EARNED INTERNATIONAL RESERVE UNITS: The Catalyst of Two Complementary World Problems - the Monetary and Development CHRIS ECONOM I DES, President,
1. THE SECOND AND - HOPEFULLY COLLAPSE
1.1.
In the
Cyprus
- THE LAST
OF THE GOLD EXCHANGE
world’s
monetary
Economic
history
STANDARD
of the past 50
years, two memorable dates, 20 September 193 1, and 15 August 1971, happen to have much in common: on the former date, the gold-sterling exchange standard, standard,
and on the latter, the gold-dollar exchange collapsed for practically the same reasons.
Society
International Reserve Units to be earned through the discount with the I.M.F. of long-term bonds connected with development loans.S 1.6. It is to be hoped that the world will not go back to the gold exchange standard or perpetuate ‘on a provisional basis’ the Inconvertible Dollar Standard, for history teaches that those who do not learn from their past mistakes, are doomed to repeat them with catastrophic consequences.
1.2. On 20 September 193 1, the British Government announced the suspension of the convertibility of the pound sterling into gold for the following reasons, stated in a communique of H.M. Government:
2. THE FIRST CONTRADICTION:
as
INADEQUATE
GROWTH OF MONETARY
GOLD
‘During the last few days the international financial have become demoralized, and have been liquidating their sterling assets regardless of their intrinsic ” worth.1 ‘In the circumstances there was no alternative but to protect the financial position of this country by the only means at our disposal [that is, by] suspending for the time being the operation of that section of the Gold Standard Act of 1925, which requires the Bank of England to sell gold at a fixed price.‘2
2.1. The gold exchange standard was expected to be more efficient than the ‘gold standard’, because the key-currency-originally the pound sterling and later the U.S. dollar-would supplement gold as a reserve asset and the two together would, hopefully, serve the needs of international trade better than gold alone.
Many
eliminate the main contradiction of gold as an international reserve asset, which was that its annual
markets
‘after
monetary
the
abuses
experts
thought
at that
it led to, the system
time that of the gold
exchange standard was dead for ever’.3 1.3. However, after the Second World War, that system was revived again, with the American dollar substituted for the English pound as the keycurrency. Ultimately, however, the gold-dollar exchange standard, was doomed to have the same fate as its predecessor. President
On 15 August 1971, Richard Nixon had to
the American announce the
2.2.
growth
The gold exchange
was
international
standard
could not, however,
commensurate with trade, in current prices.
not
the growth
of
1. All italics in this paper have been added for purposes of emphasis (excepting references to books, etc.). 2. Quoted in Keesing’s*Contemporay 1931-4, p. 62.
Archives,
vol.
i,
‘temporary’ suspension of the convertibility of the American dollar into gold, in order-as he put it-‘to defend the dollar against the international specula-
3. Comment by M. Pierre Quesnay, Manager-General of the Bank for International Settlements in Basle, quoted by Professor Giuseppe Ugo Papi in his paper ‘An old question: choice of an international monetary measure’, Rivista di Politica Economica, January 1970.
tors’, who ‘in recent weeks out attack on the dollar’.4
4. See the official version of President Nixon’s announcement, published in The Times on 17 August 1971.
have been
waging an all-
1.4. Although on both occasions the speculators were, admittedly, the proximate cause that precipitated the collapse, yet the real causes were more fundamental: they were the latent contradictions of the gold exchange standard, the effects of which, with the passage of time, were bound to expand and eventually to explode. 1.5. The purpose of this paper is to analyse these contradictions and to elaborate the idea which I first put forward in a letter to The Times on 27 September 1971, of substituting for the gold exchange standard and the present gold-linked gifted SDRs, new Vol. 1 Nos. 3 & 4
5. My letter to The Times on 27 September 1971, in which I gave a very brief outline of the views set forth in this paper, was occasioned by one of three articles by Professor Nicholas Kaldor published in the same paper on 8 September 1971 in which he made the point that SDRs, in the way that they have been brought into existence, ‘will be quite ineffective in performing,the vital function of ensuring that the effective demand for goods and services in international trade should go on rising’; and by a letter from Mr. Hugh M. O’Connor, former Chairman of Gilbert Brothers Discount Company, to The Times published on 14 September 1971, in which he repeated his proposal made in an article in The Times, Business News, four years earlier (18 August 1967) for the formation of an International Discount Office at a World Central Bank. 49
From
1950
to 1965
the world’s
official
holdings
of gold increased 6y only 22 per cent (from $35.5 to $43.3 billion) and in the last five years (1965-1970) they
actually
decreased
to
$41.3
the net growth of gold during was only 16 per cent. At the same time, however,
billion-therefore
the past two decades
the growth of world
imports in current prices during the same period 390 per cent (from $60 to 294 billion).6 2.3.
The main
reasons
for the very slow growth
was of
monetary gold were: (a) The price of gold was kept fixed from 1934 to 1971 at U.S.%35 per ounce, while, in the meantime, the costs of its production rose several-fold and most gold-mines in the world were depleted. As a consequence, practically only South Africa, with its rich gold-mines, and to a smaller extent, the Soviet Union, could afford to mine gold at that price. (b) Because of the comparatively low .price of gold and its use in recent years in electronics, an increasing proportion of the annual production is being absorbed for industrial and artistic purposes.’ (c) Demand for gold from the traditional hoarding countries of the Middle and Far East, has continued to rise.* (d) Speculators absorbed substantial quantities gold especially during the years 1965 to 1968.9
of
3. THE SECOND CONTRADICTION: A ZERO-SUM DYNAMIC GAME’
3.1. The second contradiction of the gold exchange standard is a corollary of the fist one: the widening gap created by the inadequate growth of monetary gold, on the one hand, and the secular growth of international trade which necessitated a parallel growth of reserves, on the other hand, had to be filled by the reserve currency by way of increasing deficits in the balance of payments of the reserve-currency country-U.S.A. in the post-war period. The consequences of such deficits were to reduce the CJ.S.‘s gold stock from $22.8 to $11.1 billion (1950-70), and to increase its official liabilities from $4.4 to $23.9 billion.‘O These, in their turn, weakened U.S.‘s ability to honour its obligation to convert the dollar into gold, and ultimately led to the suspension of such convertibility and the collapse of the system. 3.2. One may, however, currency country, should
wonder why the necessarily sustain
reservebalance
in the long run balance his external accounts
would
and the only thing needed would be temporary facilities like those offered by the I.M.F. to tide over short-term deficits. 3.4. In real life, however, the zero-sum game of international payments is a dynamic one, in which, first the players have unequal competitive strength and second, whereas the winners board their gains, the losers take measures to reverse their losses into gains by currency devaluation, by direct and indirect curbing of imports, foreign aid, foreign services, foreign investments and other capital outflow and by boosting exports. In such a game, alJ countries other than the reserve-currency country thus manage, in the long
run,
surpluses
to
have
either
overall
because
balance-of-payments
they
are
competitively
stronger than the reserve-currency country or because they become stronger through the measures just mentioned, which the reserve-currency country, owing to promptly-for so
its
easily.
position example,
Since
we
as such, cannot take so it cannot devalue its currency assume
a
zero-sum
game,
balance-of-payments surpluses for the countries other than the reserve-currency country necessarily entail corresponding deficits for the latter. 3.5. These consequences of a zero-sum dynamic game are intensified if the game becomes a negativesum one, as was the case during the last five years when the global official gold holdings actually fell. 3.6. The above-described trends are reinforced by the following consequential factors: First, the reserve-currency country is usually a rich mature industrial country which disposes of large savings seeking profitable investments. As long as its currency is acceptable by other countries as a reserve asset, such a country falls into temptation and allows its capital to be invested abroad in quantities much in excess of its balanceof-payments potentialities. Actually in the past 11 years (1960-70), during which the U.S.‘s official net reserves (after deducting official liabilities and SDRs) declined billion, their ‘Direct Investments Abroad’ to $30.4 billion.‘l Second, same time
by $21.7 amounted
the reserve-currency country being at the a ‘world power’, it is likewise tempted to
incur excessive overseas military increasing its balance-of-payments
6. See International
Financid
expenditure, thus deficits further.
Statistics,
April 1960
and
January 1972. 7. See I.M.F. Annual paragraph 13.2, below.
Report,
1971,
p. 146.
See rlso
of payments deficits. To reply to this question, we will assume that no new gold enters the international monetary systemwhich, after all, is not far from the truth. Then, that system becomes practically a zero-sum game: the global balance-of-payments surpluses equal the global deficits.
10. See lntemntional October 1972.
3.3. If all the players in such a game had an equal probability of winning or losing and were ready to accept both gains and losses stoically, each player
11. See L:S. Survey of Cunent Business. June 1971, p. 32, line 39, and International Financial Statistics. February 1968 and December 1971.
50
8. ibid. 9. ibid. Financial Statistics,
April 1960
and
World Development
During 1960-70 the U.S.‘s ‘Direct Defence Expenditures Abroad’ totalled $40.4 billion. 1 2 3.7.
It might,
however,
be asked
whether
this order
of things might not, after all, change following the Smithsonian Currency Realignment of 18 December 1971, which was hailed by President Nixon as ‘the most significant the world’.’ 3 3.8.
monetary
In the absence
agreement
in the history
of a fundamental
reform
of
of the
adequate
working
capital,
proportional
of their foreign transactions; (b) the precautionary motive-to
to the volume create
strikes, war or other emergencies. (c) the deferred-investment motive-to keep tions
at home or abroad; and, last but not least, (d) the prestige and power motive-to
nothing
of
international
than a readjustment trade competition.
of handicaps
in
Such a readjustment
may very well give the U.S., after a time-lag of a year or two, a better chance of winning. In the context of a ‘zero-sum game’, however, the prospective balance-of-payments necessarily create ments of other turn, inevitably
surpluses corresponding
of the deficits
U.S.A. in the
will pay-
countries. Such countries will, in their take the measures envisaged in para-
graph 3.4 above, in their attempt to protect their balance*f-payments positions and regain their surpluses. The result will then be the adoption of ‘beggar-my-neighbour’ policies and the drift towards world economic stagnation.
the
ACCUMULATE
4.1.
It is evident
from
OF ALL COUNTRIES TO FOREIGN RESERVES
the foregoing,
that
exchange standard can no longer serve national economy and that a fundamental the international
reserve
system
the gold the interreform of
is long overdue.
Before considering any reform scheme, we must inquire why do all countries increase their reserves?
however, strive to
4.2. It is a well-known phenomenon that all developed countries have the propensity: fo export (goods and services) more than they import; thereby realize current-account to
and
country’s
wealth
keep
in international
pan
reserves,
which enhances the feeling of being financially strong and independent. Balance-of-payments surpluses, which increase the reserves, are seen as the prize of success in the international trade contest which the winners are loath fo part with; on the other hand, deficits which reduce the reserves, are felt to be a sign of failure, restrictive 4.3.
which the losers hasten measures.
In this connexion,
country reserves strive
it should
to reverse by taking be stressed
that
no
is satisfied with only the minimum volume of required as ‘working balances’; all countries to
accumulate
more
reserves
rhan
that
minimum. This is true not only for the rich countries but also the poor countries, which refrain from using all their foreign earnings in the purchase of badly needed
4. THE PROPENSITY
create
reServes pending better opportunities or condito spend them on national needs or investments
international monetary system, such as the one proposed here, the currency realignment by itself is more
and keep
reserves to be used in case of adverse eventualitiessuch as balance-of-payments deficits, flight of capital,
imports,
for
the
sake
of
satisfying
their
‘propensity’ to increase their reserves. Thus, in the past decade (1960-70), ‘the Less Developed Areas’ increased their reserves from $9.4 to $18.2 billion.14 4.4. Each country’s volume of reserves appears to have a strong positive correlation with both its imports and GNP. This is confumed by my calculations of the coefficients of correlation between reserves and imports and reserves and GNP for all countries of the O.E.C.D., with the exception of the U.S.A., the U.K., and Switzerland which are special cases (the first two as reserve-currency countries and the third as a deposit-banker for citizens of other countries), shown in Tables 1 to 5 at the end of this paper, and which have given the following results: 1 5 Coefficients
of correlation
between
average
reserves and average imports for the years 1959-61 for the years 1968-70
0.919 0.938
Coefficient of correlation between the increments of average reserves and the growth of average imports between
the years 1959-61
and 1968-70
0.939
12. ibid., line 17. 13. See The Times, 20 December 1971, p. 1. 14. See international bhmcial
Statistics,
February 1968 and
January 1972. 15. The figures of Tables 1 to 5 were taken from the sources in note 14 and from the National Accounts of O.E.C.D. counfries, 1950-1968. 1 Nos. 3 & 4
51
.
of correlation between
Coefficient
the average
The
reserves and average GNP (at current prices) for the years 1959-61 for the years 1966-68 4.5.
