Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data analysis

Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data analysis

Accepted Manuscript Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data analysis Wenfeng Liu, Xingping Zhang, Sida Feng PII: S0960-1481(18...

NAN Sizes 0 Downloads 54 Views

Accepted Manuscript Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data analysis

Wenfeng Liu, Xingping Zhang, Sida Feng PII:

S0960-1481(18)31468-X

DOI:

10.1016/j.renene.2018.12.037

Reference:

RENE 10912

To appear in:

Renewable Energy

Received Date:

20 March 2018

Accepted Date:

09 December 2018

Please cite this article as: Wenfeng Liu, Xingping Zhang, Sida Feng, Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data analysis, Renewable Energy (2018), doi: 10.1016/j.renene. 2018.12.037

This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

1

Does renewable energy policy work? Evidence from a panel data

2

analysis

3

Wenfeng Liua, b, Xingping Zhanga, c, , Sida Fenga

4

a

5

China

6

b

7

Power University), Changping Beijing, 102206, China

8

c

9

Abstract

School of Economics and Management, North China Electric Power University, Beijing, 102206,

Beijing Key Laboratory of New Energy and Low-Carbon Development (North China Electric

Research Center for Beijing Energy Development, Beijing 102206, China

10

This paper develops a fixed effect model to evaluate the effect of renewable energy policy using

11

a panel dataset covering 29 countries during the period of 2000 to 2015. The renewable energy

12

policy system in this paper includes seven aggregate policies and twelve specific ones. The

13

empirical results indicate that four of seven aggregate policies, including fiscal and financial

14

incentives, market-based instruments, policy support, and research, development and deployment,

15

are demonstrated to be significant to the improvement of renewable energy capacity. Meanwhile,

16

three of twelve specific policies, including price policy, grants and subsidies, and strategic planning,

17

have positive effects on renewable energy development. This paper assesses the aggregate and

18

specific policies in the same analysis framework, and the empirical results determined that synergy

19

effects existed among specific policies. The empirical results also indicate that the implementation

20

of the Kyoto Protocol in 2005 has had positive impacts on renewable energy development in typical



Corresponding author: Tel.: +86 10 61773096; fax: +86 10 61773311.

E-mail address: [email protected] (X. Zhang). 1

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 21

countries.

22

Keywords: Renewable energy policy; Policy effect assessment; Panel data model

23

1. Introduction

24

Climate change has become more pronounced in recent years, as CO2 emissions have continued

25

to grow worldwide. The countries researched in this paper emitted more than 70% of the entire

26

world carbon emissions in 2016 [1], and they have set quantitative targets for renewable energy

27

development, which is a key option to mitigate the climate change. Based on this background, public

28

renewable policies have been components of national planning agenda for many developed and

29

several large developing countries over the past several decades.

30

There is broad consensus in the literature concerning the need for public policy to promote

31

renewable energy development. First, the renewable energy policies are aimed at promoting the

32

development and deployment of renewable energy, which provides a sustainable and stable

33

domestic renewable energy market [2]. Second, the development of renewables that internalize the

34

costs of no pollution deserves incentives from public policies. Third, reducing energy dependence

35

is an important factor in introducing the public policy [3]. Finally, the compliance of international

36

agreements, such as the Kyoto Protocol, European Union directives or a long-term development

37

plan for renewable energy, are also indicated as other factors requiring the design of public policy.

38

Hence, many countries and international organizations view renewables as important elements of

39

energy security, dynamic economic development, environmental protection and greenhouse gas

40

emissions reduction efforts [4]. There are a variety of incentives and regulations to choose to support

41

renewables development; therefore, it is vital to assess the effectiveness of public policies for

42

renewables. A majority of published studies have qualitatively or theoretically discussed the 2

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 43

effectiveness of RE policies in the US or EU [5,6,7], while a minority present quantitative analyses.

44

Menz and Vachon [8] was the pioneering study to quantitatively assess the effectiveness of different

45

state policies that promote wind power, and several scholars have attempted to quantify the impacts

46

of renewable energy policies in different directions subsequently. First, many studies have focused

47

on analyzing the effectiveness of renewable energy policies at the state or provincial level. Several

48

state level studies have reached a positive conclusion. For instance, Menz and Vachon [8] assessed

49

the policies' relative effectiveness in terms of their impact on the level of wind capacity existing in

50

states of the US, finding a positive relationship between the renewable portfolio standard (RPS) and

51

wind power development. While others found mixed results, Carley [9] evaluated the effectiveness

52

of state energy programs with an empirical investigation of the linkage between state RPS policy

53

implementation and the percentage of renewable energy electricity generation across states in the

54

US, and the results indicate that RPS implementation is not a significant predictor of the percentage

55

of renewable energy generation in the total generation mix but increases the total amount of

56

renewable energy generation. Against this background, researchers have started to question whether

57

the effectiveness of renewable energy policies is conditional on the social, natural and institutional

58

environment. For instance, Delmas and Montes-Sancho [10] argued that a large presence of non-

59

governmental organizations, democratic representatives, and green residential customers facilitate

60

the transmission of renewable energy policies in the US.

61

There are also studies analyzing the effectiveness of renewable energy policies at the country

62

level. Johnstone et al. [11] examined the effect of environmental policies using panel data for 25

63

OECD countries during the period of 1978 to 2003 and found that public policy plays a significant

64

role in different renewable technological innovation. Based on this, Zhao et al. [12] evaluated the 3

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 65

effects of renewable electricity policies on renewable electricity generation using a large panel

66

dataset that covers 122 countries including developed, developing, and emerging market countries

67

during the period of 1980 to 2010. The results suggest that renewable electricity policies play a

68

crucial role in promoting renewable electricity generation, but their effectiveness is subject to

69

diminishing returns as the number of policies increases. In addition, there are several cross-country

70

studies investigating the relative effectiveness of different policy mechanisms. For instance, Dong

71

[13] examined the relative effectiveness of feed-in tariff (FIT) and RPS in promoting wind capacity

72

development using panel data covers 53 countries including the US, China, Germany, Spain, India

73

etc. Fiscal and financial incentives were demonstrated to accelerate the development of renewable

74

energy projects [14,15]; furthermore, mandatory requirements, quota, and obligation schemes do

75

exhibit a positive influence on renewable energy application in the US [8].

