policy in the framework of econometric models.
155
Furthermore, there are factors delaying the investment process, such as the need to build a wind
156
farm or solar park. With this analysis, we expand Polzin et al. [16] by providing more detailed 8
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 157
policies for renewable installed equipment, considering the lagged reaction of policy variables to
158
the installed capacity of renewable energy.
159
Control variables are drawn from the World Development Indicators database and BP Statistical
160
Review Worlds Energy database, which includes Macroeconomic data and Energy data. Further,
161
economic indicators that might drive renewables capacity include the GDP (cv_gdp). Electric power
162
consumption (cv_epc) and CO2 emissions (cv_co2) are used respectively to account for energy
163
consumption and CO2 emissions. To account for technological level, this paper includes High-
164
technology exports (cv_hte).In Table 1, we present a summary of the variables used in this paper,
165
along with their descriptive statistics.
166 Variable re_c
cv_gdp cv_co2 cv_epc cv_hte pv_1 PP GS T pv_2 GA GC pv_3 FSG
Table 1 Variables definition, sources and descriptive statistics Definition
Obs.
Mean
Std.dev.
Min
Max
Logarithm of the installed capacity of multiple renewable energy resources (Megawatts)
464
7.74
1.7
2.3
12.12
Real gross domestic product (in billions U.S. dollars,constant 2010)
464
17,005.66
28,510.70
1,066
165,974.50
464
7.5
4.63
0
20.21
464
6,858.25
5,399.26
0
25,590.69
464
16.3
8.46
0
47.84
ANPM (Fiscal and financial incentives)
464
5.38
5.49
0
31
ANPM (Price policy) ANPM (Grants and subsidies) ANPM (Tax)
464 464 464
1.08 1.74 0.41
1.78 2.19 0.71
0 0 0
12 12 3
ANPM (Market-based instruments)
464
0.53
1.11
0
7
464
0.15
0.45
0
2
464 464
0.27 0.91
0.64 1.74
0 0
5 9
464
0.20
0.52
0
3
Carbon dioxide emissions (metric tons per capita) Electric power consumption (kWh per capita) High-technology exports(% of manufactured exports)
ANPM (Greenhouse gas emissions allowances) ANPM (Green certificates) ANPM (Direct investments) ANPM (Funds to sub-national governments)
9
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT II
ANPM (Infrastructure investments )
464
0.23
0.55
0
2
pv_4 IC SP pv_5 CS OS
ANPM (Policy support) ANPM (Institutional creation) ANPM (Strategic planning) ANPM (Regulatory instruments) ANPM (Codes and standards) ANPM (Obligation schemes)
464 464 464 464 464 464
4.21 0.75 2.07 3.90 1.02 0.55
5.59 1.32 3.02 4.77 1.81 1.08
0 0 0 0 0 0
50 11 28 29 15 5
OMR
ANPM (Other mandatory requirements)
464
0.65
1.21
0
8
pv_6
ANPM (Information and education)
464
1.51
3.01
0
19
pv_7
Research, development and deployment (Total RD&D in Million USD, 2015 price and exch. rates)
464
94.38
208.52
0
2,442.68
167 168
2.2 Model
169
2.2.1 Variable intercept panel model
170
A panel model can be categorized into three types: pooled regression model, variable intercept
171
model and variable coefficient model [19]. A pooled regression model is a basic panel data model
172
that assumes each individual in the sample has exactly the same regression equation; that is to say,
173
the intercept and coefficient of the model would not change with individuals and time. A variable
174
intercept model assumes the individual's regression equation has the same coefficient while different
175
intercepts to capture the heterogeneity, and it means that the impact of unobserved effects can be
176
absorbed into the intercept term. A variable coefficient model is suitable in the cases where there
177
are changing economic structures or unobserved different socioeconomic and demographic
178
background factors that imply that the response parameters of the included variables may be varying
179
over time or may be different for different cross-sectional units [20]. Thus, it means that generally
180
a variable intercept model or a pooled regression model is picked. Hence, this paper conducts an F-
181
test to identify which method to use.