0.853 0.852
The above correlation figures signify that: (a) the volume of global reserves tend to be shared
by all countries-or at least by those of whom the sample of O.E.C.D. countries is representative-more or less in proportion to each country’s value of imports and GNP fat current prices). (Tables l-4.) (b) the increments of global reserves tend to be diffused among all countries more or less in proportion 4.6.
to each country’s growth of imports. That, however, does not mean that
(Table 5.) the global
reserve increments in the past decade were fully proportional to the growth of global imports and GNP. In fact, Table S shows that between the years 1959-61
and
1968-70
reserve
increments
corres-
ponded to only 21.1 per cent on the actual growth of imports, and the ratio of aggregate reserves to imports thus fell from 43.3 per cent in 1959-61 to 29.7 per cent in 1968-70. Yet, this less-than-proportional increase
of
the
ratio
of
reserves
to
imports
was
obviously due to the reduced supply of global reserves rather than to the fall in the demand for reserves. Actually the global reserve increments were in the past two decades created mainly by the balance-ofpayments
deficits
of
the
reserve-currency
country
(U.S.A.); and-with the exception of the massive outflow from America of speculative capital during 1970 and 1971-they were not sufficiently large to satisfy fully all the other countries’ demand for reserves; as the I.M.F. Annual Report for 1969 remarks (p. 27): ‘a case can be made for the view that by 1968 global reserve ease had not only been declining for a number of years but had also become less than adequate.’ 4.7.
The inference from the foregoing (a) all countries have a strong
is that: propensity
first
issue,
totalling
U.S.$3.4
billion,
was
allocated on 1 January 1970, and the second and third allocations, of about $3 billion each, were made on 1 January 1971 and 1972 respectively. 5.2. In principle, the issue of SDRs is an historic
to
progressive innovation which should be welcome. That, however, ought not to prevent us from pointing out their drawbacks and making suggestions for putting them on a sounder basis. Special Drawing Rights, in the way in which they have been issued, do not appear to fulfil their purpose, which was ‘to promote the attainment of the I.M.F.‘s purposes’, one of which was ‘to facilitate the expansion and balanced growth of international trade and to contribute thereby to the promotion and maintenance of high levels of employment and real income and to the development of the productive resources of all the members economic policy’. l7
as primary
objectives
of
5.3. Their first drawback is that, according to their conditions of issue, they should be convertible into currencies ‘convertible in fact’ into goldl* and that if any participant
would,
at any time,
withdraw
from
the scheme, the Fund was obligated to give it gold or ‘currencies convertible in fact’, in exchange for the SDRs it was then holding in excess of its cumulative allocation.’ 9 Following the coilapse of the gold exchange system, however, the SDRs’ convertibility and repayability have become meaningless. 5.4. So long as SDRs were, even contingently, repayable in gold, their allocation in proportion to each country’s quota in have been justified. convertibility is dead, ‘new-year presents’ inequitable way-much
the I.M.F. might conceivably Now, however, that goldSDRs have become mere distributed in the most to the rich and little
to the
poor. 5.5. Their serious drawback, however, is that they are not ‘earned’ through international trade which was the only way to fulfil their above-quoted official purposes.
accumulate reserves in amounts having a more or less close relation with the growth in the value of their imports and their GNP (in current prices); and (b) in a world of growing international trade and
5.6. It may, however, be wondered how it happened that the devisers of SDRs overlooked this crucial point. The answer can I think be found if one
GNP, an indispensable condition for the efficient working of the international monetary system, is a secular growth of global reserves, more or less commensurate with trade and GNP growth.
analyses carefully the following syllogism on SDRs contained in the I.M.F. Directors’ Report on the Reform of the International Monetary System (p. 8) published in August 1972:
5. SDRs AND THEIR DRAWBACKS
5.1. The Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) have been issued by the I.M.F. in order ‘to meet the long-term global need . . . to supplement existing reserve assets in such manner as will promote the attainment of the I.M.F.‘s purposes and will avoid economic stagnation and deflation as well as excess demand and inflation in the World’.16 52
16. Article XXIV, Monetary Fund.
17. ibid., Amck
Section
l(a)
of
the
International
I (ii).
18. ibid., Article XXV, Section 4 and XXX11 (b). 19. ibid., Schedule
H and Article XXX, Section
5.
World Development
‘With few exceptions countries feel more comfortable with an overall balance-of-payments surplus than with an overall deficit. ‘In so far as this attitude reflects a general desire of countties for rising reserves it should be possible to meet this desire by an appropriate amount of global reserve creation in the form of SDRs without the need for reliance on some countries to run payments deficits to accommodate the reserves needs of others.’ (Italics have been added.) 5.7. The first of the above two propositions is I think valid, as it agrees with the observed facts. Actually, it is not very different from my formulation of the countries’ ‘propensity to increase their reserves’ (in
paragraph 4.2 above). The validity of the second
proposition,
however,
on which the issue of SDRs as grants has been based, hinges on the hypothesis that the countries’ preference for balance-of-payments surpluses their desire to increase their reserves.
reflects
only
My own hunch is that an overall balanceofpayments surplus in a market-economy country is not the result of that country’s authorities’ desires and actions
alone,
but
the resultant
of numerous
desires
6. THE PRODUCTIVE VERSUS THE STERILE WAY OF REPLACING
6.1.
As we
sau’
GOLD
in paragraph
4.2
there
is a close
analogy between a person’s propensity to save and a country’s propensity to accumulate foreign reserves. My further thesis is that it is in the interests of the world economy that countries should earn their reserves rather than receive them as grants, in the same way that it is in the interests of a national economy that persons should earn their savings rather than receive them as a gift. 6.2. It is now a commonplace that in a modern economy the ‘propensity to save’ is un instrument of as it puts-usually-through the banking growth, system
goods
produced preneurs’ borrowed ‘multiplier
and
by the who are money. effect’,
growth in a national 6.3. In pm-banking
services
equivalent
to
those
savers at the disposal of ‘entrewilling to make ‘investments’ on Such investments, along with their are the means of development and economy. economies,
however,
the
and actions in the country’s business, personal, and public sectors. As is known, the business sector in
pensity to save’ was satisfied gold and silver. To the extent
every developed country is striving hard to maximize its sales both at home and abroad in order to realize economies of scale and raise its productivity and profits. On the other hand, the members of the personal sector have the propensity to save part of the income they derive from the business sector as wages, salaries and dividends. The combined effect of these tendencies is that the personal and business sectors ‘feel more comfortable’ when their country realizes current-account balance-of-payments those surpluses are the surpluses because, first,
took such a form, no goods and services equivalent those savings would be available for ‘investment’,
manifestation international and business
of the business
sector’s
success in the
trade contest and, second, the personal sectors combined gain financial surpluses
and increase their financial assets as a counterpart the country’s increased reserves. Therefore,
countries’
preference
for
of
balance-of-
payments surpluses reflects not only their authorities’ desire for rising reserves but also their business and personal sectors’ desire for currentaccount payments
surpluses
which
obviously
cannot
be
satisfied simply by a grant of SDRs to their monetary authorities. 5.8. The foregoing analysis leads us to the conclusion that
the
above-quoted
syllogistic
inference
is not
valid, and that an important role in the developed countries’ propensity to increase their reserves is played by their business and personal sectors, whose desires could be satisfied only if the SDRs were earned by their countries in exchange for increased exports of goods and services. It looks as though the ‘Group of Ten’, the devisers of SDRs, were led astray by a similar invalid syllogism. 5.9. The above analysis also explains why developed countries with large reserves continue unabatedly their drive to export more than they import and resent running current-account payments deficits. Vol.
1 Nos.
3 &4
‘pro-
by hoarding-mostly that current ‘savings’
they would be exchanged, directly the imported gold or silver-assuming
to as
or indirectly, for that these were
not produced at home. 6.4. Let us now suppose that one such country, finding itself unable to get any more gold from abroadlet us say, the gold-mines had been because, exhausted-decided to issue ‘paper gold’ to satisfy its people i ‘propensity to save ‘. If such ‘paper gold’ were to be distributed as a gift in proportion to the gold which each family used to save every year, the result would be that the goods and services equivalent to the savings, previously exchanged for the imported gold, would become redundant and, in the absence of a credit system, they could either be consumed by their producers . themselves or wasted. 6.5. If, however, the government of the country issuing the.‘paper gold’ wanted to develop the country, they would, instead, get their people to ‘earn’ the paper gold into their savings, for example, by setting up a credit establishment to issue long-term loans in paper gold to any enterprising some new industries at home. hand,
the people
persons willing to start In that way, on the one
who had a propensity
to save would
sell their spare goods and services directly or indirectly to the new ‘entrepreneurs’, in exchange for the paper gold; on the other hand, those goods and services would be used in new investments for the development
of the country.
6.6. The analogy of our imaginary pre-banking community wanting to introduce ‘paper gold’ to satisfy its people’s ‘propensity to save’ with the contemporary world community wanting to do the same to satisfy all the countries’ ‘propensity to accumulate reserves’ should, by now, be clear. Equally clear should be the moral drawn from this 53
analogy:
SDRs
namely, activity by
can
‘expansion
fulfii
their
developed
development
as grants
purpose
of
remain
countries
exports
allocated
developing extent
by
such
to the developed
of employment, on the other
increased SDRs;
SDRs
countries are
for the
instance,
to
development
incomes, exports hand, SDRs granted
or
only
thirty-two
months
of
of SDRs during
their
life (up
1972)* 1 proves the above point. (a) Out of the global allocations the the
to
more
employment,
31 August
the whole
of SDRs during
their The
SDRs
industrial
amounting
countries,
to $2,877
who
million,
have kept all their SDRs unused, with the exception of only $11 million used by Denmark. (d) The remaining SDRs, amounting to $3,138, were allocated to 99 non-industrialized countries who used
only
one-third
of
them
($1,037
millionj
in
payment of imports. The other two-thirds of their allocations ($2,101 million) have not been used so far, with
the exception
of $169 million,
which
may
be considered as having enabled their holders to use part of their other reserves. For example, Pakistan’s reserves at the end of 1969 amounted to $324 million, but by the end of August 1972 they were reduced to $265 million, including SDRs 36 million. In this case, it may be argued that the latter SDRs enabled Pakistan to use an equivalent amount of her other reserves and that they halve therefore played the same role as if they were actually used. (e) Summarizing the above, we find that of the $9,315 million SDRs issued during the past three years: 77 per cent ($7,184 million) remained economically sterile; 13 per cent tively; and
($1,217
million)
10 per cent ($914 mi!lion) of their recipients’ financial 54
were
used
produc-
were used in payment obligations.
SDRs
demand
1968-70,
incomes
would
and
ultimately
have
in proportion
to
with
the and
above. for develop-
and services would have fulfilled their main purpose and would have contrithe
realization
too-exchange stagnation,
been
19.59-61 4.5(b)
in
to each
as was done
between
have
exports
ejfects.
the issue of SDRs in exchange
ment goods abovequoted
and
countries
multiplier
them,
created
would
developed
as we saw in paragraph
Thus,
buted
tbe
the world for
reserves
employment, countries,
of the above
into
with further
throughout
country’s
world, nor to have in any way mitigated the 1971 dollar crisis. (b) Britain’s total SDR allocations were $1,006 million, of which $423 million were used in payment of her obligations to the 1.M.F. The remaining SDRs have augmented her reserves, but such augmentation does not appear to have increased employment,
world,
TtJe
diffused new
remainder ($1,803 million) have been added to the U.S.A.‘s reserves. Such addition, however, does not appear to have promoted economic activity, trade, or development, either in the U.S.A. or in the rest of the
allocated
effect
creating
$491 million were used in payment of obligations to the I.M.F. and other countries.
incomes, or exports, at all. (c) The remaining twelve
multiplier
to the
the first
to the
World.
imports
years 1970-2, amounting to $9.315 million,** U.S.A. received $2,294 million. Of these, only
were
The
(ii)
(iii) performance
in the Third
more
their
issued
to equivalent
in the developed
induced
that they are used by them for increasing
The actual
rise
and exports
to
imports. 6.7.
all the SDRs had been
have given
conducive
will be productive
liable
If, instead,
developed countries in exchange for goods and services supplied to the Third World for development purposes, the result would have been quite different: (i) All the $9,315 million SDRs would, in the first incomes
reserves i.e., not
sterile,
countries
6.8.
to
their
economically
purpose,
economic
through
financed
increasing
any growth development;
main
trade,
only if they are earned
and development’,20
the
jkt
of international
stability,
of
their
other
avoidance
of
purposes economic
etc.