76

This study attempts to quantitatively assess the effectiveness of renewable energy public policies

77

on renewable energy and extends previous studies in two ways. First, empirical analyses of the

78

combination of aggregate and specific policies effectiveness remain scarce. The few existing studies,

79

such as that of Zhao et al. [12], primarily focus on aggregate renewable energy policies, while Polzin

80

et al. [16] mainly focus on specific renewable energy policies across OECD countries. In this paper,

81

we assess the effectiveness of aggregate and specific policies in the same analysis framework, which

82

can provide notable policy implications. Second, the Kyoto Protocol, a key international milestone,

83

has experienced an important impacts on the formulation of renewable energy policies in various

84

countries, we therefore incorporate it into model in the form of dummy variable. In addition, several

85

control variables are introduced into the model to reduce the deviations of missing variables in this

86

paper. 4

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 87

The remaining sections of this paper are structured as follows: Section 2 presents the data and the

88

analytical method. Section 3 presents the results and discussion, while section 4 presents the study’s

89

conclusion and policy implications.

90

2. Methods and Data

91

2.1 Variables and data sources

92

As dictated by the availability of data, 29 countries from the EU, the OECD, the signatories of

93

the Kyoto Protocol and two developing countries (China and India), are the study sample in this

94

paper. The reason for choosing these countries is that these countries have great support for

95

renewable energy policies and the scale of renewable energy in these countries has increased stably.

96

Fig. 1 shows the growing trend of renewables installation and the reduction of carbon dioxide

97

emissions following the time that the Kyoto Protocol entry into force in the sample countries.

98 99

Fig. 1 Total installed and new added capacity of renewable energy 5

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 100

Specifically, the sample countries in this paper include Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada,

101

China, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, India, Ireland,

102

Italy, Japan, Mexico, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, South Korea, Spain,

103

Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the United States of America. Many

104

countries have generally focused on the question of the development of renewable energy from

105

approximately 2000. Hence, we consider the data index of the stability and availability, and

106

therefore choose 2000 as the starting year and 2015 as the ending year.

107 Policy variables

Dummy variable

The Kyoto dummy (d_k)

Fiscal and financial incentives (pv_1) Price policy (PP) Grants and subsidies (GS) Tax (T) Market-based instruments (pv_2) GHG emissions allowances (GA) Green certificates (GC) Direct investments (pv_3) Funds to sub-national governments (FSG) Infrastructure investments (II)

Dependent variable Total capacity installed-renewable energies (in MW) RE_capacity (re_c)

Policy support (pv_4) Institutional creation (IC) Strategic planning (SP) Regulatory instruments (pv_5) Codes and standards (CS) Obligation schemes (OS) Other mandatory requirements (OMR)

Control variables

108 109

Real Gross Domestic Product (cv_gdp)

Carbon dioxide emissions (cv_co2)

Electric power consumption (cv_epc)

High-technology exports (cv_hte)

Information and education (pv_6)

Research, development and deployment (pv_7)

Fig. 2 Framework of variables

110

Fig. 2 shows the framework of variables. The data of dependent variable (renewable energy

111

capacity) is from the International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA), which is an

112

intergovernmental organization that supports countries in their transition to a sustainable energy 6

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 113

future and serves as the principal platform for international co-operation and a repository of policy,

114

technology, resource and financial knowledge on renewable energy [17]. These data include

115

information on installed electricity generating capacity, additions in renewable energy capacity and

116

renewable energy power generation at the country level.

117

We consider that the commitment to reduce greenhouse gas emissions and the emission-trading

118

scheme are substantial factors driving renewables development. The Kyoto Protocol signed in 1998

119

was a milestone in promoting carbon reduction. One of the key international steps in this direction

120

was the implementation of the Kyoto Protocol in 2005. Countries that signed this protocol are

121

expected to have great commitment to renewables deployment, as shown by Popp et al. [18].

122

Although the Kyoto Protocol was signed in 1998, there was no legal effect at that time. The Kyoto

123

Protocol entry into force in 2005, it is the first time to restrict greenhouse gas emissions in the form

124

of regulations. Therefore, this paper takes the time of 2005 to set up variable. In this paper, dummy

125

variable is used: The Kyoto Protocol dummy (variable d_k) is 1 for the implementation countries

126

after 2005 and 0 otherwise. We expect a positive relationship between renewables capacity and the

127

Kyoto Protocol variable.

128

The policy variables are drawn from the IEA/IRENA policy and measure database. These

129

indicators have been used by previous scholars to analyze the impacts of policy instruments on

130

renewable energy in OECD countries [16], Europe [3] and globally [4]. In this paper, we consider

131

the following seven aggregate and fourteen specific policy instruments: (1) Fiscal and Financial

132

Incentives, which designed to reducing the risk of investors, includes three specific instruments of

133

price policy (PP), grants and subsidies (GS), and tax (T). (2) Market-based instruments, which

134

provides a tool for trading and meeting renewable energy obligation among producers, and an open 7

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 135

fair trading platform among market subjects, include specific instruments of greenhouse gas

136

emissions allowances (GA) and green certificates (GC). (3) Direct investments, aimed at reducing

137

the capital cost of renewable energy investment, includes funds to sub-national governments (FSG)

138

and infrastructure investments (II). (4) Policy support, which seeks to define strategies and outlines