182
Furthermore, given that it generally takes time to implement policies, the policy variables, except 10
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 183
control variables, are l-period lagged in our research. The model to estimate is
184
Ykt const i X ikt l ' jCjkt uk kt
i
j
i 1
j 1
(1)
185
where k is country and t is year. Ykt denotes the development of renewable energy. const is the
186
national entity intercept. X is a vector of the i policy variables. βi is the coefficient of policy variable.
187
C is a vector of the j control variables. β’j is the coefficient of control variable. uk+εkt is composite
188
error term, unobservable random variable uk is intercept term of individual heterogeneity, εkt is a
189
disturbance term that varies with time and individual.
190
Table 2 presents the summary statistics for the results of model tests. F-test is to identify whether
191
pooled regression model or variable intercept model is suitable; Hausman test and Auxiliary
192
regression are to select the fixed effect model or the random effect model. Specifically, for F-test,
193
“H0: all uk =0”, that is, a pooled regression model is acceptable. For Hausman test and Auxiliary
194
regression test, “H0: no correlation between uk and X”, that is, random effect model is correct model.
195
The p-value of F-test is 0.00 shown in Table 2, so the original hypothesis is therefore strongly
196
rejected. Moreover, ρ represents the autocorrelation coefficient between the disturbance terms of
197
different individuals in different periods. The greater the value of ρ is, the more important the
198
individual effect part of the composite error term is. In Table 2, “ρ=0.97” indicates that the variance
199
of composite error term is mainly due to the variation of individual effect. Consequently, the variable
200
intercept model is adopted in the model evaluation.
201
Table 2 Hausman test and F-test results
202 203
Test type
ρ
F-value
Chi-Square Statistic
P-value
F-test Hausman test Auxiliary regression
0.97 -
40.21 -
61.83 81.38
0.00 0.00 0.00
2.2.2 Fixed effect model and random effect model 11
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 204
A variable intercept model can be further divided into a fixed effect (FE) model and a random
205
effect model [19]. It is a basic problem to use the fixed effect model or the random effect model
206
when we address the panel data. In a fixed effect model, the individual effect or time effect is
207
interrelated to the independent variables, whereas in a random effect model, the individual effect or
208
time effect is not relative to explanatory variables. In other words, the random-effects model allows
209
one to estimate the coefficients of both time-varying and time-invariant variables while the fixed-
210
effects model allows us only to estimate the coefficients of time-varying explanatory variables [20].
211
When N (This paper is 29, which refers to the number of countries) is larger relative to T (This paper
212
is 16, which refers to the time series), whether to treat the effects as fixed or random is not an easy
213
question to answer. It can make a surprising amount of difference in the estimates of the parameters.
214
Zhao et al. [21] used the Hausman test to identify the specific model of whether it is a fixed effect
215
or a random effect. However, the traditional Hausman test assumes that the random effect is fully
216
efficient, which means that both uk and εkt must be independently and identically distributed.
217
Therefore, the traditional Hausman test is not applicable if the error of the clustering robust standard
218
is quite different from that of the ordinary standard. To avoid this situation, in this paper, the
219
Hausman test is done and the auxiliary regression with test is further conducted. It can be seen from
220
the data in Table 2 that the original hypothesis is rejected for both p-values are 0.00 in Hausman test
221
and Auxiliary regression test, meaning that a fixed effect is suitable.
222
The variable intercept model with fixed effects is as Eq. (2). The variables are measured as
223
logarithms, since the logarithm of the data will not change the nature and relationship, and
224
simultaneously is helpful to heteroscedasticity elimination.
225
ln Ykt const i ln Xikt l ' j ln Cjkt uk kt
i
j
i 1
j 1
(2) 12
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 226 227 228
Furthermore, we add the dummy variable of the Kyoto Protocol as a virtual variable for panel empirical study. i
j
i 1
j 1
ln Ykt const i ln Xikt l ' j ln Cjkt Dkt uk kt
229
Where Dkt =1 denotes the Kyoto Protocol is implemented.
230
To examine the effectiveness of specific policy, this paper set up model (4).