7. THE BEST, REALISTIC, NEW SDRs (or IRUs)
WAY OF GETTING EARNED
7.1. If the foregoing thesis is sound, the next question is: What is the best, realistic, way toget the new SDRs
earned
by the
countries
wanting
to increase
their reserves, thereby contributing to the growth of international trade and the deveIopment of the productive resources of the whole world? 7.2. Having regard to what we have ascertained so far, I venture tentatively to put forward the following scheme: (a) New SDRs-to which, jb~ dijyerentiation purposes, Units’
I will give
the name
‘International
Reserve
fIR Us&-will
be issued by a Special Department of the I.M.F. to those members of the Development Assistance Committee (D.A.C.) (now comprising the 16 richest countries23
nations) of the O.E.C.D. and any other who will agree to participate in the
20. This is how the I.M.F. Managing-Director summarized the first objecti,ve of the SDRs in his Report to the Governors in September 1969 (see International Resemes -~ Needs and Availability, I.M.F.. 1970, p. 493). 21. See Intemntronal Financial Staristics, October 1972, p. 7. The figures of SDRs used, quoted above, differ somewhat from the totals shown on p. 7, because the latter are net totals, whereas mine are dggegnre totals. 22.
All
$
figures
in
this
paper
ue
pre-Smithsonian
U.S.
dOkUS.
23. LDCs that are in a position to contribute to the development of other LDCs could participate as lenders, provided that the loans are denominated in the convertible currency of a developed country. Such participation should not prejudice the lending country’s right to borrow under the IRU scheme for its own development. World Develupment
scheme,
against the discount
of ‘eligible’24
bonds
guaranteed, by governments to them, or less developed countries (LDCs) in connexion new development loans. Such loans should be additional development country
assistance
and should
(i) the supplied
to the
due of with
official
level given in 1971-2
by each
cover:
cost of goods and services by the lending country direct
for a development
project
currently to an LDC
or programme;
(ii) the local expenditures
and
of such project
or pro-
gramme. Thus,
part
and part,
of the loan in foreign
will be in goods
exchange,
which
and services
will enable
the
borrowing country to pay for the imports to be induced by the local expenditures needed for implementing the project or programme for which the loan is given. The lending country will then be credited by the I.M.F. with IRUs equal to the full value of the discounted bond less a small commission. (b) The lending county discounting the bonds with the I.M.F. will act as a guarantor of such bonds. (cl The debt under these bonds will be, like the National Public Debts, a ‘funded’ debt, on which only the
interest
will
be
annually
payable-without
amortization. (d) Such bonds will be currency of the lending county
denominated in the and will bear interest
at a uniform low rate, say, 3% per cent p-a. payable annually by the borrowing country to the I.M.F., and in case of default, by the guarantor. On the other hand, the I.M.F. will pay interest at, say, 3 per cent to the holders of IR Us. (e) Participant countries, which will include both lenders and borrowers as well as other countries, will undertake- to accept IRUs as a medium of international payments, unconditionally. cf, The IRU will be the common denominator of all currencies; its unit value will be fixed equal to the average parity value of one currency unit of all the participating
lending
countries
on the D-day.
On the
basis of the parity (or central) rates ruling in February 1972, one IRU would be equal to U.S. $0.4685, or Dh11.5097,or 4ZO.1798,or FFr.2.3967. (g) All countries will be able to devalue or upvalue their currencies against the IRU, in the same way as they do at present I.M.F. Article IV.
against
gold,
in accordance
with
(b) IRUs will be used as a reserve asset, side by side with gold, but they will not be obligatorily convertible
into gold.
8. BILATERAL
IRU SCHEME VERSUS
SDRs MULTILATERALLY
LINKED WITH
DEVELOPMENT
8.1. The fundamental scheme and the present Vol. 1 Nos. 3 & 4
differences between my 1RU SDR system are that, whereas
SDRs are allocated virtually as grants to all the countries in proportion to each one’s 1.M.F. quota, of which, as we saw in Section 6, only being used for ‘productive’ purposes:
13 per cent are
(a) all IRL’s will be issued to the developed countries; (b) such issue will be against a valuable consideration-goods, services and foreign exchange; and (cl all such consideration development purposes.
will
go to LDCs for
Thus the issue of IRUs will, in the first instance, give rise to equivalent exports of goods and services from the developed to the developing countries, to be followed induced
by further growth of international trade by the ‘multiplier effect’, thereby fulfilling
the original international ment’.
object of SDRs, trade, economic
namely, activity
‘expansion of and develop-
8.2. The main points of differentiation between the IRU scheme and other proposals for linking SDRs with development2 5 are, besides the above, that: (a) all the IRUs will be linked with development; (6) the link will be through bilateral loans rather than through multilateral-institution loans. The first point over the hitherto
is obviously demanded
a very great advantage SDR multilateral link,
the extent of which, if it were ever accepted by the developed countries, would not amount to more than a fraction of the global issue of SDRs. The second point may, on the face of it, appear to be a disadvantage. Before considering, however, the advantages and disadvantages, if any, of the bilateralism of the IRU scheme, we should inquire into the chances that an SDR fully multilateral link system has of being adopted by the developed countries. 8.3. The post-war history of official foreign aid shows that the industrial developed countries overwhelmingly prefer bilateral rather than multilateral and ‘tied’ratber than ‘untied’aid. This is evident from the following
facts:
(a) The famous
‘Marshall Plan ‘, at the end of the
1940s and beginning economy of Western ‘tied ‘.
of the 1950s which restored the Europe, was wholly bilateral and
(b) During the last few years, about 95 per cent of the American official foreign aid has been bilateral (of which
86 per cent was in goods and services
per cent in dollar
currency)
24. See the ‘eligibility’ conditions
and only
and 9
5 per cent
was
in paragraph 14.8.
25. See. for example, the proposal of the UNCTAD Expert Group on International Monetary Issues in their Report Intematronal Monetary Reform and Co-operation for Development (TDIB/tSS), U.N., 1969. p. 14: ‘One method [for implementing a link with development aid1 would involve an amendment to the Articles of Agreement of I.M.F. to permit the direct contribution of SDRs bYy the developed countries to I.D.A. out of their allocatzom. The other method would involve contributions in national currencies by the developed countries to I.D.A. in proportion to SDRs annually allocated to them. ’ 55
.
‘multilateral untied’ aid through international and regional credit institutions.26 (c) Also, British aid in last has been about 90 cent bilateral and presumably ‘tied’ and only 10 per cent multilateral.27 (d) The Commission on International Development makes the following remarks in its Report: ‘The of aid to purchases in the aid-giving tying spread a contagious fashion in the country. . 196Os, than
and
untied
aid
now the
rather
8.4. of the above, I believe that of a fully-multilateral SDR-development
the chances link being
adopted by the developed countries in the near future are rather slight.29 On the contrary, a bilateral system such as the one proposed here should have much more chance of being accepted by the parties, since, besides its other advantages, it is based on the existing practice of official bilateral assistance, the extension Strategy ment.
of which
to
the
of Development30
target
set
by the
it is intended
8.5. The IRU system described above, bilateral, should not have the disadvantages aid for the following reasons:
U.N.
to implethough of tied
(a) As mentioned in paragraph 7.2(a), part of the loans under this system will be in foreign exchange intended
to enable
the borrowing
country
to pay for
the imports induced by the local expenditure of the project or programme. This part of the loans will be ‘untied’ and will therefore, though bilateral, have all the advantages of multilateralism. (b) The main part of the loans, which will cover the cost of goods and services directly supplied by the lending country, will of course be ‘tied’, though, for the reasons given below, they should not be expected to have the disadvantages of ‘tied aid’. 8.6. As reported by the Commission on International Development31 the main disadvantage of tied aid is that the ‘direct costs . . frequently exceed by 20 per cent’ competitive market prices. This, I believe, is due to the fact that bilateral aid has the taint of charity which gives, on the one band, to the donor the sense of superiority which enables bim to dictate the terms of the deal, and, on the other band, to the recipient the feeling of inferiority which prevents him from bargaining those terms. Under the LRU system,
however,
and especially
when it is well established, the said relationship will evolve into one of a seller, on the one hand, who is paid for his goods and services ‘in cash’ (IRUs), and of a buyer, on the other hand, to whom easy financial terms are extended by the I.M.F. rather than by the seller, and who is free to bargain the terms of the transaction and to compare them with those of alternative suppliers. Under this new relationship, the suppliers will have to charge international market prices raised only by a certain margin to cover their guarantee obligation32 and their other special costs of the transaction. 8.7. Furthermore, the IRU scheme is expected to 56
have certain definite advantages over the SDR tiltilateral link system: (a) Under the IRU scheme countries with spare productive
the deficit developed capacity will be able
to take the initiative and increase the official bilateral development assistance which they already provide, thus gaining, and second,
first, the trade surpluses they long for, the IRUs they need. Under the SDR
multilateral link system, however, the chances would be that most of the SDRs (or the equivalent foreign exchange) loaned out by I.D.A., would be gained by the more competitive surplus countries. (b)
Under
the holders
the
IRU scheme,
of IRUs-which
interest
payment
to
is of course
essential
for
the efficient operation of the system-is secured by the guarantee on the part of the developed country presenting the bond to the I.M.F. for discount,33 as is usual in domestic discounting business. Something similar would apparently be difficult to do in connection with the multilateral link system. (c) Under the latter system, the I.D.A._‘s and other Development Banks’ administrative Regional expenses, amounting perhaps to 1 per cent p.a. on the loans34 would either increase the interest charged on the loans or reduce the interest payable to the holders of IRUs. Under the IRU bilateral system all the preparatory work for the development projects and programmes will be done by the developed countries issuing the loan, and even if the expenses involved were to be added to the price of the goods and services supplied, the LDC would have to pay only the annual
interest
thereon.
26. See U.S. Survey of Current Business. June 1971. Table 5, p. 40. Total U.S. official foreign aid in 1970 amounted to $5,05Om, of which $4,348m were ‘transactions involving no direct dollar outflow from the U.S.‘, while $702m involved dollar payments, of which 9234m were ‘capital subscriptions to international and regional organizations excluding I.M.F.’ 27. See U.K. Balance of Payments, 1971, Table 43. p. 46. Total U.K. official economic aid in 1970 amounted to &219m, of which only EtOm was multilateral through the I.D.A., the Asian Development Bank or other agencies. 28. Partners in Devefopment (the Pearson Report), Pall Mall Press, London 1969, p. 172. 29. ‘. . . the idea [of a link between SDRs and development aid! was generally unwelcome to industrial countries who felt that . reserve creation should not provide a back door through from
which aid-giving could be freed, in some measure, the restraints of pnrliammrary control over
expenditure.’ Quotation from Pierre-Paul Schweitzer. ‘New arrangements to supplement world reserves and their implications for the developing countries’, fncemationnl Financial News Suruey. 15 December 1967, p. 418. 30. See Section 14. 31. Partners in Development. p. 172. 32. See Section 33.
See paragraph
10. 7.2(b)
34. See World Bank and 80, 82, 94 and 95. 1971 total balances, 98.562m.
and Section
10. pp. 3, $2,48Zm:
I.D.A. Annual Report, 1971, expenses.
976m;
loans,
World Development
(d)
Last
but
not
the developed
least,
would under the IRU system in the development of the under
the
SDR multilateral
be mere sleeping but
taking
partners,
no active
countries
become active partners Third World, whereas link system
supplying
they
would
only the capital
part in the development
effort.