139

specific programs to promote renewable capacity inside a country, includes institutional creation

140

(IC) and strategic planning (SP). (5) Regulatory instruments, which place a requirement on the

141

minimum amount of electricity supply that comes from renewable sources, primarily include codes

142

and standards (CS), obligation schemes (OS), and other mandatory requirements (OMR). (6)

143

Information and education, which provides guidelines and obligations in regards to further

144

deployment of renewable energy installations, and provides education and trainings for the

145

workforce employed in the building sector on matters of energy efficiency and renewable energy

146

installations. (7) Research, development and deployment (RD&D), which captures effect of

147

technological progress on the promotion of renewable energy. The first 6 aggregate policy variables

148

are measured by the number of active policies in a country per year, which previous studies call

149

“accumulated number of renewable energy policies and measures (ANPM)” [4,16]. Econometric

150

model is a common method to quantitatively evaluate policy effectiveness of renewable energy,

151

such as Marques and Fuinhas [3], Aguirre and Ibikunle [4] and Polzin et al. [16]. In the process of

152

econometric analysis, a potential hypothesis is that the more policies of a specific type there are, the

153

better it is for renewable energy capacity. Following this strand, we set up policy variables and

154

evaluate the effectiveness of renewable energy policy in the framework of econometric models.

155

Furthermore, there are factors delaying the investment process, such as the need to build a wind

156

farm or solar park. With this analysis, we expand Polzin et al. [16] by providing more detailed 8

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 157

policies for renewable installed equipment, considering the lagged reaction of policy variables to

158

the installed capacity of renewable energy.

159

Control variables are drawn from the World Development Indicators database and BP Statistical

160

Review Worlds Energy database, which includes Macroeconomic data and Energy data. Further,

161

economic indicators that might drive renewables capacity include the GDP (cv_gdp). Electric power

162

consumption (cv_epc) and CO2 emissions (cv_co2) are used respectively to account for energy

163

consumption and CO2 emissions. To account for technological level, this paper includes High-

164

technology exports (cv_hte).In Table 1, we present a summary of the variables used in this paper,

165

along with their descriptive statistics.

166 Variable re_c

cv_gdp cv_co2 cv_epc cv_hte pv_1 PP GS T pv_2 GA GC pv_3 FSG

Table 1 Variables definition, sources and descriptive statistics Definition

Obs.

Mean

Std.dev.

Min

Max

Logarithm of the installed capacity of multiple renewable energy resources (Megawatts)

464

7.74

1.7

2.3

12.12

Real gross domestic product (in billions U.S. dollars,constant 2010)

464

17,005.66

28,510.70

1,066

165,974.50

464

7.5

4.63

0

20.21

464

6,858.25

5,399.26

0

25,590.69

464

16.3

8.46

0

47.84

ANPM (Fiscal and financial incentives)

464

5.38

5.49

0

31

ANPM (Price policy) ANPM (Grants and subsidies) ANPM (Tax)

464 464 464

1.08 1.74 0.41

1.78 2.19 0.71

0 0 0

12 12 3

ANPM (Market-based instruments)

464

0.53

1.11

0

7

464

0.15

0.45

0

2

464 464

0.27 0.91

0.64 1.74

0 0

5 9

464

0.20

0.52

0

3

Carbon dioxide emissions (metric tons per capita) Electric power consumption (kWh per capita) High-technology exports(% of manufactured exports)

ANPM (Greenhouse gas emissions allowances) ANPM (Green certificates) ANPM (Direct investments) ANPM (Funds to sub-national governments)

9

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT II

ANPM (Infrastructure investments )

464

0.23

0.55

0

2

pv_4 IC SP pv_5 CS OS

ANPM (Policy support) ANPM (Institutional creation) ANPM (Strategic planning) ANPM (Regulatory instruments) ANPM (Codes and standards) ANPM (Obligation schemes)

464 464 464 464 464 464

4.21 0.75 2.07 3.90 1.02 0.55

5.59 1.32 3.02 4.77 1.81 1.08

0 0 0 0 0 0

50 11 28 29 15 5

OMR

ANPM (Other mandatory requirements)

464

0.65

1.21

0

8

pv_6

ANPM (Information and education)

464

1.51

3.01

0

19

pv_7

Research, development and deployment (Total RD&D in Million USD, 2015 price and exch. rates)

464

94.38

208.52

0

2,442.68

167 168

2.2 Model

169

2.2.1 Variable intercept panel model

170

A panel model can be categorized into three types: pooled regression model, variable intercept

171

model and variable coefficient model [19]. A pooled regression model is a basic panel data model

172

that assumes each individual in the sample has exactly the same regression equation; that is to say,

173

the intercept and coefficient of the model would not change with individuals and time. A variable

174

intercept model assumes the individual's regression equation has the same coefficient while different

175

intercepts to capture the heterogeneity, and it means that the impact of unobserved effects can be

176

absorbed into the intercept term. A variable coefficient model is suitable in the cases where there

177

are changing economic structures or unobserved different socioeconomic and demographic

178

background factors that imply that the response parameters of the included variables may be varying

179

over time or may be different for different cross-sectional units [20]. Thus, it means that generally

180

a variable intercept model or a pooled regression model is picked. Hence, this paper conducts an F-

181

test to identify which method to use.

182

Furthermore, given that it generally takes time to implement policies, the policy variables, except 10

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 183

control variables, are l-period lagged in our research. The model to estimate is

184

Ykt  const   i X ikt l    ' jCjkt  uk   kt

i

j

i 1

j 1

(1)

185

where k is country and t is year. Ykt denotes the development of renewable energy. const is the

186

national entity intercept. X is a vector of the i policy variables. βi is the coefficient of policy variable.