231
232 233
r
j
r 1
j 1
ln Ykt const 1r ln X 'rkt l ' j ln Cjkt Dkt uk kt
(3)
(4)
where X ’is a vector of the r specific policy variables and β1r is the coefficient of specific policy. 3. Results and Discussion
234
The aim of this research is to uncover the influence of different policy instruments on the installed
235
capacity of renewable energy and conduct further discussion between cluster and specific policies
236
among typical countries. Table 3 presents the results based on Eq. (3) and Eq. (4). FE(1) is the
237
regression results of aggregate policy, and FE(2) is the deletion of the insignificant variable on the
238
basis of FE(1) to identify the robustness of our model. The results show that in terms of the positive
239
or negative effects of the regression on renewable energy capacity, both models generate very
240
similar results, including the R2 values. FE(3) is the regression results of specific policy on the basis
241
of FE(2). The empirical results of aggregate and specific policies are shown in Fig. 3, which present
242
the ranking of policies impacts and standard error bars.
13
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
243 244
Fig. 3 The ranking of policies impacts
245
As is well-known, the Kyoto Protocol has played a vital role in the climate change mitigation and
246
renewable energy development. The results in Table 3 confirm its notable effect on renewables.
247
Furthermore, the ranking of aggregate policies impacts on renewable energy development shown in
248
Fig. 3 is market-based instruments, RD&D, fiscal and financial incentives, and policy support.
249
Specifically, our results imply that every 1 percentage point increase in these four aggregate policies,
250
respectively, is associated with an approximately 0.300, 0.210, 0.182, 0.163 percentage point
251
increase in renewable energy capacity at the 1% significance level. For the specific policy model,
252
PP, GS, SP are positive policies at the significance level of 1%, 1% and 5%, respectively. The
253
contribution to renewable energy is increased by 0.191, 0.163, 0.167 percentage point for every 1
254
percentage point increase in PP, GS, SP. Additionally, significant are the four control variables in
255
all models, specifically, GDP, High-technology exports, and Electric power consumption, which are
256
positively related to the renewables capacity, while the remaining variable of CO2 emissions 14
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 257
negatively affects the dependent variable. In the following discussion, we highlight effective and
258
ineffective policy measures and relate our results to the following previous studies [3,4,11,16].
259
Table 3 Panel analysis results
Variables
FE(1)
FE(2)
coefficient
S.E.
coefficient
S.E.
cv_gdp cv_hte cv_co2 cv_epc
2.265** 0.361** -1.051** 0.210**
0.277 0.106 0.193 0.048
2.168** 0.369** -1.050** 0.209**
0.266 0.106 0.189 0.048
pv_1
0.182**
0.057
0.152**
0.052
pv_2
0.299**
0.088
0.286**
0.085
pv_3
-0.062
0.073
/
/
pv_4
0.163**
0.056
0.134**
0.051
pv_5 pv_6 pv_7 d_k cons R-sq
-0.063 -0.016 0.210** 0.522** -14.570** 0.801
0.060 0.070 0.046 0.072 2.393
/ / 0.213** 0.523** -13.740** 0.800
/ / 0.045 0.070 2.303
260
Note: Standard errors * p<0.05, ** p<0.01
261
3.1 Fiscal and financial incentives
Variables cv_gdp cv_hte cv_co2 cv_epc PP GS T GA GC / IC SP / / pv_7 d_k cons R-sq
FE(3)
coefficient
S.E.
2.120** 0.420** -1.092** 0.221** 0.191** 0.163** -0.048 0.315 0.188 / 0.001 0.167* / / 0.191** 0.546** -13.320** 0.803
0.272 0.104 0.191 0.048 0.063 0.066 0.099 0.177 0.112 / 0.097 0.074 / / 0.047 0.068 2.354
262
It is found that fiscal and financial incentives have positive impacts on renewable energy
263
installation, which implies that the fiscal and financial incentives effects on renewable power
264
development is notably strong. In addition, the specific policies effects regressed in Eq. (4) show
265
that the coefficient of price policy, grants and subsidies are statistically significant, which means
266
they have played a substantial role in the fiscal and financial package and have large positive effects
267
on renewable energy promotion.