THE IDCs’ DEBTS
The
errtiating financed debts,
second
main point
of my scheme,
it from others, is that by IRUs will be in the
on which
will be payable,
differ-
the loans to be form of ‘funded’
only interest at, say, 3% per cent p.a, without annual amortization. Such a
proposal may, at fist sight, appear rather unorthodox. In fact, however, it is simply an extension of a system prevalent in all domestic economies. 9.2. If we take a look at most national monetary systems we will see that they are all backed by funded public debts, which are in fact permanent debts, although part of them is technically ‘unfunded’. At the end of 1970: l (a) The U.K.‘s ‘reserve money’-currency in circulation and commercial banks’ deposits with the Bank of England-amounting to 164.7 billion, was wholly backed by U.K. Government securities;3 5 (b) the U.S.A.‘s ‘reserve money’, amounting to $81 billion, was backed by $69 billion worth of claims on the U.S. Government, $11 billion in gold, and $1 billion (part of) I.M.F. gold tranche position.36 9.3. As is well known, national monetary and banking systems are based on the statistical law of large numbers in spite behaviour.
and the constancy of the society’s bebaviour of the unpredictability of individuals’
In this connexion, although individuals’ savings are ‘liquid’, the savings of a modern society, as a whole, are permanent and ever growing. Therefore, the counterpart-or ‘backing’-of a society’s savings may very well be permanent and ever growing, too-as they
actually
9.4.
The
are in all modern
same
applies
also
societies.
to
international
liquid
savings in the form of monetary reserves: they too are permanent and perennially growing, and tberifore their liquidity will not be harmed if their ‘backing’ consists
of permanent
and growing funded
9.6.
In the case of the
will
be
LDCs’ funded
counterpart
obviously be thereto-debtors,
of resources
of
the
never replace debts,
IRUs,
more convenient guarantors and
towards
the industrial
eased. How unbearably be, should the present
it
for all I.M.F.-if
which would parties their
tinue,
IS shown
countries,
will be
heavy this burden will shortly system of amortization con-
by the following
quotation
from
the
Report of the Commission on International Develop ment:37 ‘If the flow of new lending were to remain at the level of 1965-7, with no change in its composition,. . . by 1977, debt service [interest and amortization] would considerably exceed new lending’: e.g., East Asia’s debt service will be 134 per cent of new gross lending, Africa’s 121 per cent, Latin America’s 130 per cent, Europe’s 109 per cent and South Asia’s and the Middle East’s 97 per cent. 9.8.
It should
be realized
that it is equally
unrealistic
and a ‘fallacy of composition’ to contemplate the eventual redevnption of the debts of all the LDCs as a whole template
to
the
industrial
the redemption
countries,
as it is to con-
of internal
public
debts.
In
either case, such redemption would involve a largescale reverse flow of resources-in the former, from the poor to the rich countries, and in the latter from the taxpayers to the savers-which, if ever attempted, would create severe deflation and chronic economic depression. Those who may doubt, should look back to the reparations imposed on Germany after the First World War. For the fist five years Germany paid the reparations to the Allies with money borrowed from the U.S.A. In 1931, however, when the U.S.A. wanted its money back, the whole of Europe virtually went bankrupt, and the U.S.A. had to proclaim in June 1931 the famous ‘Hoover Moratorium’ which, inter alia, put an end to the German reparations, though too late to avert the advent of Hitler.
debts. 10.
9.5. The funding of public debts is done either with fixed redemption dates or with indefinite redemption dates, like British ‘undated’ funds, such as ‘Consols 2.5 p-c. 1923 or after’, ‘War Loan 3.5 p.c. 1952 or after’, etc. Both ‘fixed-dated’ and ‘undated’ public funds are in fact permanent loans; the only difference is that, in the former case, the public authorities have to make, on the fixed redemption date, a new issue, at the ruling interest rate-which may be higher or lower than that of the original fund-whereas in the case of ‘undated’ funds, on which the interest payable is Vol. 1 Nos. 3 & 4
the
need
redemption dates were made indefinite-for example, ‘2000 or after’, thus obviating the need for renewal. 9.7. By funding the LDCs’ debts to be financed through the IRUs, the already heavy debt-service burden of the LDCs, which necessitates a reverse flow
9. THE CASE FOR ‘FUNDING’
9.1.
usually very low, the authorities them by a new issue.
GUARANTEE
OF THE INTEREST
ON DEVELOPMENT
PAYMENTS
LOANS
10.1. The third main distinguishing point of my scheme is the guarantee of the discounted bonds by tbe lending
countries
35. See International 349. 36.
ibid., p. 355.
37.
Partners
in
receiving
IRUs in exchange
Financral Sratistics, January
1972,
for
p.
Development, p. 74. 57
those bonds. As is known, such a guarantee banking business whenever the payee discounts it in exchange for cash.
is usual in of a bill
the principal, and second, they will be denominated in national currencies which are subject to a secular tendency to depreciation and devaluation.
A similar guarantee is suggested in the case of the bonds that will back the IRUs, in order to secure the 11. PARITY
CHANGES BETWEEN
payment of the interest due on such bonds and enable the I.M.F. in its turn regularly to pay the holders of IRUs the interest due to them. In practice, as most of the IRUs will ultimately be held by the developed countries, the latter will at the same time be guarantors and beneficiaries of the interest on such IRUs. So, such a guarantee is to a great extent in the interest of the developed countries themselves, and it is of course indispensable for the smooth working of the system. 10.2. As is mentioned in paragraph 8.6, the suppliers of goods and services will in practice tend to raise their prices by a certain margin to cover the risk
the Fund the difference, initially in its own currency, and eventually in an acceptable convertible currency,
undertaken by them by this guarantee. This price rise, however, is not expected to be significant and in any case what the debtors will have to pay is only the interest on such a rise.
in gold, or in SDRs. In case of upvaluation, the Fund refunds the difference to the country concerned.38 11.2. In the case of IRUs, the question will arise as to who has to pay the difference and how. Can the
10.3.
Fund
ally
The risks under such guarantees be
pooled
under
insurance schemes. margin mentioned
ad
hoc
could eventu-
regional
or global
In such a case, the price-rise in the previous paragraph will
equal the insurance premium. 10.4. A problem will, however,
arise with
the very
poor LDCs, which will be a ‘poor risk’ for such insurance. It would be too bad if the very poor LDCs, being
a ‘poor
risk’,
were
either
by-passed
‘by the
developed countries or burdened with higher prices. The solution of this problem would obviously lie in relieving the very poor LDCs from the payment of interest on their development loans. Thus, the very poor LDCs will become the very best clients of the developed countries as the goods and services supplied to them will be paid for in ‘cash’ (IRUs) without any risk on the part of the suppliers. If the principle of relieving the very poor LDCs of obligations is adopted, their interest-payment provision should also be made for border-line cases for which it would be fair to fix a lower inrerest rate than the normal one. 10.5. In order to accommodate the cases of the very poor LDCs as well as those on the border-line, it would be necessary that the normal interest payable to the I.M.F. on the development loans under the
NATIONAL
CURRENCIES
AND IRUs
11.1. As national currencies may be upvalued against IRUs, provision should
devalued or be made for
compensating the I.M.F. for its loss on bonds payable in devalued currencies and also for adjusting the difference due to a currency upvaluation. For similar cases, the I.M.F. Articles provide that, if a country which is a debtor to the Fund for drawings devalues its currency, that country has to pay to
claim such difference
If the
loans
were
from the debtor
in terms
of IRUs,
country? the debtor
would obviously be liable to pay the devaluation difference. In the scheme envisaged above, however, the development loans will be, as usual, in terms of the lender’s currency. Therefore, the debtor cannot be held liable for any exchange difference between , the currency in which its loan was expressed and the IRUs received by the lender against the discount of the debtor’s bond, especially since the devaluation decision is taken by the lender itself. The inference, therefore, is that the lender and guarantor which received the IRUs and which is now devaluing its currency against the IRU, has to make up the devaluation difference to the Fund. 11.3. Since the original debt against which the IRUs had been issued was, as contemplated above, a funded debt, it is only fair that the difference should also be paid in the same way, by a bond signed by the lender/guarantor bearing the same interest and having the same maturity as the original bond. Thus, the actual burden to the devaluing country will be only the annual interest on the devaluation difference of the bonds already discounted with the Fund. 11.4.
On the same reasoning,
the inference
would
be
IRU scheme should be a little-perhaps % per centhigher than the interest payable by the I.M.F. to the
that if a country entitled to claim
holders of IRUs. This difference could be either added to the interest rate paid by the debtors to make it, say, 3.5 per cent, or deducted from the interest rate payable to the IRU holders to make it 2.5 per cent. It seems to me that the latter would make the IRUs less attractive as a reserve asset vis-his reserve currencies, whereas the former would not make the debtservice burden on the average LDC too heavy, provided that, as I am proposing in this paper, first, the loans will be perpetual with no amortization of
difference on the bonds already discounted with the Fund. However, it could be argued, that, ongrounds of equity, the poor debtors should not be compelled to pay interest of a higher real value than before, simply because its rich lender opted, for reasons of its own, to increase the real value of its currency. If the equity line is adopted, the upvaluing (lender) country’s position towards the Fund, regarding the bonds already discounted, will remain
58
38. I.M.F.
Arricle
upvalues its currency from the Fund the
IV, Section
it is legally upvaluation
8. World Development
unchanged, while the Fund will be able to relieve the debtors of part of the interest due to the Fund in terms of the upvalued 11.5.
Unlike
gold
currency.
and
the reserve
currencies,
IRUs
of ail 59 countries,
the U.S.A.,
for all the
years 1954 to 1968, was an almost reserves-imports ratio of about 40 per 476-8).
excluding
constant cent (pp.
will be capable of devaluation or upvaluation without any repercussions on any domestic economy or on
(iv) The actual reserves-imports ratio of the countries for 1968 was only 33 per cent (p. 473).
the international
12.2. On the basis of these and other calculations it was concluded by the I.M.F. that ‘by 1968 global reserves ease bad not only been declining for a number of years but bad also become less than adequate ‘,40 and that SDRs should be issued in order
economy.
In view of the secular trends of price inflation over the world, I think that a general devaluation
all of
the IRU against all currencies will be called for, say, every decade-or earlier if so decided by the prescribed majority of participants-in order to relieve the
to supplement
existing
reserve
59
assets.
lenders, which would in the meantime have devalued their currencies, of the interest (or part of it) payable
The I.M.F. Managing-Director’s proposal, in September 1969, on the SDRs allocation of $9.5
by them,
billion
Such to
the
as per paragraph a devaluation weighted
11.3 above.
could
be fixed
average
at a rate equal
devaluation
during
the
(at the old exchange
rate of the dollar)
first basic period 1970-2, appears on the following estimates:41
for the
to have been based
decade-or other shorter period-of all the currencies in which the discounted bonds are denominated.
(i) If the normal growth in the need for reserves were to be measured by the growth of imports over
Supposing that such an average devaluation is found to have been 20 per cent, the I.M.F. would then distribute to each holder of IRUs new IRUs
the 1952-68
equal to 25 per cent of its holdings, provided that in the case of countries owing devaluation differences to the Fund, the Fund would set off such debts against their share of new IRUs.
(ii) Other approaches, estimating the need for lower rates of increase.
At the same time, the necessary adjustments will have to be made regarding differences due to previous upvaluations of currencies, as per paragraph 11.4 above. Thus,
the
countries
with
a lower
than
average
currency devaluation during the previous decade will have their devaluation-difference debts settled and will also receive a supplementary issue of IRUs to make up for the devaluation
of the IRU.
12. THE TARGET ANNUAL
12.1.
A crucial
reserve creation.