187

C is a vector of the j control variables. β’j is the coefficient of control variable. uk+εkt is composite

188

error term, unobservable random variable uk is intercept term of individual heterogeneity, εkt is a

189

disturbance term that varies with time and individual.

190

Table 2 presents the summary statistics for the results of model tests. F-test is to identify whether

191

pooled regression model or variable intercept model is suitable; Hausman test and Auxiliary

192

regression are to select the fixed effect model or the random effect model. Specifically, for F-test,

193

“H0: all uk =0”, that is, a pooled regression model is acceptable. For Hausman test and Auxiliary

194

regression test, “H0: no correlation between uk and X”, that is, random effect model is correct model.

195

The p-value of F-test is 0.00 shown in Table 2, so the original hypothesis is therefore strongly

196

rejected. Moreover, ρ represents the autocorrelation coefficient between the disturbance terms of

197

different individuals in different periods. The greater the value of ρ is, the more important the

198

individual effect part of the composite error term is. In Table 2, “ρ=0.97” indicates that the variance

199

of composite error term is mainly due to the variation of individual effect. Consequently, the variable

200

intercept model is adopted in the model evaluation.

201

Table 2 Hausman test and F-test results

202 203

Test type

ρ

F-value

Chi-Square Statistic

P-value

F-test Hausman test Auxiliary regression

0.97 -

40.21 -

61.83 81.38

0.00 0.00 0.00

2.2.2 Fixed effect model and random effect model 11

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 204

A variable intercept model can be further divided into a fixed effect (FE) model and a random

205

effect model [19]. It is a basic problem to use the fixed effect model or the random effect model

206

when we address the panel data. In a fixed effect model, the individual effect or time effect is

207

interrelated to the independent variables, whereas in a random effect model, the individual effect or

208

time effect is not relative to explanatory variables. In other words, the random-effects model allows

209

one to estimate the coefficients of both time-varying and time-invariant variables while the fixed-

210

effects model allows us only to estimate the coefficients of time-varying explanatory variables [20].

211

When N (This paper is 29, which refers to the number of countries) is larger relative to T (This paper

212

is 16, which refers to the time series), whether to treat the effects as fixed or random is not an easy

213

question to answer. It can make a surprising amount of difference in the estimates of the parameters.

214

Zhao et al. [21] used the Hausman test to identify the specific model of whether it is a fixed effect

215

or a random effect. However, the traditional Hausman test assumes that the random effect is fully

216

efficient, which means that both uk and εkt must be independently and identically distributed.

217

Therefore, the traditional Hausman test is not applicable if the error of the clustering robust standard

218

is quite different from that of the ordinary standard. To avoid this situation, in this paper, the

219

Hausman test is done and the auxiliary regression with test is further conducted. It can be seen from

220

the data in Table 2 that the original hypothesis is rejected for both p-values are 0.00 in Hausman test

221

and Auxiliary regression test, meaning that a fixed effect is suitable.

222

The variable intercept model with fixed effects is as Eq. (2). The variables are measured as

223

logarithms, since the logarithm of the data will not change the nature and relationship, and

224

simultaneously is helpful to heteroscedasticity elimination.

225

ln Ykt  const   i ln Xikt l    ' j ln Cjkt  uk   kt

i

j

i 1

j 1

(2) 12

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 226 227 228

Furthermore, we add the dummy variable of the Kyoto Protocol as a virtual variable for panel empirical study. i

j

i 1

j 1

ln Ykt  const   i ln Xikt l    ' j ln Cjkt   Dkt  uk   kt

229

Where Dkt =1 denotes the Kyoto Protocol is implemented.

230

To examine the effectiveness of specific policy, this paper set up model (4).

231

232 233

r

j

r 1

j 1

ln Ykt  const   1r ln X 'rkt l    ' j ln Cjkt   Dkt  uk   kt

(3)

(4)

where X ’is a vector of the r specific policy variables and β1r is the coefficient of specific policy. 3. Results and Discussion

234

The aim of this research is to uncover the influence of different policy instruments on the installed

235

capacity of renewable energy and conduct further discussion between cluster and specific policies

236

among typical countries. Table 3 presents the results based on Eq. (3) and Eq. (4). FE(1) is the

237

regression results of aggregate policy, and FE(2) is the deletion of the insignificant variable on the

238

basis of FE(1) to identify the robustness of our model. The results show that in terms of the positive

239

or negative effects of the regression on renewable energy capacity, both models generate very

240

similar results, including the R2 values. FE(3) is the regression results of specific policy on the basis

241

of FE(2). The empirical results of aggregate and specific policies are shown in Fig. 3, which present

242

the ranking of policies impacts and standard error bars.

13

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

243 244

Fig. 3 The ranking of policies impacts

245

As is well-known, the Kyoto Protocol has played a vital role in the climate change mitigation and

246

renewable energy development. The results in Table 3 confirm its notable effect on renewables.

247

Furthermore, the ranking of aggregate policies impacts on renewable energy development shown in

248

Fig. 3 is market-based instruments, RD&D, fiscal and financial incentives, and policy support.

249

Specifically, our results imply that every 1 percentage point increase in these four aggregate policies,

250

respectively, is associated with an approximately 0.300, 0.210, 0.182, 0.163 percentage point

251

increase in renewable energy capacity at the 1% significance level. For the specific policy model,

252

PP, GS, SP are positive policies at the significance level of 1%, 1% and 5%, respectively. The

253

contribution to renewable energy is increased by 0.191, 0.163, 0.167 percentage point for every 1

254

percentage point increase in PP, GS, SP. Additionally, significant are the four control variables in

255

all models, specifically, GDP, High-technology exports, and Electric power consumption, which are

256

positively related to the renewables capacity, while the remaining variable of CO2 emissions 14

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 257

negatively affects the dependent variable. In the following discussion, we highlight effective and

258

ineffective policy measures and relate our results to the following previous studies [3,4,11,16].