268
In the process of renewable energy development, each country provides renewable energy support
269
from the electricity price policy, feed-in tariffs (FIT) and Feed-in premium (FIP) are generally used. 15
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 270
The FIT can be described as a premium paid for electricity that is supplied to an electricity grid from
271
a particular renewable energy generation source [22]. It is minimum price guaranteed by the national
272
governments for per unit of renewable electricity supplied to the grid for a long-term [23]. Grid
273
enterprises must pay the cost to renewable energy generation enterprises at such price. FIP is a type
274
of price-based policy instrument whereby eligible renewable energy generators are paid a premium
275
price, which is a payment in addition to the wholesale price. This premium can be fixed or floating.
276
Price policy proved particularly successful in countries such as China, Germany, and Spain. The
277
main features of this instrument are ensuring the stability of renewable energy projects and attracting
278
all types of social capital into the field of renewable energy. For investors, it is an important market
279
signal, and the adjustment of electricity price can also reflect the level of technological progress to
280
a certain extent. Thus, this research is in accordance with evidence by Del Río and Bleda [24], who
281
emphasize the advantages of price policy to spur development and to lower risks in renewable
282
energy investment. From the perspective of policy evolution, the price policy was implemented
283
beginning with three countries in 2000, and it had been implemented in 21 countries of 29 sample
284
countries by 2015. It has played an important role in promoting the large-scale development of
285
renewable energy generation.
286
Grants and subsidies are the means by which the government provides financial aid or other forms
287
of income or price as the measures of support for the purpose of developing renewable energy
288
without direct capital gains or returns. From the perspective of evolution, this policy is a commonly
289
adopted policy in various countries. This policy, on the one hand, subsidizes production and
290
subsidies for renewable energy producers. On the other hand, subsidies are made for the output of
291
renewable energy equipment, which will increase production, reduce costs and improve economic 16
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 292
efficiency.
293
However, tax instruments are not significant for promoting renewable energy development. This
294
is a surprising result since the primary objective of such an instrument is to financially enhance
295
renewables. Johnstone et al. [25] related this situation to the fact that investors may have little or no
296
confidence in policies that depend on public finance, since they are likely to be withdrawn abruptly
297
with a change in administration. A good example is the Production Tax Credit for wind power in
298
the United States. This tax instrument has had a pattern of repeated expiration and short-term
299
renewal (usually no more than a couple of years), creating a boom-bust cycle in investment in this
300
technology over years, which is also believed to be damaging the industry's prospects due to the
301
uncertainty it creates (see [26]). In addition, although the industry agrees on the necessity of a five-
302
to ten-year incentive, legislators do not want to be associated with large spending programs, which
303
is why the Production Tax Credit is likely to remain as a two-year address option of renewal
304
indefinitely. Another source of uncertainty for tax incentive is economic downturn, particularly
305
during a financial crisis, when there are limited resources to support these measures. It would thus
306
be that the issue with the lack of positive reinforcement of renewable energy by tax instrument is a
307
result of the uncertainty of the policies. Gan et al. [5] also criticize how these measures do not
308
necessarily guarantee the achievement of their expected targets.
309
This paper confirms the findings reported by Marques and Fuinhas [3], who show that fiscal and
310
financial incentives policies are positive to increasing the contribution of renewables to the total
311
energy supply. In addition, this research confirms that a variety of policies comprising specific and
312
technology measures spur renewable energy technology deployment, higher income through grants
313
and subsidies, and lower capital costs through price policy support investors to increase renewable 17
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 314
energy capacity. In sum, the price policy is a strong signal for investors, because it adjusts the risk
315
or reward structure to address capital market constraints. Grants and subsidies policy is proven to
316
be effective short-term measures to ease fiscal constraints. Tax incentives reduce the tax burden of
317
renewable energy enterprises and increase the competitiveness of renewable energy, but need a
318
stable policy environment.
319
3.2 Market-based instruments
320
This empirical research also provides evidence for market-based instruments including
321
greenhouse gas emissions allowances (GA), green certificates (GC) and white certificates (WC).
322
Many sample countries have not yet implemented the white certificates policy, only South Korea
323
and Italy introduced this instrument in 2007 and 2011, respectively (data from IEA/IRENA policies
324
and measures database); therefore, we mainly focus on greenhouse gas emissions allowances and
325
green certificates.