RESERVE
question
creation As this
several exhaustive findings, published
is the problem
VOLUME OF CREATION
in any scheme
of deliberate
annual volume of such has been the subject of
studies by the I.M.F. staff, their in June 1969 in an article entitled
‘Quantitative criteria needs’, are relevant.39
for the assessment of reserve Here are some of them:
(i) The 1954-64 annual average trend rate of growth qf reserves of industrial countries, excluding the U.S.A., was 8.4 per cent, and that of their imports 8 per cent (p. 475). (ii) The corresponding trend for all 59 countries for which reliable data were available, excluding the U.S.A., showed an average annual rate of growth of resewes of 5.8 per cent, and of 7.4 per cent for imports
reserves annum.
period,
would
the long-term
increase
trend
in required
at the rate of 7 per cent per however, reserves,
might be used for which would give
To be on the safe side, the required growth of reserves was taken to be about 6 per cent per annum on the 1968 global volume of reserves ($77 billion), that is, about $4.5 billion. (iii) Of these, $1 to 1.5 billion were expected to be covered by the growth of gold reserves, reserve positions in the Fund, U.S. dollars and other currencies. Thus, the first allocations of SDRs were fixed at $3.5 billion for the first year (1970) and at $3 billion for each of the following two years. 12.3. Actual developments during the past three years from 30 June 1968 however, been very different
to 30 June 1971 from expectations:
have,
(a) The average rate of growth of world imports has been double the 1952-68 trend, namely 14 per cent per annum.42 (b)
The
dollar
component
of
global
reserves
increased from $15.9 on 30 June 1968 to $34.3 on of 30 June 1971,43 and during the third quarter 1971 it increased by a further $11 billion, raising the total to over $45 billion.
39. Republished in International Reserves Availability, I.M.F., 1970, pp. 464-90. 40.
See I.M.P. Annual Report,
-
Needs
and
1969, p. 27.
41. See the I.M.F. Managing-Director’s Report to the Board of Governors, republished in International Reserues. . ., op. cit., pp. 501-2.
(p. 475 ).
(iii) The above-mentioned trends were distorted by past redistributions of reserves from countries with initially high reserves-imports ratios to those with low ratios. After eliminating these distortions by regression analysis it was found that the ‘ideal trend’ Vol. 1 Nos. 3 & 4
42. See International Financial Statistics, January 1970, p. 33 and January 1972, p. 37. World imports in years-ending 30 June 1968 and 1971 were $209 and 312 billion respectively. 43. See International January 1972.
k’inancial Statistics,
January
1970 and
59
(c) Global placing market,
reserves
were
also
inflated
by
the
of official reserves in the Euro-currency which resulted in counting the same reserves
twice-first, secondly
in
in the depositor-country’s the reserves of the
reserves and country whose
residents had borrowed that money from the Eurothe Euro-currency component of market. Thus, global reserves, during the same period (1968-71), increased from $3.3 to 14.5 billion.44 (d) Official holdings of gold increased by only $250m per annum-from $40.5 billion on 30 June 1968 to $41.3 billion on 30 June 1971.45 12.4.
The
total
volume
of
world
reserves
on
30
September 1971, standing at $117 billion, gives the false impression of adequacy, as it represents a 35.5 per cent compared
ratio with
to world imports a similar ratio of
($330 billion), 34.2 per cent in
1968 ($77 billion reserves to $225 billion imports).46 In fact, however, a large part of present reserves
with
the signing
would
show
of the aforesaid
in their
external
bonds-which
accounts
long-term capital’. Besides that, could, if they wanted to increase
they
as ‘inflow
of
however, the LDCs their reserves, try to
export to the developed countries more goods than they imported-apart from those covered by bonds-in which case they would also have overall surpluses paid for by the developed countries with part of their IRUs. All the other countries, nor
receive
balance-of-payments developed countries they
imported
which
neither
give
also
have
surpluses by exporting more goods and services
to than
IRU-financed
from
would
loans,
them,
could
receiving
in exchange
part
of the latter countries’ IRUs. Thus, although IRUs will, in the first instance, be received by the developed countries, they will ultimately be diffused into the international monetary system in proportion to each country’s demand for reserves, provided of course that, first, such demand is matched by the requisite competitiveness, and secorrd, the volume of annual reserve creation is sufficiently large. Therefore, under the IRU system, balance-of
consists of short-term funds (mostly American) which are bound, sooner or later, to be repatriated. If this ‘hot money’ is excluded from permanent, owned, international reserves, the ratio of global reserves to imports in 1971 was lower than that of 1968, which was considered by the I.M.F. experts as inadequate. 12.5. Before attempting to make any estimate of the future needs of global reserve growth, 1 would like to point out that, under a system of a fiduciary reserve medium as envisaged here, it would be wrong to aim
supplied to LDCs.
‘to shorten the duration and lessen the degree’ of balance-of~ayments surpluses, as implied by I.M.F. Article I (vi).
volume another
It is certainly true that under the gold exchange standard, and especially under conditions of a zero-
issued so far and the IRUs proposed here. As the SDRs are issued virtually as gifts
sum game (as I argued balance-of-payments
distributed in an obviously arbitrary and inequitable way, their volume has to be estimated with great caution and wariness.
in Section 3 above), surpluses in
overall some
competitively-strong countries provoked deficits in others, and the rules of the game therefore required all countries to try negative imbalances.
to minimize
12.6. Under the system overall balance-of-payments
both
positive
and
proposed here, however, surpluses would not
necessarily create corresponding deficits. On the contrary, the ideal situation would be one in which all countries in the world bad overall balance-ofpayments surpluses, the counterpart of which would, for the developed countries, be the net amount of goods and services supplied to less developed countries in the way described in Sections 7 above and 14 below, financed by the issue of IRUs; and for all the other countries, the net amount of goods and services which they supplied to the developed countries. In other words, the developed countries will show balance-of-payments surpluses because they would export more goods and services than they imported, and receive the difference in IRUs by discounting with the I.M.F. the bonds covering part of their exports to LDCS.“~ On the other hand, the less developed countries would basically square their balance of payments
payments surpluses. especially of the rich countries, should be encouraged rather than disapproved of, as implied
by
counterpart 12.7.
Coming
the of
I.M.F. such
back
of reserve fundamental
inasmuch
Articles, surpluses
to the
will
question
be
as the
resources
of the
annual
creation, I would like to stress difference between the SDRs as and are
In the case of IRUs, however, as they will be issued against a valuable consideration, there is no reason for particular caution and wariness especially since the consideration will be mostly goods and services already supplied by countries which have, presumably, judged that they could afford to do so without any risk of excess-demand inflation to their domestic economy. The issue, therefore, of IRUs cannot be excessive from the point of view of the countries supplying the equivalent resources in the first instance. As, however, such issues are bound to have multiplier effects on the international economy, it would be advisable for the issuing authority (the I.M.F.) to fix a target ceiling for its annual IRU creation in order to avert a world excessdemand inflation, which is hypothetically possible, although, as I argue in Section 17 below, the real danger facing
44.
ibid.
45.
ibid.
46.
ibid. World
Development
the world
today
and in the coming years
is economic
stagnation rather than excess-demand inflation. 12.8. Without playing the crystalgazer, I will now try to make a rough estimate of such a target ceiling of IRU tions,
creation,
based
on the
and on the following
(a) World imports to grow at an annual
foregoing
considera-
assumptions:
at current prices will continue rate of about 10 per cent, and
will amount to about $400 billion (at the previous dollar value) in 197 3. (b) World GNP at current prices will continue to grow at an annual rate of about 8 per cent4* (c) Global reserves, which on 30 September 1971 amounted to $117 billion, will, excluding the ‘hot amount in 1973 to about $100 billion, money’,49 corresponding to only 25 per cent of global imports. (d) Insignificant quantities of gold will be added to official holdings. (e) Under the new monetary like all other
countries,
proportion to its trade probably more than that, their present shortfall. (f,
On the other
system,
the U.S. will,
tend to increase
its reserves
in
and GNP growth-and in order to make up for
hand,
the volume
be demanded by the enlarged Community will, as a percentage
of reserves
to
be lower than so far, in view of the expected morethan-worldaverage increase in their inter-community
venture
to
suggest
annual
creation
that of
period-which
might
1974-should
be
namely,
rhe
IRUs
during
hopefully
7 per
cent
ceiling the
begin
for
first
I the
basic
on 1 January
on the
$100
billion,
$7 billion.
13. THE FUTURE THE RESERVE
13.1.
target
If a scheme
medium, question
for the creation
AND SDRs
of a new reserve
such as the IRU, is to be adopted, will arise: what is to be done with
present balances
reserve media-gold, and SDRs?
dollar
and
the the
sterling
13.2. At the end of September 1971 gold represented 31 per cent of global reserves ($36.2 billion out of $117.3 billion). If the trend of the past decade continues, additions
it is very doubtful to official gold holdings
if in future any will be made at all.
For example, the use of gold for industrial and artistic purposes in 1958 absorbed 28 per cent of newly available gold ($360m out of $1,26lm). By 1970
this
proportion
increased
to
67
per
cent
($975m out of $1,450m).50 If this trend continues, and assuming that the annual demand for gold for hoarding purposes will be only 14 per cent ($200m)-which was the minimum so far-the demand for gold in the private market will very shortly outstrip current production. 13.3. In the circumstances, and having regard to the Vol.
1 Nos. 3 & 4
provided
for, ‘each member
currency member
held shall
shall buy balances
of its
by another member’, and ‘the buying have the option to pay either in the
currency of the member gold, or in IR Us’. Article
V should
making
the request,
be amended
or in
so that IRUs
will be acceptable by the Fund, as well asgold, when a member wants to purchase another member’s currency, charges.
or to repurchase
its own currency
or to pay
Provision should also be made in the Articles for the Fund to be able ‘to require any member to sell its currency to the Fund for either gold or IRUs’ when that currency is in legitimate demand by other members. (Amendment of Article VII, Section 2, which now provides for replenishment of the Fund’s holdings of scarce currencies, for gold). 13.5. Un.der the amendments proposed above, although all countries will have the option to pay in gold, no country will be obliged to give gold in exchange for its own or any other currency. Thus, the monetary continue
OF GOLD,
CURRENCIES
countries already holding it. 13.4. Under the scheme proposed here all currencies will be convertible into IRUs. To this end the relevant I.M.F. Articles will have to be amended accordingly. For example, Article VIII, Section 4, should be amended to the effect that, subject to the conditions
Also,
European Economic of imports, tend to
trade and their monetary cooperation. On the above considerations and assumptions,
inelastic supply of gold and the role of speculators, it is very likely that the free-market price of gold will always tend to exceed its official price for monetary purposes, and that very little new gold, if any, will flow into the coffers of the monetary authorities in future. In view of this tendency, gold cannot and should not continue to be the primary reserve asset, although it will most probably continue for long to form part, and indeed the residual of the reserves of the
system will be untied to use gold as a reserve
from gold, but it will component.
13.6. World consensus now appears to support the view that the role of the dollar and the pound sterling as reserve national long
currencies currencies
as they
were,
should played
be phased
their
or they
out.
reserveasset
pretended
These role so
to be,
con-
vertible into gold. Following the collapse of the gold exchange standard, however, they cannot continue playing
that
system
were
47. In order flows.
role,
unless
the international
to be converted
into
monetary
an inconvertible
to simplify my description
I ignore capital
48. Between 1965 and 1968 the GNP (at current prices) of all O.E.C.D. countries grew at the rate of 8.3 per cent (O.E.C.D. National Accounts, 1950-68, pp. 11-13); and during 1969. and 1970, due to price inflation, the rate of growth of GNP of most countries was higher than 8 per cent Unternntional Financial Statistics, January 1972). 49. Even if the expected reflux of ‘hot money’ does not materialize, the arrangement suggested therefor in paragraph 13.9 will reduce global reserves. 50. See I.M.F. Annual Report,
1971. p. 146.
. 61
dollar standard, which monopolistic power countries.
would give the United States a unacceptable to the other
A rough be made liabilities
estimate
of this short-term
capital
could
by comparing the increase of U.S. official with the U.S. ‘basic’ balance-of-payments
13.7. Already Great Britain, during its negotiations for entering the E.E.C., has made the following declaration about the future of sterling balances: ‘We are prepared to envisage an orderly and gradual rundown of official sterling balances after our acceswe shall manage our sion . . In the meantime,
deficit was only $8.8; this means that the net shortterm capital outflow from the U.S. during that period
policies with a view to stabilising balances, in a way which would these longer-term objectives.‘5 1
was about $17 billion.52 On the basis of these figures it may be assumed that the official dollar balances due to be funded will
This declaration is assumption that Great
the official sterling be consistent with
apparently based on the Britain should eventually
redeem the sterling balances, amounting on 30 September 1971 to $6.8 billion, by its own meanswhich would undoubtedly require a very long time. On the
same
balances,
which
assumption,
the redemption
of dollar
on the same date amounted
to $45.7
billion, would certainly need an even longer timealthough such redemption is bound to provoke serious international economic saw in paragraph 9.8 above. 13.8.