259

Table 3 Panel analysis results

Variables

FE(1)

 

FE(2)

 

coefficient

S.E.

coefficient

S.E.

cv_gdp cv_hte cv_co2 cv_epc

2.265** 0.361** -1.051** 0.210**

0.277 0.106 0.193 0.048

2.168** 0.369** -1.050** 0.209**

0.266 0.106 0.189 0.048

pv_1

0.182**

0.057

0.152**

0.052

pv_2

0.299**

0.088

0.286**

0.085

pv_3

-0.062

0.073

/

/

pv_4

0.163**

0.056

0.134**

0.051

pv_5 pv_6 pv_7 d_k cons R-sq

-0.063 -0.016 0.210** 0.522** -14.570** 0.801

0.060 0.070 0.046 0.072 2.393  

/ / 0.213** 0.523** -13.740** 0.800

/ / 0.045 0.070 2.303  

260

Note: Standard errors * p<0.05, ** p<0.01

261

3.1 Fiscal and financial incentives

Variables cv_gdp cv_hte cv_co2 cv_epc PP GS T GA GC / IC SP / / pv_7 d_k cons R-sq

FE(3)

 

coefficient

S.E.

2.120** 0.420** -1.092** 0.221** 0.191** 0.163** -0.048 0.315 0.188 / 0.001 0.167* / / 0.191** 0.546** -13.320** 0.803

0.272 0.104 0.191 0.048 0.063 0.066 0.099 0.177 0.112 / 0.097 0.074 / / 0.047 0.068 2.354  

262

It is found that fiscal and financial incentives have positive impacts on renewable energy

263

installation, which implies that the fiscal and financial incentives effects on renewable power

264

development is notably strong. In addition, the specific policies effects regressed in Eq. (4) show

265

that the coefficient of price policy, grants and subsidies are statistically significant, which means

266

they have played a substantial role in the fiscal and financial package and have large positive effects

267

on renewable energy promotion.

268

In the process of renewable energy development, each country provides renewable energy support

269

from the electricity price policy, feed-in tariffs (FIT) and Feed-in premium (FIP) are generally used. 15

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 270

The FIT can be described as a premium paid for electricity that is supplied to an electricity grid from

271

a particular renewable energy generation source [22]. It is minimum price guaranteed by the national

272

governments for per unit of renewable electricity supplied to the grid for a long-term [23]. Grid

273

enterprises must pay the cost to renewable energy generation enterprises at such price. FIP is a type

274

of price-based policy instrument whereby eligible renewable energy generators are paid a premium

275

price, which is a payment in addition to the wholesale price. This premium can be fixed or floating.

276

Price policy proved particularly successful in countries such as China, Germany, and Spain. The

277

main features of this instrument are ensuring the stability of renewable energy projects and attracting

278

all types of social capital into the field of renewable energy. For investors, it is an important market

279

signal, and the adjustment of electricity price can also reflect the level of technological progress to

280

a certain extent. Thus, this research is in accordance with evidence by Del Río and Bleda [24], who

281

emphasize the advantages of price policy to spur development and to lower risks in renewable

282

energy investment. From the perspective of policy evolution, the price policy was implemented

283

beginning with three countries in 2000, and it had been implemented in 21 countries of 29 sample

284

countries by 2015. It has played an important role in promoting the large-scale development of

285

renewable energy generation.

286

Grants and subsidies are the means by which the government provides financial aid or other forms

287

of income or price as the measures of support for the purpose of developing renewable energy

288

without direct capital gains or returns. From the perspective of evolution, this policy is a commonly

289

adopted policy in various countries. This policy, on the one hand, subsidizes production and

290

subsidies for renewable energy producers. On the other hand, subsidies are made for the output of

291

renewable energy equipment, which will increase production, reduce costs and improve economic 16

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 292

efficiency.

293

However, tax instruments are not significant for promoting renewable energy development. This

294

is a surprising result since the primary objective of such an instrument is to financially enhance

295

renewables. Johnstone et al. [25] related this situation to the fact that investors may have little or no

296

confidence in policies that depend on public finance, since they are likely to be withdrawn abruptly

297

with a change in administration. A good example is the Production Tax Credit for wind power in

298

the United States. This tax instrument has had a pattern of repeated expiration and short-term

299

renewal (usually no more than a couple of years), creating a boom-bust cycle in investment in this

300

technology over years, which is also believed to be damaging the industry's prospects due to the

301

uncertainty it creates (see [26]). In addition, although the industry agrees on the necessity of a five-

302

to ten-year incentive, legislators do not want to be associated with large spending programs, which

303

is why the Production Tax Credit is likely to remain as a two-year address option of renewal

304

indefinitely. Another source of uncertainty for tax incentive is economic downturn, particularly

305

during a financial crisis, when there are limited resources to support these measures. It would thus

306

be that the issue with the lack of positive reinforcement of renewable energy by tax instrument is a

307

result of the uncertainty of the policies. Gan et al. [5] also criticize how these measures do not

308

necessarily guarantee the achievement of their expected targets.

309

This paper confirms the findings reported by Marques and Fuinhas [3], who show that fiscal and

310

financial incentives policies are positive to increasing the contribution of renewables to the total

311

energy supply. In addition, this research confirms that a variety of policies comprising specific and

312

technology measures spur renewable energy technology deployment, higher income through grants

313

and subsidies, and lower capital costs through price policy support investors to increase renewable 17

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 314

energy capacity. In sum, the price policy is a strong signal for investors, because it adjusts the risk

315

or reward structure to address capital market constraints. Grants and subsidies policy is proven to

316

be effective short-term measures to ease fiscal constraints. Tax incentives reduce the tax burden of

317

renewable energy enterprises and increase the competitiveness of renewable energy, but need a

318

stable policy environment.