326
The separate policies of greenhouse gas emissions allowances or green certificates have no
327
significant effects in promoting renewable energy; however, the aggregate policy of market-based
328
instruments has a strong impact on renewable capacity expansion at the 1% significance level. This
329
indicates that synergy effects do exist between these two specific policies; that is to say, the
330
implementation of market-based instruments require the combination of greenhouse gas emissions
331
allowances and green certificates. On the one hand, greenhouse gas emissions allowances and green
332
certificates have different starting points: greenhouse gas emissions allowances is aimed at carbon
333
dioxide emission reduction and at solving the problem of greenhouse gas emissions, while the green
334
certificate is aimed at promoting the utilization of renewable energy and solving the problem of the
335
adjustment of energy structure. On the other hand, the two policies are essentially reducing 18
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 336
greenhouse gas emissions by means of market-based instruments. The empirical analysis shows that
337
the combination of the two specific policies plays a very important role in the promotion of
338
renewable energy. Hence, the combination of greenhouse gas emissions allowances and green
339
certificates might be the most effective way to push the entire society to achieve energy
340
transformation with the least cost.
341
3.3 Direct investments
342
The class of policy “Direct investments” includes funds to sub-national governments (FSG),
343
infrastructure investments (II). The results from empirical analysis revealed that this type of
344
instrument is ineffective in promoting renewable energy capacity. We hereby confirm earlier works
345
(based on Multiple renewable energy analyses) that resulted in that this form of direct investment
346
did not spur renewable energy development [16]. This stands in contrast to previous literature that
347
highlights the grid expansion as conducive to renewable energy deployment and investment [27].
348
Funds to sub-national governments are a direct investment of federal money, with regional, local or
349
municipal level entities as targets. Infrastructure investment to provide grid access seem ineffective
350
for channeling investors’ money into renewable energy technologies, according to the paper [16].
351
The reasons for non-significant results in this paper might lie in the different structure of different
352
renewable energy technologies, which have different regional focuses and scales of power plants.
353
3.4 Policy support
354
Certain policies and measures seek to define strategies and outline specific programs to promote
355
renewable capacity within a country. These measures are tracked as policy support, which includes
356
institutional creation (IC) and strategic planning (SP). The empirical results indicate that policy
357
support instruments accelerated the capacity additions in the renewable energy sector effectively in 19
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 358
the period of 2000 to 2015.
359
From the perspective of specific policy, institutional creation is insignificant to promoting
360
renewables capacity, while strategic planning has positive effects on the development of renewable
361
energy, as investors favor a long-term stable policy environment.
362
As shown in Fig. 3, the coefficient of aggregate policy (That is, the combination of institutional
363
creation and strategic planning policy) has no significant differences than that of the strategic
364
planning instrument. While it can be seen from the data in Table 3 that the aggregate policy group
365
(Significant at 1% level) reported more significance than the specific policy group (Significant at
366
5% level). Indicating that the combination of institutional creation and strategic planning policy
367
might promotes the effects of strategic planning policy. Institutional creation, such as the
368
implementation of an energy agency, might accelerates the deployment of strategic planning
369
effectively.
370
With this analysis, the empirical results are in support of the strong role that institutional creation
371
and a long-term policy commitment play in an effective policy mix. Commitment, creation, stability,
372
reliability and predictability are all elements that increase confidence of market actors, reduce
373
regulatory risks, and reduce the cost of capital. Thus, the results of this study confirm empirical
374
works that indicate clear strategic long-term economic instruments are conductive to renewable
375
energy development. Therefore, long-term policies for the stable environment through strategic
376
planning and probably through institutional creation will support the long-term development of
377
renewable energy.
378
3.5 Regulatory instruments and information and education
379
According to Table 3, the regulatory instrument is insignificant in the stage of renewable energy 20
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 380
development. Gan et al. [5] state that regulatory instruments appear to have been the most effective
381
in promoting renewable energy development, while the empirical results in this paper are
382
inconsistent with the this view reported by Gan et al. (2007). Furthermore, there are cases in the
383
previous literature where even more details about the policies do not generate the expected results.
384
For example, Polzin et al. [16] note that regulatory mechanisms and the institutionalization of
385
markets in the form of regulatory instruments also attract institutional investors, while the empirical
386
results are not significant. Aguirre and Ibikunle [4] did not find significance for regulatory
387
instruments. This result is aligned with those from Marques and Fuinhas [3]. Furthermore, measures
388
and policies belonging to the “Information and education”, such as Advice/Aid in Implementation,
389
Information provision, do not yet seem to be relevant in stimulating the renewable deployment.