The
world,
however,
repercussions, cannot
wait
as we
until
the
U.S.A. and the U.K. are able to redeem these balances by their own means-let alone risk the disastrous repercussions of such redemption. Obviously, this problem
should
be tackled
simultaneously
with
the
inauguration of a new monetary system. If the system propounded here were to be adopted, a consistent solution would be to exchange these balances for IRUs to be issued by the I.M.F. against ‘undated’ bonds bearing interest at 3% per cent per annum signed and due by the U.K. and the U.S. respectively, to the I.M.F. This arrangement regarding the dollar balances could be considered as a sort of repayment to tbe United States for the generous reconstruction and development aid they have given to the whole since the end of the Second World War. With regard
to the sterling
balances,
world
their funding
against IRUs should also be considered as a gesture of goodwill in view of the fact that these balances are actually an aftermath of Britain’s Second World War expenditure, incurred for the Allied cause. 13.9. When this funding operation is to be implemented the question will arise whether all the official dollar and sterling balances outstanding on the D-day should be so funded.
deficit since 30 June 1970. Such a comparison shows months liabilities
in the
fifteen
be roughly $28 billion, less the ‘working balances’, plus the U.S.‘s net basic deficits from 30 September 1971
to the D-day.
On the other hand, the official sterling balances due to be funded will be about $7 billion, less ‘working balances’. 13 .lO. If the scheme of IRUs as described above is to be adopted provision should also be made for the gradual replacement of the present-day SDRs by IRUs. This should meet with no difficulty as the I.M.F. Articles (Schedule I) lay down the procedure to be followed in the event of a liquidation of the Special Drawing Account: eventual balances shall be discharged ‘in ten half-yearly installments or in such longer period as the Fund may decide is needed in currency convertible in fact’-we would add-into IRUs. 13.11.
Eventually,
the system
will have two main reserve besides the I.M.F. facilities.
put forward
herewith
media, gold and IRUs, Of these, gold, being a
commodity with ever increasing comparative scarcity, will tend to be officially undervalued and to flow out of the monetary system into the private market for industrial, artistic and hoarding purposes. International Reserve Units will be the primary reserve medium to be quantities commensurate
continually with the
international 13.12. Of
central
community. course, thg
increasing needs of
banks’
in the
monetary
reserves will always contain certain amounts of the main national currencies, as working balances; these, however, will not create any problem, provided that: (a) they are freely convertible into IR Us; and (b) measures will be adopted for the control of the movement of ‘hot money’ which should not be allowed to derange the new monetary system. At long last, the world should heed the warning
First, the dollars and pounds sterling needed by their official holders as ‘working balances’ should obviously be excluded from the funding operation.
given by Keynes
Second, the speculative short-term capital that has swollen the official dollar holdings, especially since 30 June 1970, should presumably also be excluded. The funding of this volatile capital does not appear to be justified, especially since it is likely under favourable conditions to flow back to the U.S.; but even if by the D-day it does not, an arrangement other than its exchange for IRUs should be made for its withdrawal from the international reserve system.
still fresh in his mind:
62
that
up to 30 September 1971 U.S. official increased by $26.2 billion, whereas its basic
Clearing havoc
Union’
caused
in his ‘Proposals twenty-nine
by the
‘hot
for an International
years
money’
ago,
when
the
in the
1930s
was
51. Qwration from the official declaration by Mr. G. Rippon in Luxembourg (Financial Timrs, 24 January 1972, p. 6.). 52. U.S. liabiliks: 30 June 1970 - $t9.5 billion; 30 f~inancial September 1971 - $45.7 billion (Intemational Statistics. January 1972). ‘Balance on current account and long-term capital account’ from 30 June 1970 to September 19il - $8.8 billion (U.S. Survey of Current Business, Jamdary 1972, S-3). World
Development
‘There is no country which can, in future, safely allow the flight of funds for political reasons or to wade domestic taxation [we should now add, or for speculative purposes] . . . Equally, there is no country that can safely receive fugitive funds, which constitute an unwanted import of capital, yet cannot safely be used for fiied investment. ‘For these reasons it is widely held that cotztml of cqital movements, both inward and outward, should be a permanent feature of the post-war system. ‘53
14.
ODA will not change much in the next few years, though slow upward movement is possible’56 14.4.
STRATEGY
OF THE U.N. DEVELOPMENT
AND RESERVE
Nobody
denies
CRJJATJON-TWO
industrial
the
countries
(LDCs).
to narrow
countries Such
for to
the
the gap between
aid
less developed in order
the rich and poor nations,
which is one of the most serious predicaments of mankind today. The U.N. General Assembly, by a unanimous vote on 24 October 1970, adopted the ‘International Development Strategy for the Second U.N. Develop ment Decade’ beginning on 1 January 1971. In this International Strategy all countries have accepted the objective that ‘each economically advanced country should
endeavour
veloping minimum
to
provide.
. . annually
countries financial resource net amount of 1 per cent
do
to
de
by 1972 but in any assis-
by the sixteen Development (D.A.C.) countries amounted
to only 0.34 per cent of their aggregate GNP ($2,000 billion), i.e., half-way to the target, with the following breakdown: 55
Official bilateral loans Less- Amortization of outstanding
% of GNP
2.819 433
loans
Net official bilateral loans Official bilateral grants and grant-like flows Official contributions to multilateral institutions Total ODA
is so, then
the
5 billion
2,386 3.298 1.124
0.12 0.16 0.06
6,808 -_
Fz
1 Nos. 3 & 4
loans
be
$14
% of GNP
9.6 3.3 1.1 14.0 -
Total ODA
0.48 0.16 0.06 z -
14.6. It would appear, therefore, that, by a strange coincidence, the annual amount of additional official loans from the D.A.C. countries
is needed
reserve
to reach
is equal creation
to
the target
the
which
we
target
development assistance-appear and can both be resolved
volume
estimated
by
running
of the IRU scheme
problems creation
in and
the industrial by the 1.M.F.
of the U.N. Interand the efficient
proposed
H.M.S.O., London,
of annual
in paragraph
to be complementary one and the same
catalyst-$7 billion funded loans from countries to the LDCs to be discounted against the issue of IRUs. 14.7. For the implementation national Development Strategy
to the LDCs
set by the V.N.
12.8 above, at U.S. $ 7 billion.57 the two world In other words, question-the urgent needs for reserve
p. 9, and the Development
Strategy. ‘The outlook’, it writes, ‘for substantial increases in official development assistance in the immediate future or in the percentage of GNP transferred as official development assistance is anything but favourable. Given the fact that the 1970 level was slightly less than one-half of 0.7 per cent of GNP . . . there is no evidence just at present of the reversal of priorities required in several major countries to bring about the increases in disbursements that would be needed to Vol.
solves
10.0 0.4
Net official bilateral loans Official bilatcrai grants and grant-like flows Official contributions to multilateral institutions
of reaching
U.N.
which
the said U.N. Development
Official bilateral Loans Less: Amoniution of outstanding
53. Cmd. 6437,
set in the
and
of 0.7 per cent of GNP for ODA
14.3. The Development Assistance 1971 Review of the O.E.C.D. is very pessimistic about the prospects the targets
IRU system,
way to achieve
Strategy
S million
financial-budgetary
issued-so that the total of ODA would billion, with the following breakdown :
bilateral
tance (ODA) given Assistance Committee
for
transfers of a of its GNP at
development
their
were to have been reached in 1970, another $7.2 billion official bilateral loans should have been advanced, in addition to the $2.8 billion already
that
case not later than 1975. 54 14.2. During 1970, the official
mainly
Strategy target. 14.5. If that target
targets
if possible,
so
practical
market prices’, of which 70 per cent should be in the form of grants and long-term loans from official sources and the balance from private sources-such to be reached,
why the
to increase
rather than creates such problems, should prove acceptable to the developed countries as the best
development
aid is indispensable
that the reasons
are reluctant
official development assistance to reach the abovementioned target is mainly political. I believe that, on the contrary, developed countries would, for political reasons, be willing to increase their aid, but they do
If that
PROBLEMS RESOLVABLE
the need
believed
countries
balance-of-payments-reasons.
BY ONE CATALYST 14.1.
It is widely
developed
not IMJ’JEMENTATJON
COMPLEMENTARY
by
meet the target by 1975. Thus, taken as a whole, the probability is that the percentage of GNP devoted to
here,
however,
April 1943, p. 16.
54. See the international Review,
O.E.C.D.,
55. D.A.C.
Review,
Development Strategy. U.N.. 1970. Assistance Committee 1971 December 1971, p. 47.
op. cit., pp. 34, 37n.
56. ibid., p. 50. 57. The coincidence is due to the fact that the estimated GNP of D.A.C. countries is 20 times the estimated value of global reserves ($2000:$100 billion) and that the shortfall of the target of ODA as a percentage of GNP was 20 times smaller than the estimated rate of target growth of reserves (0.35:7.0 per cent). 63
it will be necessary to set up an International Development Strategy Headquarters (I.D.S. H.Q.), which will plan and coordinate all bilateral and multilateral development assistance and advise the I.M.F. on the ‘eligibility’ of the bonds presented for discount against IRUs-as per paragraph 7.2 (a)-as well as on other relevant matters, such as interest remission or reduction At the same Co-ordinating
. in all LDCs
(as per paragraph time, Local
10.4), etc. Development
Agencies (L.D.C.A.s) should be set up receiving aid, which will co-ordinate aid on the spot and report to I.D.S.
development H.Q. Such co-ordination
both
on the global
and on the
local levels would be facilitated if each country would set up its own development
developed authority
like the American Agency for International ment (A.I.D.), the British Ministry of Development
Agency
for
Development Assistance. Both in the I.D.S. H.Q. and in the L.D.C.A.s,
the
developing
and
the
countries
representation. 14.8. On reporting
German
should
Federal
Develop Overseas
also have an effective
on the ‘eligibility’
of the bonds
to
be discounted, the L.D.C.A.s and I.D.S. H.Q. should consult with the respective creditor and debtor countries and should see to it that: (a) such bonds are related to currently advanced bona fide loans directly or indirectly promoting the development of developing countries; (b) all developing countries should get a fair share of the global development assistance both in the form of official grants and in the form of official loans;58 (c) such loans are additional to non-discounted development loans at concessional terms of a volume at least equal to the 1971-2 level, and that they are ’ not made at the expense of the creditor country’s usual official grants and grant-like flows and grants and contributions to multilateral institutions; (d) in case the demand for IRUs is greater
than
the target ceiling set by the I.M.F., all developed countries should be given a fair share of the new IRUs to be issued within such a target, on the basis of each one’s need for liquidity. In such a case, however, the IMF should consider the review of its target ceiling upwards, since the existence of demand in excess of the target, by countries that are ready to exchange goods and services for IRUs, is prima facie evidence that the said target
was set rather
10w.~~
their volume
would
tend
to reach the target accepted
by the developed countries themselves. (b) At the same time, there is a consensus world informed opinion that there should be annual though
creation its volume
of a fiduciary is a controversial is intended scheme
of an
reserve medium, issue. to facilitate the
(c) My developed countries in increasing their development assistance by financing such assistance with IRUs, up to the limit to be set by the I.M.F. for reserve creation. Suppose, for the sake of argument, that that limit is set at only $1 billion: then the increase of development assistance will be facilitated up to that amount only; yet, little facility is better than none and therefore the link will in any case increase rather than prejudice development assistance. (See also paragraph 14.8 (c).) (d) At the other extreme, suppose that the I.M.F. estimates that there is a need for an annual reserve creation of $10 billion, and sets the target ceiling at that figure. If such a need is real, it will certainly be felt by most developed countries which will experience the impact of inadequate international liquidity. Such being the case, the remedy will in the instance lie with the sufferers themselves, since reserve-creating authority is ex bypothesi ready discount their development loan bonds up to billion. If the developed countries, however, do not like exchanging say, $5 billion,
feel
resources for IRUs for more than, this means that the realistically right
and proper level of reserve
creation in that year is $5
billion rather than $10 billion, as estimated by the I.M.F. In the circumstances, reserve creation than $5 billion, of two things:
first the to $10
by another method, would
ex ante of more mean one
(i) If such higher liquidity were to be issued to the LDCs, this would mean that LDCs would be given internationallyaccepted purchasing power for more resources than the developed countries are ready to exchange. (ii) If, on the other hand, such higher liquidity were to be gifted to developed countries, this would mean that the latter would be granted international money that will either be kept by them sterile (as we saw in paragraph 6.7 above) or will be used in payment of a reverse flow of resources from the poor to the rich countries, which is economically, politically and morally unacceptable.