319

3.2 Market-based instruments

320

This empirical research also provides evidence for market-based instruments including

321

greenhouse gas emissions allowances (GA), green certificates (GC) and white certificates (WC).

322

Many sample countries have not yet implemented the white certificates policy, only South Korea

323

and Italy introduced this instrument in 2007 and 2011, respectively (data from IEA/IRENA policies

324

and measures database); therefore, we mainly focus on greenhouse gas emissions allowances and

325

green certificates.

326

The separate policies of greenhouse gas emissions allowances or green certificates have no

327

significant effects in promoting renewable energy; however, the aggregate policy of market-based

328

instruments has a strong impact on renewable capacity expansion at the 1% significance level. This

329

indicates that synergy effects do exist between these two specific policies; that is to say, the

330

implementation of market-based instruments require the combination of greenhouse gas emissions

331

allowances and green certificates. On the one hand, greenhouse gas emissions allowances and green

332

certificates have different starting points: greenhouse gas emissions allowances is aimed at carbon

333

dioxide emission reduction and at solving the problem of greenhouse gas emissions, while the green

334

certificate is aimed at promoting the utilization of renewable energy and solving the problem of the

335

adjustment of energy structure. On the other hand, the two policies are essentially reducing 18

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 336

greenhouse gas emissions by means of market-based instruments. The empirical analysis shows that

337

the combination of the two specific policies plays a very important role in the promotion of

338

renewable energy. Hence, the combination of greenhouse gas emissions allowances and green

339

certificates might be the most effective way to push the entire society to achieve energy

340

transformation with the least cost.

341

3.3 Direct investments

342

The class of policy “Direct investments” includes funds to sub-national governments (FSG),

343

infrastructure investments (II). The results from empirical analysis revealed that this type of

344

instrument is ineffective in promoting renewable energy capacity. We hereby confirm earlier works

345

(based on Multiple renewable energy analyses) that resulted in that this form of direct investment

346

did not spur renewable energy development [16]. This stands in contrast to previous literature that

347

highlights the grid expansion as conducive to renewable energy deployment and investment [27].

348

Funds to sub-national governments are a direct investment of federal money, with regional, local or

349

municipal level entities as targets. Infrastructure investment to provide grid access seem ineffective

350

for channeling investors’ money into renewable energy technologies, according to the paper [16].

351

The reasons for non-significant results in this paper might lie in the different structure of different

352

renewable energy technologies, which have different regional focuses and scales of power plants.

353

3.4 Policy support

354

Certain policies and measures seek to define strategies and outline specific programs to promote

355

renewable capacity within a country. These measures are tracked as policy support, which includes

356

institutional creation (IC) and strategic planning (SP). The empirical results indicate that policy

357

support instruments accelerated the capacity additions in the renewable energy sector effectively in 19

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 358

the period of 2000 to 2015.

359

From the perspective of specific policy, institutional creation is insignificant to promoting

360

renewables capacity, while strategic planning has positive effects on the development of renewable

361

energy, as investors favor a long-term stable policy environment.

362

As shown in Fig. 3, the coefficient of aggregate policy (That is, the combination of institutional

363

creation and strategic planning policy) has no significant differences than that of the strategic

364

planning instrument. While it can be seen from the data in Table 3 that the aggregate policy group

365

(Significant at 1% level) reported more significance than the specific policy group (Significant at

366

5% level). Indicating that the combination of institutional creation and strategic planning policy

367

might promotes the effects of strategic planning policy. Institutional creation, such as the

368

implementation of an energy agency, might accelerates the deployment of strategic planning

369

effectively.

370

With this analysis, the empirical results are in support of the strong role that institutional creation

371

and a long-term policy commitment play in an effective policy mix. Commitment, creation, stability,

372

reliability and predictability are all elements that increase confidence of market actors, reduce

373

regulatory risks, and reduce the cost of capital. Thus, the results of this study confirm empirical

374

works that indicate clear strategic long-term economic instruments are conductive to renewable

375

energy development. Therefore, long-term policies for the stable environment through strategic

376

planning and probably through institutional creation will support the long-term development of

377

renewable energy.

378

3.5 Regulatory instruments and information and education

379

According to Table 3, the regulatory instrument is insignificant in the stage of renewable energy 20

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 380

development. Gan et al. [5] state that regulatory instruments appear to have been the most effective

381

in promoting renewable energy development, while the empirical results in this paper are

382

inconsistent with the this view reported by Gan et al. (2007). Furthermore, there are cases in the

383

previous literature where even more details about the policies do not generate the expected results.

384

For example, Polzin et al. [16] note that regulatory mechanisms and the institutionalization of

385

markets in the form of regulatory instruments also attract institutional investors, while the empirical

386

results are not significant. Aguirre and Ibikunle [4] did not find significance for regulatory

387

instruments. This result is aligned with those from Marques and Fuinhas [3]. Furthermore, measures

388

and policies belonging to the “Information and education”, such as Advice/Aid in Implementation,

389

Information provision, do not yet seem to be relevant in stimulating the renewable deployment.

390

3.6 Research, development and deployment (RD&D)

391

To capture the effect of RD&D to renewable energy installment, we use Detailed Country RD&D

392

Budgets of renewable energy as a proxy, taken from the IEA's Energy Technology Research and

393

Development Database. In the 1970s, the renewables policy framework was dominated by Research

394

and Development programs [4]. In this paper, we evaluate how effective and significant the policy

395

instruments are in promoting renewable energy deployment. The results suggest that RD&D is an

396

important factor to facilitate renewables in typical countries. This is reflected by a high level of

397

statistical significance, at the 1% significance level, and positive relationship between the RD&D

398

budget variable and the dependent variable. As renewable technologies are still expensive and thus

399

cannot compete with fossil fuel technologies, RD&D was needed to reduce costs and create more

400

advanced renewable energy technologies.

