Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jedc
Estimating contract indexation in a Financial Accelerator Model$ Charles T. Carlstrom a, Timothy S. Fuerst b,c,n, Alberto Ortiz d,e, Matthias Paustian f a
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Cleveland, OH 44101, USA Department of Economics, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556, USA Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, 419-320-300, USA d Centro de Estudios Monetarios Latinoamericanos, Mexico e EGADE Business School, Tecnologico de Monterrey, Mexico f Division of Research and Statistics, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC 20551, USA b c
a r t i c l e in f o
abstract
Article history: Received 6 June 2013 Received in revised form 31 March 2014 Accepted 13 June 2014 Available online 30 June 2014
This paper addresses the positive implications of indexing risky debt to observable aggregate conditions. These issues are pursued within the context of the celebrated financial accelerator model of Bernanke et al. (1999). The principal conclusions include: (1) the estimated level of indexation is significant, (2) the business cycle properties of the model are significantly affected by this degree of indexation, (3) the importance of investment shocks in the business cycle depends upon the estimated level of indexation, and (4) although the data prefers the financial model with indexation over the frictionless model, they have remarkably similar business cycle properties for non-financial exogenous shocks. Published by Elsevier B.V.
JEL Classification: E32 E44 Key words: Agency costs Financial accelerator Business cycles
1. Introduction The fundamental function of credit markets is to channel funds from savers to entrepreneurs who have some valuable capital investment project. These efforts are hindered by agency costs arising from asymmetric information. A standard result in a subset of this literature, the costly state verification (CSV) framework, is that risky debt is the optimal contract between risk-neutral lenders and entrepreneurs. The modifier risky simply means that there is a non-zero chance of default. In the CSV model external parties can observe the realization of the entrepreneur's idiosyncratic production technology only by expending a monitoring cost. Townsend (1979) demonstrates that risky debt is optimal in this environment because it
☆ The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors, and not necessarily those of the Bank of England, Centro de Estudios Monetarios Latinoamericanos, the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or its staff. We have received helpful comments from two anonymous referees. n Corresponding author at: Department of Economics, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556, USA. Tel.: þ 1 574 631 4853; fax: þ 1 574 631 4783. E-mail addresses:
[email protected] (C.T. Carlstrom),
[email protected] (T.S. Fuerst),
[email protected] (A. Ortiz),
[email protected] (M. Paustian).
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2014.06.009 0165-1889/Published by Elsevier B.V.
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
131
minimizes the need for verification of project outcomes. This verification is costly but necessary to align the incentives of the firm with the bank. Aggregate conditions will also affect the ability of the borrower to repay the loan. But since aggregate variables are observed by both parties, it may be advantageous to have the loan contract indexed to the behavior of aggregate variables. Therefore, even when loan contracts cannot be designed based on private information, we can exploit common information to make these financial contracts more state-contingent. That is, why should the loan contract call for costly monitoring when the event that leads to a poor return is observable by all parties? Carlstrom et al. (2013),1 hereafter CFP, examine questions of this type within the financial accelerator of Bernanke et al. (1999), hereafter BGG. CFP demonstrate that the privately optimal contract in the BGG model includes indexation to: (i) the aggregate return to capital (which we will call Rkindexation), (ii) the household's marginal utility of wealth, and, (iii) the entrepreneur's valuation of internal funds. CFP also demonstrate that the latter two forms of indexation quantitatively largely cancel out, so our focus will be on Rk-indexation. In this paper we thus explore the business cycle implications of indexing the BGG loan contract to the aggregate return to capital. There are at least two reasons why this is an interesting exercise. First, as noted above, CFP demonstrate that the privately optimal contract in the BGG framework includes indexation of this very type. Second, indexation of this type is not so far removed from some financial contracts we do observe. Since we are assuming that the CSV framework proxies for agency cost effects in the entire US financial system, it seems reasonable to include some form of indexation to mimic the myriad ex post returns on external financing. For example, in contrast to the model assumption where entrepreneurs get zero in the event of bankruptcy, this is clearly not the implication of Chapter 11 bankruptcy. In any event, we use familiar Bayesian methods to estimate the degree of contract indexation to the return to capital. To avoid misspecification problems in the estimation we need a complete model of the business cycle. We use the recent contribution of Justiniano et al. (2011), hereafter JPT, as our benchmark. A novelty of the JPT model is that it includes two shocks to the capital accumulation technology. The first shock is a non-stationary shock to the relative cost of producing investment goods, the “investment specific technology shock” (IST). The second is a stationary shock to the transformation of investment goods into installed capital, the “marginal efficiency of investment shock” (MEI). For business cycle variability, JPT find that the IST shocks are irrelevant, while the MEI shocks account for a substantial portion