14.9. The link between the issue of IRUs and development finance, as envisaged here, is not likely to prejudice either development assistance or reserve creation, for the following reasons: (a) Practically all developed countries have already undertaken to give LDCs official development assistance up to 0.7 per cent of their GN‘P. Yet, mainly
The inference is that the link of the issue of IRUs to development finance, as proposed here, is not likely to impair the creation of a ‘realistically right and proper’ (in the sense of sub-paragraph (d) above) volume of reserves.
because of balance-of-payments and other difficulties, their assistance so far is about $7 billion short of that target. There is, therefore, a presumption that if the transfer of resources from developed to
58. The I.D.% H.Q. should lay down criteria for a fair distribution of development assistance through the IRU scheme, first among continents and regions and second among the individual LDCs.
less developed
59. See Section 16.
64
countries
were
facilitated
financially
World Development
14.10.
In both
IRU scheme, socialist ment
the
Development
it would
countries
Strategy
to participate
may become
15. CAUSAL
15.1.
It appears
that
the
the
Previous
the
Trade Balames
so that the Develop
really international.
THERAPY
SYMPTOMATIC
and
to invite
Strategy
be commendable
RATHER
New Trade Balances
A.
+
B.
+ 0.8
+
i.778
+ 2.578
C.
-
0.8
+ 1.722
+ 0.922
D.
-
1.6
+ 1.694
+ 0.094
0.0
+ 7.000
+ 7.000
Total
THAN
New Exports
1.6
+ 1.806
+ 3.406
TREATMENT
idea is gaining
ground
in
15.4. The above example leads to the conclusion that a ‘deficit country’ in a ‘zero-sum’ trading contest, can
I.M.F. forums that the world monetary problem can be solved by laying down and enforcing an international code of conduct that will aim at prompt and
be turned into a ‘surplus country’ without changing irs exchange parity, by the creation of new reserves
frequent
through
adjustments
that this imbalances.
will
do
of exchange away
with
rates, in the hope foreign
payments
Under this code of conduct ‘deficit countries’ will have to devalue and ‘surplus countries’ to upvalue their currencies promptly so that international competition may be conducted on a basis of ‘fair play’. It seems to me ‘that this line of approach may be likened to an attempt to treat the symptoms rather than cure the causes of the disease. 15.2. As I argued in Section 3, since international trade
is now
carried
on practically
as a zero-sum
game, some countries are bound to have balance-ofpayments deficits. The realignment of currencies is a kind of symptomatic treatment which may change the relative positions of the contestants but cannot do away with deficits. The causal therapy in this case would lie in turning the international trade contest from a zero-sum to a positive-sum one. The following simplified example will make my point clearer. 15.3. Suppose that the trading world is made up of four developed countries whose relative competitive strengths
are in the ratios
respectively.
If the trade
contest
is like a zero-sum
Imports
Trade Balances
A.
25.8
24.2
+
B.
25.4
24.6
+ 0.8
C. D.
24.6 24.2
25.4 25.8
-
100.0
100.0
Total
1.6 0.8 1.6 0.0
Now, suppose that the I.M.F. issues to the Third World SDRs amounting to 7 per cent of the above exports, on condition that they should be used for buying goods from these four developed countries. Other things being equal, the $7m new exports will be shared by the four exporters in proportion to each one’s competitive strength, with the result that all four countries will become surplus countries: Vol.
1 Nos. 3 & 4
and
international trading
trade,
contest
thus
into
transforming
one with
the
a positive
This kind of therapy is not only more fundamental effective but avoids the risk of competitive
currency devaluations to if the policy
which the world would be led of curing foreign payments
imbalances by ‘prompt and frequent exchange rates’ were to be adopted.
readjustment
of
Furthermore, the Iatter attempt is a negative rather than a constructive way of dealing with the dynamic urge of all countries and especially the developed countries to realize balance-ofpayments surpluses. Instead of suppressing that urge-which will most probably prove futile-the constructive way would be to take advantage of it and use the goods and services made thereby spare for the purposes of world development.
16. HOW TO ALLOCATE WHEN THEIR AGGREGATE
NEW IRUs DEMAND
EXCEEDS THEIR SUPPLY
of 258, 254, 246 and 242
game, the result will be that the first two countries will have trade surpluses and the last two, trade deficits, as follows (in million $):
Exports
zero-sum sum.
16.1. In paragraph 14.8 (d), we envisaged the where the demand for IRUs was higher than target ceiling set by the I.M.F.; in such a case, said, ‘all developed countries should be given a
case the we fair
share in the new IR Us to be issued within such target, on the basis of each one’s needs for liquidity’. Although we added that in such a situation there would be prima facie evidence that the target should be revised upwards, until that was done there still be a problem of estimating each country’s for liquidity ‘.
would ‘needs
16.2. A similar problem faced by the I.M.F., when it had to allocate the new issues of SDRs, was solved by the adoption of the respective quotas in the I.M.F. as the measure of each country’s ‘needs for !iquidity’. This solution, backs pointed
however, apart from its other drawout above, ignored the actual volume
o,f resewes each country held at the time of allocation, which should of course have been deducted from its ‘total requirements’ in order to find its actual ‘needs’. 16.3. Our attempt to estimate each country’s ‘total reserve requirement’ will be based on: 65
(a) the I.M.F. Staff’s findings mentioned in paragraph 12.1 above, to the effect that the ‘ideal trend’ of all countries in the world, except the U.S.A., for the years 1954-68, was an almost constant reserves-imports ratio of about 40per cent;
Bonds
(bj the findings in paragraphs 4.4 and tables l-5 that there is a close correlation between the reserves on the one band and the imports and GNP on the other of the 0. E. C. D. countries; (cj in the absence of a more
estimate
which
is approximately
the same one (6.6 per
cent) we found in table 3 for the O.E.C.D. countries in the years 1959-61 when their reserves-imports ratio was 43.3 per cent (table 1). 16.4. In order to exemplify our tentative method of allocating the new IRUs when their aggregate demand exceeds their supply, let us suppose that there are only four creditor countries A, B, C, D, offering to the I.M.F. eligible bonds for discount valued at $500m,
$400m,
$700m
and $400m,
respectively,
2,000
16.7. In case a country’s total ‘reserve requirement’ as calculated above is found to be smaller than its actual reserves that country will not be allocated any IRUs. 16.8. If, on the other hand, a country’s allocation is found to be greater than the amount of the eligible bonds offered by it, the excess will be reallocated to the remaining creditor their first allocations.
17.
R eserces 4
(a) the provoked
increase inflationary
B. c.
15 20
120 130
5 7
economies and if
of the
D.
14 61 -
110
6 22 -
of
6.5Per
(in $ million):
CCRf of
AChd
GNP
Meon
ReSCWPS
Sh0rtfd
of
Reserves
A.
J.800
6.500
5.650
4,000
1,650
B.
6,000
7.800
6.900
5,000
1.900
C.
8.000
8.450
8.225
7,000
1,225
5,600
24,400 -
-
7,150
29,900 -
-
6,375
27.150 -
-
6.000
22,000 -
in
could world pressures
countries
provoke
world
monetary in the
increasing
I believe proposed
their
infla-
reserves domestic reserves;
(bj the demand for goods and services created by the development loans financed by the issue of IRUs
Total ‘Reserve Reqritcmmt ImpOTtS
to
OF
such a link would lead to world inflation. that with the IRUs issued in the way hereby this danger is rather remote.
100
per cent
proportion
17.1. One of the arguments against linking the issue of deliberately created reserves to development is that
12
picture
in
.
WITH THE ISSUE OF IRIJs?
A.
460
countries
IS THERE A DANGER
INFLATION
GNP
the following
-
375
5,150
16.6. On the basis of the above figures I would suggest that a fair method of allocating the $1 billion of new IRUs among the candidates who demanded $2 billion IRIJs, would be to do so in proportion to each one’s ‘sbortjkll’ of reserves. Considering that the $1 billion IRUs represent a proportion of 19.4 per cent of the total shortfalls (%5,15Omj, each country’s allocation would then be 19.4 per cent of its own shortfall as follows (in $ million): 66
1,000
17.2. The issue of IRUs tion only if:
16.5. If we assume that each country’s ‘total requirement’ for reserves is the mean between 40 per cent of its imports and 6.5 per cent of its GNP we will have
-
500 400 700 400
Imports
Total
D.
369 238 73
C. D.
in a
year in which the I.M.F. target for reserve creation was only $l,OOOm. We will further suppose that the imports and GNP of these countries during the previous year and their current volume of reserves were as follows (in $ billion) :
Total
320
B.
of
the ‘ideal trend’ of the reserves-GNP ratio for the whole world, we will make use of the ratio of 6.5 per cent,
A.
Total accurate
Total of Eligible
‘Fair’
.4llocations
rose beyond the supply potential of the industrial countries. 17.3. The danger of domestic inflationary pressures being provoked by increased reserves, is minimized: (a) by limiting the global increment to a percentage commensurate with the expected growth in world trade and GNP, as has already been proposed here; and the increased reserves-a (bj by neutralizing technique
sucessfully
authorities. Such successful
practised neutralization
by the monetary authorities ing 1970 and 1971 the monetary reserves increased
by several
monetary
was recently
done
of West Germany. DurDeutsche Bundesbank’s by 86 per cent and 20
per cent respectively (from DM 27,793m at end-1969 to DM 51,830m at end-1970, and to DM 62,219m at end-1971); yet, the German domestic economy was so well insulated from such a flood of external assets that the money stock (Ml) increased by only 9 and 12 per cent respectively (from DM 99,429m at end1969 to DM 108,219m at end-1970, and to DM 121,522m end-1971j.60 60. .Monthiy Rrport 1972. pp. 4. 74.
of‘ the Deutschr
Bundesbank,
February
World Development
17.4.
The risk of world
excessive
demand
inflation
for goods
being
provoked
by the
than 2 million eliminated’.65
defense-orientated
through
17.6.
The preceding
paragraphs
initiative
for
point
that
and services
issue of IRLJs is rather remote because: (a) in my scheme of IRUs, the
putting resources at the disposal of LDCs will come from the side of the suppliers of such resources, who will, presumably, see to it that the bilateral loans issued by them will be within their own supply potential; and (b) the industrial countries at present have such a large unutilized, underutilized and misutilized productive capacity, especially in the capital and durable consumer goods industries, that the supply of additional goods and services equal to only 0.35 per cent of their GNP is very far from provoking excessdemand inflation. 17.5. The following
facts
and
figures
confirm
argument of the preceeding sub-paragraph: (a) The indices of capital utilization facturing industries in the main industrial during the fourth
quarter
in manucountries
of 1970 were as follows:61
U.S.A. U.K. Germany France Belgium
83 per cent 95 94 96 94 95 87
Netherlands Ital) Unemployment
the
in these
” ” ” ” ” ”
prove,
were
I believe,
my
in the way proposed,
is
not likely to provoke inflation in the developed countries. It may, however, be retorted: How about the inflation already prevailing in nearly all developed countries? Will it not be aggravated by the increase of exports to LDCs? 17.7. My reply is that the prevailing inj?ation is not a ‘demand inflation’, i.e., injlation due to excess effective demand over the supply potential of the economies
concerned,
Since,
as indicated
economies potential,
to which above,
I was referring.
all developed
countries’
are actually working below their ‘demand inflation’ is by definition
supply ruled
out. 17.8. Presumably, the prevailing inflation wage-cost-price vicious spiral, the prime
is due to a mover of
which, I venture to submit, is the perennial Sisypbean attempt by the workers and employees in all economies to increase their secular!y almost constant share in the real GNP of their countries. Apparently, this attempt has recently been intensified due to ‘rising expectations’ among all peoples, evoked by the vast development of communications and the
“ ” ” “ ‘I ”
countries
the issue of IRUs,
jobs
amazing achievements recent years. has increased
of science
and technology,
in
17.9. In these circumstances, the developed countries are facing the dilemma: Either to follow the negative
since 1970, which means that their capacity utilization is now lower than the above. (b) The steel industry in all countries is now working well below capacity. For instance, Japanese crude steel production in 1971 was 26 per cent below capacity (85 out of 115 million tons)62 and the operating rate of estimated capacity of American
ment and economic stagnation curb the wage demands and break the wage-cost-price vicious spiral; or to follow up the welfare policy of giving priority
steel industry cent.(j3
structive ways wage-cost-price
(c) elasticity countries planned durables (d) period
It
in September
is a well-known
1972 was only fact
that
the
70 per income-
of demand for durable goods in developed is falling in favour of services, and that obsolescence and reduced durability of are extensively It is an open
used to boost secret
that
demand.
during
the post-war
industrial production in the developed countries has been increasingly boosted by military expenditure, by the recurrent obsolescence of weapons
and
and costlier programme.
their
continual
replacement
by newer
versions, as well as by the space-research The total military expenditures by the
developed countries during 1970 was estimated to be $177 billion, i.e., about 9 per cent of their GNP.64 realization of hoped-for world dis(e) The armament would be facilitated if the further spare productive capacity to be thereby created could be employed for some useful alternative purpose, such as the development of LDCs. Otherwise, there will be the danger of increased unemployment, as happened in the U.S. following a comparatively small cut in their military expenditures in fiscal year 1971, when, as President Nixon stated on 24 October 1971, ‘more Vol.