401

3.7 Non-policy variables 21

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 402

Besides the above policy variables, GDP, high-technology exports, CO2 emissions, electric power

403

consumption, and the Kyoto Protocol are statistically significant non-policy variables at the 1%

404

significance level. Out of these non-policy variables, CO2 emissions negatively related to the

405

dependent variable, while the remaining variables positively affected renewables deployment. It is

406

worth noting that the implement of Kyoto Protocol in 2005 was a key international milestone in

407

carbon emission, which shocked the policymakers in their minds and promoted the transformation

408

of the world development philosophy on low-carbon economy. Although some countries failed to

409

achieve the goal of reducing emissions because of the high cost of low carbon development in the

410

short term, a large number of countries are committed to search for a low-carbon development path

411

in the long run. It is undeniable that the low carbon development philosophy will promote the

412

renewable energy deployment in the long term, which is an effective way to emission reduction.

413

4. Conclusions

414

This paper focuses on a panel of 29 typical countries for the time span 2000-2015 to characterize

415

the effectiveness of public policies regarding renewables. This research adds empirical evaluation

416

of specific policies on renewables to uncover the effects of different policies on renewables

417

development and detail function of specific instruments in aggregate policies.

418

The analysis demonstrates that certain aggregate public policies have been drivers toward the

419

development of renewables. On the one hand, four of seven aggregate measures have produced the

420

desired effect of increasing renewable energy power capacity in the period analyzed. The ranking

421

of aggregate policies impacts is, market-based instruments, research, development and deployment

422

(RD&D), fiscal and financial incentives, and policy support. Specifically, regressions indicate that

423

for a 10 percentage point increase in these four policies, countries will install respectively 3.00%, 22

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 424

2.10%, 1.82%, 1.63% more renewable energy capacity per year on average. However, the other

425

three aggregate measures, including direct investments, regulatory instruments, information and

426

education, have not yet been effective in fostering renewable energy use in these target countries.

427

For the specific policies, price policy, grants and subsidies are the stable instruments of fiscal and

428

financial incentives to promote the development of renewable energy. For policy support

429

instruments, strategic planning was the main effect policy to spur renewable energy development

430

while institutional creation was not. We find that for a 10 percentage point increase in price policy,

431

grants and subsidies, and strategic planning, countries will install 1.91%, 1.63%, 1.67% more

432

renewable energy capacity per year on average.

433

This paper assesses the aggregate policy and their specific ones in the same analysis framework,

434

and the empirical results found that synergy effects do exist among specific policies, so it is vital

435

for policy makers to incorporate specific mix and economic conditions into the policy design. For

436

example, separate policies of greenhouse gas emissions allowances or green certificates have an

437

insignificant effect while their combination (that is, the aggregate policy of market-based incentives)

438

has a positive influence on renewable energy capacity at the 1% significance level. It is worth noting

439

that market-based instruments should be given special attention in promoting renewable power

440

development in the future. In the formulation of market-oriented policies, integrating greenhouse

441

gas emissions allowances and green certificates policies may be a better solution to avoid policy

442

failure. On the one hand, countries can directly control greenhouse gas emissions through

443

greenhouse gas emissions allowances policy, such as setting a cap on the permitted amount of

444

emissions and distributing a corresponding number of allowances globally. On the other hand, they

445

set indirect energy means through green certificates instrument to increase the proportion of 23

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 446

renewable energy consumption and reduce greenhouse gas emissions. In addition, the specific

447

policy of institutional creation has insignificant effects while the specific policy of strategic planning

448

has positively effects (at the 5% significance level) on the development of renewable energy. It is

449

worth noting that their combination has a more significant effect (at the 1% significance level) on

450

the development of renewable energy, which indicates that institutional creation promotes the

451

effects of strategic planning.

452

The empirical results highlighted that implementation of the Kyoto Protocol in 2005 has positive

453

impact on renewable energy deployment in typical countries. In fact, due to the entry into force of

454

the Kyoto Protocol, many countries have introduced renewable energy development policies to

455

promote renewable energy development. The empirical results also indicate that GDP, electric

456

power consumption, and high-technology exports, which are control variables in the model, are

457

confirmed to have positive effects on the continuous development of renewables. However, CO2

458

emissions, another control variable in the model, have a negative impact on the deployment of

459

renewables.

460

Overall, the empirical results suggest that the development of renewables has been established

461

essentially upon direct subsidies, strategy plans and RD&D while market-oriented policy

462

instruments should be the greenhouse gas emissions allowances and green certificates mixes. With

463

the increase of government subsidies and expenditure, the further direction of renewables is market-

464

driven logic instead of policy-driven logic; therefore, the appropriate design of market-oriented

465

policy instruments need to be discussed further.

466

Acknowledgements

467

The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees and the editor of this journal. The authors 24

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 468

also gratefully acknowledge the financial support of the Major Program of the National Social

469

Science Fund of China (Grant No. 15ZDB165).

470

References

471 472 473 474 475 476 477 478 479 480 481 482 483 484 485 486 487 488 489 490 491 492 493 494 495 496 497 498 499 500 501 502 503 504 505 506 507 508

[1]

BP, BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2017, Br. Pet. (2017) 1–52. http://www.bp.com/content/dam/bp/en/corporate/pdf/energy-economics/statistical-review2017/bp-statistical-review-of-world-energy-2017-full-report.pdf.

[2]

S. Zhang, P. Andrews-Speed, X. Zhao, Y. He, Interactions between renewable energy policy and renewable energy industrial policy: A critical analysis of china’s policy approach to renewable energies, Energy Policy. 62 (2013) 342–353. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.063.