390
3.6 Research, development and deployment (RD&D)
391
To capture the effect of RD&D to renewable energy installment, we use Detailed Country RD&D
392
Budgets of renewable energy as a proxy, taken from the IEA's Energy Technology Research and
393
Development Database. In the 1970s, the renewables policy framework was dominated by Research
394
and Development programs [4]. In this paper, we evaluate how effective and significant the policy
395
instruments are in promoting renewable energy deployment. The results suggest that RD&D is an
396
important factor to facilitate renewables in typical countries. This is reflected by a high level of
397
statistical significance, at the 1% significance level, and positive relationship between the RD&D
398
budget variable and the dependent variable. As renewable technologies are still expensive and thus
399
cannot compete with fossil fuel technologies, RD&D was needed to reduce costs and create more
400
advanced renewable energy technologies.
401
3.7 Non-policy variables 21
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 402
Besides the above policy variables, GDP, high-technology exports, CO2 emissions, electric power
403
consumption, and the Kyoto Protocol are statistically significant non-policy variables at the 1%
404
significance level. Out of these non-policy variables, CO2 emissions negatively related to the
405
dependent variable, while the remaining variables positively affected renewables deployment. It is
406
worth noting that the implement of Kyoto Protocol in 2005 was a key international milestone in
407
carbon emission, which shocked the policymakers in their minds and promoted the transformation
408
of the world development philosophy on low-carbon economy. Although some countries failed to
409
achieve the goal of reducing emissions because of the high cost of low carbon development in the
410
short term, a large number of countries are committed to search for a low-carbon development path
411
in the long run. It is undeniable that the low carbon development philosophy will promote the
412
renewable energy deployment in the long term, which is an effective way to emission reduction.
413
4. Conclusions
414
This paper focuses on a panel of 29 typical countries for the time span 2000-2015 to characterize
415
the effectiveness of public policies regarding renewables. This research adds empirical evaluation
416
of specific policies on renewables to uncover the effects of different policies on renewables
417
development and detail function of specific instruments in aggregate policies.
418
The analysis demonstrates that certain aggregate public policies have been drivers toward the
419
development of renewables. On the one hand, four of seven aggregate measures have produced the
420
desired effect of increasing renewable energy power capacity in the period analyzed. The ranking
421
of aggregate policies impacts is, market-based instruments, research, development and deployment
422
(RD&D), fiscal and financial incentives, and policy support. Specifically, regressions indicate that
423
for a 10 percentage point increase in these four policies, countries will install respectively 3.00%, 22
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 424
2.10%, 1.82%, 1.63% more renewable energy capacity per year on average. However, the other
425
three aggregate measures, including direct investments, regulatory instruments, information and
426
education, have not yet been effective in fostering renewable energy use in these target countries.
427
For the specific policies, price policy, grants and subsidies are the stable instruments of fiscal and
428
financial incentives to promote the development of renewable energy. For policy support
429
instruments, strategic planning was the main effect policy to spur renewable energy development
430
while institutional creation was not. We find that for a 10 percentage point increase in price policy,
431
grants and subsidies, and strategic planning, countries will install 1.91%, 1.63%, 1.67% more
432
renewable energy capacity per year on average.
433
This paper assesses the aggregate policy and their specific ones in the same analysis framework,
434
and the empirical results found that synergy effects do exist among specific policies, so it is vital
435
for policy makers to incorporate specific mix and economic conditions into the policy design. For
436
example, separate policies of greenhouse gas emissions allowances or green certificates have an
437
insignificant effect while their combination (that is, the aggregate policy of market-based incentives)
438
has a positive influence on renewable energy capacity at the 1% significance level. It is worth noting
439
that market-based instruments should be given special attention in promoting renewable power
440
development in the future. In the formulation of market-oriented policies, integrating greenhouse
441
gas emissions allowances and green certificates policies may be a better solution to avoid policy
442
failure. On the one hand, countries can directly control greenhouse gas emissions through
443
greenhouse gas emissions allowances policy, such as setting a cap on the permitted amount of
444
emissions and distributing a corresponding number of allowances globally. On the other hand, they
445
set indirect energy means through green certificates instrument to increase the proportion of 23
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 446
renewable energy consumption and reduce greenhouse gas emissions. In addition, the specific
447
policy of institutional creation has insignificant effects while the specific policy of strategic planning
448
has positively effects (at the 5% significance level) on the development of renewable energy. It is
449
worth noting that their combination has a more significant effect (at the 1% significance level) on
450
the development of renewable energy, which indicates that institutional creation promotes the
451
effects of strategic planning.