1 Nos. 3 & 4
and socially
unacceptable
to full employment to
devise
other
policy
of letting
and economic more
socially
and means inflation.
unemploy-
growth
and to try
acceptable
and con-
of solving
the problem
of
17.10. It is in the context of the second alternative, just mentioned, that I believe that the IRUs, issued in the way proposed, the two monetary
will not
only
be the catalyst
for
complementary major problems-the and the development-facing mankind
today, but will also be instrumental in procuring to the industralized countries what they now zqently need: export-led growth; and in averting the real danger facing mankind today and in the coming years: world-wide stagnation. 61. Wharton indices quoted in the I.M.F. Annual Report, 1971, p. 58. 62.
See report in the Financial Times, 19 January 1972, p. 9.
63.
See Wall Street Journal,
10 October 1972, p. 10.
64. Estimated by the U.S. Arms Control and Disarmament Agency in their fifth report, quoted in the Survey of International Developmen& May 1971. 65. Radio Address by President Nixon on Veterans’ Day. 24 October 1971 (U.S. Information Service). According to the Monthly ‘Economic Letter of the First National City Bank, January 1972, ‘U.S. Defense spending declined to $76 billion in fiscal year 1971, nearly $3 billion below fiscal year 1969, the peak of Vietnam spending, but is likely to flatzen out in the 1972 fiscal year’. 67
Table 1. Calculation of the Coefficient of Correlation: end-1958~6Ulmports 1959-61 for Average Reserves O.E.C. D. Countries (excluding the U.S.A., the U.K.. and Switzerland) (U.S. $ billion) x Awerage reserves end-1958-61 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 1s. 16. 17. 18. 19.
1.35 3.88 1.76 6.02 9.85 4.44 4.52 1.47 2.75 6.20 4.63 1.02 0.66 0.09 0.65 0.56 0.87 0.48 0.81
22.52
& = 52.01
Japan
Finland Greece lceland Ireland Portugal Spain Turkey Yugoslavia SC= Qy
XxX = 66.81
= 266.85
(19 x 126.55) r
= ~“((19
I
=
l’ore.
x 66.81)
- (22.52
- (22.52
x 22.52))
&y
1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 1s. 16. 17. 18. 19.
rario = 43 3%
gable 2. Calculafion of tbe Coefficient of Cowelation: end- 196 7- 70Hmports 1968- 70 for Average Resewes O.E. C.D. Countries (excluding the U.S.A., the U.K., and Switzerland) (U.S. $ billion)
1.57 2.51 0.48 5.00 9.7 1 5.30 2.71 0.7 3 0.78 3.39 3.36 0.34 0.31 0.04 0.60 1.38 1.34 0.23 0.15
Austria Belgium/Lux. Denmark France Germany Italy Netherlands Norway Sweden Canada
Japan Finland Greece Iceland Ireland Portugal Spain Turkey Yugoslavia
XX = 39.93 syy =x’O.W, r = \/(I19 x 191.?9)
Finland Greece Iceland Ireland Ponugal Spain Turkey Y tigoslavia
&,’
=
r
= 0.853
,,‘((19
x 66.81)
- (22.52
s,
=
-i 14140.23
119 x 887.97)
r
- (22.52
x 22.52))
339.1
&y
= 887.97
x 339.10)
x ((19 x 14140.23)
Rcxtves:GNP
- (339.1
x 339 I))
rano = 6.6%
!” 93 x 39.93))
= 1822.60 -
Table 4. Calculation of the Coefficient of Correlation: Reserves end-l 965-68/GNP 1966-68 for Average 0. E.C. D. Countries (excluding the V.S..4., the U.K.. and Swikerhnd) (U.S. $ billion)
Y .4verage imports 1968-70
x
Average reserves end-l 967-70
X.%X= 191.99
Japan
6.2 12.0 6.0 61.4 70.8 35.5 11.3 4.6 13.1 36.9 44.1 4.9 3.6 0.3 1.9 2.5 10.4 5.3 8.3
Note. See paragraphs 4.4 and 4.5
See paragraphs 4.4 and 4.5
1. 2. 3. -h. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19.
0.74 1.55 0.28 2.11 6.22 3.09 1.70 0.29 0.57 2.09 1.53 0.32 0.23 0.02 0.33 0.77 0.43 0.21 0.04
Austria Belgium/Lux. Denmark France Germany Italy Netherlands Norway Sweden Canada
XXX = 66.81
x 52.01))
‘4 uerage GMP 1959-61
1
XX= 22.52
= 126.55
- (52.01
Y
Average resentes end- 1958-6
x 52.01)
x ((19 x 266.85)
Racrves:tmports
O.Yl9
x
Y Average imports 1959_~61
0.74 1.55 0.28 2.11 6.22 3.09 1.70 0.29 0.57 2.09 1.53 0.32 0.23 0.02 0.33 0.77 0.43 0.21 0.04
Austria Belgium/Lux. Denmark France Germany Italy Netherlands Norway Sweden Canada
Table 3. Calculation of the Coefficient of Correlation: Reserves end-1958-61/GNP 1959-61 for Average O.E.C.D. Countries (excluding the U.S.A., the U.K., and Switzerland) (U.S. $ billion)
2.96 9.89 3.82 16.85 24.89 12.57 11.22 3.12 6.02 13.76 15.65 2.09 1.65 0.14 1.41 1.35 4.14 0.8 1 2.27 &
= 134.61 &y
1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19.
J
1.41 2.37 0.54 6.07 8.39 5.13 2.49 0.60 0.91 2.88 2.30 0.30 0.28 0.05 0.47 1.15 1.23 0.13 0.11
Austria Beigium/Lux. Denmark France Germany Italy Netherlands Norway Sweden Canada Japan Finland Greece Iceland Ireland Portugal Spain Turkey Yugoslavia &
= 570.48
(19 x 2756.22) - (134.61
x 134.61))
I’
,,‘(r19
x 165.68)
- (36.81
x 36.81))
r = 0.852
10.8 20.3 11.9 116.9 124.8 69.5 23.0 8.4 24.1 57.9 120.5 8.4 7.0 0.6 3.0 4.6 25.6 10.6 9.5
= 36.81
qy
z-ix = 165.68
139.93 x 134.61) x ((19 x 1822.60)
Y Average G.VP 1966-68
x
Average re*ewes end-l 965-68
&
= 54.802.32 - (36.8i
J
x 657.4)
x ((19 x 54802.32)
Rcrerves.GNP
= 657.4 _ ~;v_.Y= 2756.22
- (657.4
x 657.4))
rau” = 5.0%
“ore. See paragraphs 4.4 and 4.5
68
World
Development
Table 5. Calculation ofthe Coefficient of Comlation between thelncrements of the Average Reserves from end-195841 to end-1967-70 and the growth of Average Imports from 1959-61 to 1968- 70 for 0. E. C. D. Countries (excluding the U.S.A., the L’.K., and Switzerland) (U.S. $ billion) Y Imports increments
x
Reserves increments 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19.
Austria. BelgiumlLux.
0.83 0.96
1.61 6.01
Denmark France Germany Italy Netherlands Norway Sweden Canada
0.20 2.89 3.49 2.21 1.01 0.44 0.21 1.30 1.83 0.02 0.08 0.02 0.27 0.61 0.91 0.02 0.11
2.06 10.83 15.04 8.13 6.70 1.65 3.27 7.56 11.02 1.07 0.99 0.05 0.76 0.79 3.27 0.33 1.46
Japan Finland Greece Iceland Ireland Portugal Spain Turkey Yugoslavia xv=
&x
zyv
= 34.66
(19 x 151.38) ’
= ,&19
r
=
x 34.66)
x li.41))
- (17.41
x 82.60)
x ((19
x 705.71)
4.4 to 4.6
1 Nos. 3 & 4
Publishers M.S.I.
at Headington Hill Hall, Oxford, or from Fairview Park, Elmsford, New York,
Inc.,
N.Y. 10523. In order to avoid administrative costs, cash must accompany the order plus postage and handling charge of 25c.”
= 82.60
&J,
= 705.71
Growth of
0.939
Note. See paragraphs
Vol.
- (17.41
&
17.41
“This article has been reprinted as a monograph with an extensive preface by Paul Streeten and is available separately, price US $1.00 from the
- (82.60
= 151.38
x 82.60))
raerva~imports ratio = 21.1%
@ Chris. Economides,
1973
69
A Welcome to World Development A journal such as World Development ought to find a useful niche among the serious periodicals of our times. The multidisciplinary approach is greatly needed in a global community of every increasing complexity. There is need, too, to point out the disparities between the developed and the undeveloped and the striking failure of the communist countries to provide a better life for their peoples. Attention to international dialogues and detentes should not be allowed to obscure the truth about the authoritarians and their contributions to economic backwardness and international conflict. The prospectus you have set forth is one of liberalism. Let it be the true liberalism of honesty and letting the facts fall where they may without regard to preconceived prejudices. We expect World Development to be a journal of constructive advance, not one of retrogression into appeasement. C. K. Yen,
Vice-President, The Republic of China.
Thank you for affording me, on behalf of the Government of Dominica, an opportunity to offer warm congratulations on the occasion of the launching of your new multidisciplinary international journal-WORLD DEVELOPMENT-a venture, which, I have no doubt, will soon rank among the world’s prestigious, chaperoned as it is by such distinguished academics and practitioners from all major regions of the world, including the socialist countries. The Government of Dominica subscribe to the ideal to which the journal is committed, namely, the promotion and study of world development and will support all legitimate and reasonable efforts in that direction; particularly the attack on the world’s chief evils of malnutrition, disease, illiteracy, slums, unemployment and inequality. Indeed, I am of the firm conviction that reconciliation of the factors which now serve to maintain racial injustice will ensure the earlier resolutions of these evils. WORLD DEVELOPMENT should consistently and persistently bare to the world that we are all members of an interdependent community and every effort should be made to narrow the gap ” between rich and poor nations. , The Government and People of Dominica commend the initiative of the world’s leading economists and scientists in this new and bold exercise and express the sincere wish that WORLD DEVELOPMENT succeeds in securing international cooperation through the maintenance of international diaglogue against the existing barriers of conflicting disciplines and professions. The Hon. E. 0. LeBlanc, Cabinet Secretariat, Government Headquarters, Roseau, Dominica.
I have great pleasure in sending this brief message expressing my appreciation of the efforts made by this journal to bring home to its readers and through them the general mass of people outside the growing discrepancy between the developing and the developed countries. I do wish the journal
every success in this crusade. Dr. N. M. Perera, Minister of Finance. Sri Lanka.
70
World Development