[3]

A.C. Marques, J.A. Fuinhas, Are public policies towards renewables successful? Evidence from European countries, Renew. Energy. 44 (2012) 109–118. doi:10.1016/j.renene.2012.01.007.

[4]

M. Aguirre, G. Ibikunle, Determinants of renewable energy growth: A global sample analysis, Energy Policy. 69 (2014) 374–384. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2014.02.036.

[5]

L. Gan, G.S. Eskeland, H.H. Kolshus, Green electricity market development: Lessons from Europe and the US, Energy Policy. 35 (2007) 144–155. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2005.10.008.

[6]

C. Liao, H. Ou, S. Lo, P. Chiueh, Y. Yu, A challenging approach for renewable energy market development, Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 15 (2011) 787–793. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2010.09.047.

[7]

K. Patlitzianas, K. Karagounis, The progress of RES environment in the most recent member states of the EU, Renew. Energy. 36 (2011) 429–436. doi:10.1016/j.renene.2010.08.032.

[8]

F.C. Menz, S. Vachon, The effectiveness of different policy regimes for promoting wind power: Experiences from the states, Energy Policy. 34 (2006) 1786–1796. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2004.12.018.

[9]

S. Carley, State renewable energy electricity policies: An empirical evaluation of effectiveness, Energy Policy. 37 (2009) 3071–3081. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.03.062.

[10]

M.A. Delmas, M.J. Montes-Sancho, U.S. state policies for renewable energy: Context and effectiveness, Energy Policy. 39 (2011) 2273–2288. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.01.034.

[11]

N. Johnstone, I. Haščič, D. Popp, Renewable energy policies and technological innovation: Evidence based on patent counts, Environ. Resour. Econ. 45 (2010) 133–155. doi:10.1007/s10640-009-9309-1.

[12]

Y. Zhao, K. Ki, L. Wang, Do renewable electricity policies promote renewable electricity generation ? Evidence from panel data, Energy Policy. 62 (2013) 887–897. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.072.

[13]

C.G. Dong, Feed-in tariff vs. renewable portfolio standard: An empirical test of their relative effectiveness in promoting wind capacity development, Energy Policy. 42 (2012) 476–485. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.12.014.

[14]

D. De Jager, M. Rathmann, Policy instrument design to reduce financing costs in renewable energy technology projects Policy instrument design to reduce financing costs in renewable energy technology projects, (2008) 142. http://www.ecofys.com/files/files/retd_pid0810_main.pdf. 25

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 509 510 511 512 513 514 515 516 517 518 519 520 521 522 523 524 525 526 527 528 529 530 531 532 533 534 535 536 537 538 539 540 541

[15]

L. Bird, M. Bolinger, T. Gagliano, R. Wiser, M. Brown, B. Parsons, Policies and market factors driving wind power development in the United States, Energy Policy. 33 (2005) 1397–1407. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2003.12.018.

[16]

F. Polzin, M. Migendt, F.A. Täube, P. von Flotow, Public policy influence on renewable energy investments-A panel data study across OECD countries, Energy Policy. 80 (2015) 98– 111. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2015.01.026.

[17]

I. Renewable, E. Agency, Renewable Energy Statistics 2017, 2017.

[18]

D. Popp, I. Hascic, N. Medhi, Technology and the diffusion of renewable energy, Energy Econ. 33 (2011) 648–662. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2010.08.007.

[19]

X. Zhao, S. Li, S. Zhang, R. Yang, S. Liu, The effectiveness of China’s wind power policy: An empirical analysis, Energy Policy. 95 (2016) 269–279. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2016.04.050.

[20]

C. Hsiao, Analysis of panel data 3th Edition, 2014. doi:10.1017/CBO9780511754203.

[21]

H. Zhao, H. Zhao, X. Han, Z. He, S. Guo, Economic Growth, Electricity Consumption, Labor Force and Capital Input: A More Comprehensive Analysis on North China Using Panel Data, Energies. 9 (2016) 891. doi:10.3390/en9110891.

[22]

L. Poruschi, C.L. Ambrey, J.C.R. Smart, Revisiting feed-in tariffs in Australia: A review, Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 82 (2018) 260–270. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2017.09.027.

[23]

M. del P. Pablo-Romero, A. S�nchez-Braza, J. Salvador-Ponce, N. S�nchez-Labrador, An overview of feed-in tariffs, premiums and tenders to promote electricity from biogas in the EU28, Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 73 (2017) 1366–1379. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2017.01.132.

[24]

P. Del Río, M. Bleda, Comparing the innovation effects of support schemes for renewable electricity technologies: A function of innovation approach, Energy Policy. 50 (2012) 272–282. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.07.014.

[25]

N. Johnstone, I. Haščič, D. Popp, Renewable energy policies and technological innovation: Evidence based on patent counts, Environ. Resour. Econ. 45 (2010) 133–155. doi:10.1007/s10640-009-9309-1.

[26]

M.J. Barradale, Impact of public policy uncertainty on renewable energy investment: Wind power and the production tax credit, Energy Policy. 38 (2010) 7698–7709. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.08.021.

[27]

D. Jager de, C. Klessmann, E. Stricker, T. Winkel, E. Visser de, M. Koper, M. Ragwitz, A. Held, G. Resch, S. Busch, C. Panzer, A. Gazzo, T. Roulleau, P. Gousseland, M. Henriet, A. Bouillé, Financing Renewable Energy in the European Energy Market Financing Renewable Energy in the European Energy Market, (2011). doi:10.13140/2.1.3115.2645.

542

26

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

HIGHLIGHTS 

Panel data study on the effectiveness of renewable energy policies to promote RE development.



Four of seven aggregate policies are positively significant to RE capacity increase especially Market-based instruments and RD&D.



Three of twelve specific policies have significant positive effects on RE capacity including price policy, grants and subsidies, and strategic planning.



Synergy effects do exist among specific policies in renewable energy increase.