452
The empirical results highlighted that implementation of the Kyoto Protocol in 2005 has positive
453
impact on renewable energy deployment in typical countries. In fact, due to the entry into force of
454
the Kyoto Protocol, many countries have introduced renewable energy development policies to
455
promote renewable energy development. The empirical results also indicate that GDP, electric
456
power consumption, and high-technology exports, which are control variables in the model, are
457
confirmed to have positive effects on the continuous development of renewables. However, CO2
458
emissions, another control variable in the model, have a negative impact on the deployment of
459
renewables.
460
Overall, the empirical results suggest that the development of renewables has been established
461
essentially upon direct subsidies, strategy plans and RD&D while market-oriented policy
462
instruments should be the greenhouse gas emissions allowances and green certificates mixes. With
463
the increase of government subsidies and expenditure, the further direction of renewables is market-
464
driven logic instead of policy-driven logic; therefore, the appropriate design of market-oriented
465
policy instruments need to be discussed further.
466
Acknowledgements
467
The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees and the editor of this journal. The authors 24
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 468
also gratefully acknowledge the financial support of the Major Program of the National Social
469
Science Fund of China (Grant No. 15ZDB165).
470
References
471 472 473 474 475 476 477 478 479 480 481 482 483 484 485 486 487 488 489 490 491 492 493 494 495 496 497 498 499 500 501 502 503 504 505 506 507 508
[1]
BP, BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2017, Br. Pet. (2017) 1–52. http://www.bp.com/content/dam/bp/en/corporate/pdf/energy-economics/statistical-review2017/bp-statistical-review-of-world-energy-2017-full-report.pdf.
[2]
S. Zhang, P. Andrews-Speed, X. Zhao, Y. He, Interactions between renewable energy policy and renewable energy industrial policy: A critical analysis of china’s policy approach to renewable energies, Energy Policy. 62 (2013) 342–353. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.063.
[3]
A.C. Marques, J.A. Fuinhas, Are public policies towards renewables successful? Evidence from European countries, Renew. Energy. 44 (2012) 109–118. doi:10.1016/j.renene.2012.01.007.
[4]
M. Aguirre, G. Ibikunle, Determinants of renewable energy growth: A global sample analysis, Energy Policy. 69 (2014) 374–384. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2014.02.036.
[5]
L. Gan, G.S. Eskeland, H.H. Kolshus, Green electricity market development: Lessons from Europe and the US, Energy Policy. 35 (2007) 144–155. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2005.10.008.
[6]
C. Liao, H. Ou, S. Lo, P. Chiueh, Y. Yu, A challenging approach for renewable energy market development, Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 15 (2011) 787–793. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2010.09.047.
[7]
K. Patlitzianas, K. Karagounis, The progress of RES environment in the most recent member states of the EU, Renew. Energy. 36 (2011) 429–436. doi:10.1016/j.renene.2010.08.032.
[8]
F.C. Menz, S. Vachon, The effectiveness of different policy regimes for promoting wind power: Experiences from the states, Energy Policy. 34 (2006) 1786–1796. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2004.12.018.
[9]
S. Carley, State renewable energy electricity policies: An empirical evaluation of effectiveness, Energy Policy. 37 (2009) 3071–3081. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.03.062.
[10]
M.A. Delmas, M.J. Montes-Sancho, U.S. state policies for renewable energy: Context and effectiveness, Energy Policy. 39 (2011) 2273–2288. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.01.034.
[11]
N. Johnstone, I. Haščič, D. Popp, Renewable energy policies and technological innovation: Evidence based on patent counts, Environ. Resour. Econ. 45 (2010) 133–155. doi:10.1007/s10640-009-9309-1.
[12]
Y. Zhao, K. Ki, L. Wang, Do renewable electricity policies promote renewable electricity generation ? Evidence from panel data, Energy Policy. 62 (2013) 887–897. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.072.
[13]
C.G. Dong, Feed-in tariff vs. renewable portfolio standard: An empirical test of their relative effectiveness in promoting wind capacity development, Energy Policy. 42 (2012) 476–485. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.12.014.
[14]
D. De Jager, M. Rathmann, Policy instrument design to reduce financing costs in renewable energy technology projects Policy instrument design to reduce financing costs in renewable energy technology projects, (2008) 142. http://www.ecofys.com/files/files/retd_pid0810_main.pdf. 25
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 509 510 511 512 513 514 515 516 517 518 519 520 521 522 523 524 525 526 527 528 529 530 531 532 533 534 535 536 537 538 539 540 541
[15]
L. Bird, M. Bolinger, T. Gagliano, R. Wiser, M. Brown, B. Parsons, Policies and market factors driving wind power development in the United States, Energy Policy. 33 (2005) 1397–1407. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2003.12.018.
[16]
F. Polzin, M. Migendt, F.A. Täube, P. von Flotow, Public policy influence on renewable energy investments-A panel data study across OECD countries, Energy Policy. 80 (2015) 98– 111. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2015.01.026.
[17]
I. Renewable, E. Agency, Renewable Energy Statistics 2017, 2017.
[18]
D. Popp, I. Hascic, N. Medhi, Technology and the diffusion of renewable energy, Energy Econ. 33 (2011) 648–662. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2010.08.007.
[19]
X. Zhao, S. Li, S. Zhang, R. Yang, S. Liu, The effectiveness of China’s wind power policy: An empirical analysis, Energy Policy. 95 (2016) 269–279. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2016.04.050.
[20]
C. Hsiao, Analysis of panel data 3th Edition, 2014. doi:10.1017/CBO9780511754203.
[21]
H. Zhao, H. Zhao, X. Han, Z. He, S. Guo, Economic Growth, Electricity Consumption, Labor Force and Capital Input: A More Comprehensive Analysis on North China Using Panel Data, Energies. 9 (2016) 891. doi:10.3390/en9110891.
[22]
L. Poruschi, C.L. Ambrey, J.C.R. Smart, Revisiting feed-in tariffs in Australia: A review, Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 82 (2018) 260–270. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2017.09.027.
[23]
M. del P. Pablo-Romero, A. S�nchez-Braza, J. Salvador-Ponce, N. S�nchez-Labrador, An overview of feed-in tariffs, premiums and tenders to promote electricity from biogas in the EU28, Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 73 (2017) 1366–1379. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2017.01.132.
[24]
P. Del Río, M. Bleda, Comparing the innovation effects of support schemes for renewable electricity technologies: A function of innovation approach, Energy Policy. 50 (2012) 272–282. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.07.014.
[25]
N. Johnstone, I. Haščič, D. Popp, Renewable energy policies and technological innovation: Evidence based on patent counts, Environ. Resour. Econ. 45 (2010) 133–155. doi:10.1007/s10640-009-9309-1.
[26]
M.J. Barradale, Impact of public policy uncertainty on renewable energy investment: Wind power and the production tax credit, Energy Policy. 38 (2010) 7698–7709. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.08.021.
[27]
D. Jager de, C. Klessmann, E. Stricker, T. Winkel, E. Visser de, M. Koper, M. Ragwitz, A. Held, G. Resch, S. Busch, C. Panzer, A. Gazzo, T. Roulleau, P. Gousseland, M. Henriet, A. Bouillé, Financing Renewable Energy in the European Energy Market Financing Renewable Energy in the European Energy Market, (2011). doi:10.13140/2.1.3115.2645.
542
26
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
HIGHLIGHTS
Panel data study on the effectiveness of renewable energy policies to promote RE development.
Four of seven aggregate policies are positively significant to RE capacity increase especially Market-based instruments and RD&D.
Three of twelve specific policies have significant positive effects on RE capacity including price policy, grants and subsidies, and strategic planning.
Synergy effects do exist among specific policies in renewable energy increase.