of business cycle fluctuations. Our principal results include the following. First, the estimated level of Rk-indexation significantly exceeds unity, much higher than the assumed BGG indexation of approximately zero. A model with Rk-indexation fits the data significantly better when compared to BGG. This is because the BGG model's prediction for the risk premium in the wake of a MEI shock is counterfactual. A MEI shock lowers the price of capital and thus leads to a sharp decline in entrepreneurial net worth in the BGG model. But under Rk-indexation, the required repayment falls also so that net worth moves by significantly less. Second, with Rk-indexation, this financial model and JPT have remarkably similar business cycle properties for nonfinancial exogenous shocks. For example, for the case of MEI shocks, the estimated level of indexation leads to net worth movements in the financial model that accommodate real behavior quite similar to the response of JPT to an MEI shock. We also nest financial shocks into the JPT model by treating fluctuations in the financial variables as serially correlated measurement error. This model horserace results in the Rk-indexation model dominating BGG, which in turn significantly dominates JPT. The financial models are improvements over JPT in two ways. The financial models make predictions for the risk premium on which JPT is silent, and the financial models introduce other exogenous shocks, e.g., shocks to net worth or idiosyncratic variance, that are irrelevant in JPT. Third, we find that whether financial shocks or MEI shocks are more important drivers of the business cycle depends upon the level of indexation. Under BGG, financial shocks account for a significant part of the variance of investment spending. But under the estimated level of Rk-indexation, financial shocks become much less important and the MEI shocks are again of paramount importance. Two prominent papers closely related to the current work are Christiano et al. (2014), and DeGraeve (2008). They each use Bayesian methods to estimate versions of the BGG framework in medium-scale macro models. Both papers conclude that the model with financial frictions provides a better fit to the data when compared to its frictionless counterpart. The chief novelty of the current paper is to introduce contract indexation into the BGG framework, and demonstrate that it is empirically relevant, altering the business cycle properties of the model. Neither of the previous papers considered indexation of this type. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents a simple example that illustrates the importance of contract indexation to the financial accelerator. Section 3 develops the DSGE model. Section 4 presents the estimation results, while Section 5 provides some sensitivity analysis. Section 6 concludes.
2. Why does indexation matter? A simple example This section presents a simple intuitive example that demonstrates the importance of indexation in determining the size of the financial accelerator. Consider a world with agency costs in which the portion of net worth owned by entrepreneurs 1
This is the logic behind Shiller and Weiss's (1999) suggestion of indexing home mortgages to movements in aggregate house prices.
132
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
Fig. 1. The multiplier as a function of indexation.
ðnwt Þ has a positive effect on the value of capital (qt ): qt ¼ pnwt þ ϵdt
ð1Þ
where the expression is in log deviations and ϵdt is an exogenous shock to capital prices, e.g., a shock to MEI in the general equilibrium model below. Eq. (1) is a manifestation of agency costs in that the distribution of net worth across lenders and borrowers affects asset prices. The idea is that higher net worth in the hands of entrepreneurs makes it easier for them to access a loan with which to buy capital, so that higher levels of net worth act like a demand channel on asset prices. In the general equilibrium model below, the value of p is a function of the agency cost and (installed) capital adjustment cost parameters. The entrepreneur accumulates net worth to mitigate the agency problems involved in direct lending. The agency problem arises from a CSV problem in the entrepreneur's production technology. The entrepreneur takes one unit of input and creates ωt units of capital, where the unit-mean random variable ωt is privately observed by the entrepreneur but can be verified by the lender only by paying a cost. This CSV problem makes equity finance problematic, so that the optimal contract is given by a risky debt contract with a promised repayment of r pt . The repayment r pt cannot be indexed to ωt because it is privately observed. But it can be indexed to the aggregate price of capital: r pt ¼ χ qt :
ð2Þ
This form of indexation is similar to indexing to the rate of return on capital in the general equilibrium model developed below. Entrepreneurial net worth accumulates with the profit flow from the investment project, but decays via consumption of entrepreneurs (which is a constant fraction of net worth). Log-linearized this evolution is given by: nwt ¼ κ ðqt r pt Þ þ nwt 1 þ r pt þ ϵnt
ð3Þ
where κ 4 1 denotes leverage (the ratio of project size to net worth) and ϵnt is an exogenous shock to net worth. Using the indexation assumption (2), we can express (3) as nwt ¼ qt ½κ χ ðκ 1Þ þ nwt 1 þ ϵnt
ð4Þ
Note that since κ 41, the slope of the net worth equation is decreasing in the level of indexation. Eqs. (1) and (4) are a simultaneous system in net worth and the price of capital. We can solve for the two endogenous variables as a function of the pre-determined and exogenous variables: nwt ¼
qt ¼
nwt 1 þ ϵnt þ ϵdt ½κ χ ðκ 1Þ f1 p½κ χ ðκ 1Þg
pðnwt 1 þ ϵnt Þ þ ϵdt f1 p½κ χ ðκ 1Þg
ð5Þ
ð6Þ
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
χ=0
χ=1
qt
133
nwt Fig. 2. A shock to asset demand. (Asset price is blue line. Net worth evolution is red line.) Demand shock shifts up asset price. The new equilibrium in (n,q) space depends upon the level of indexation. Lower levels of indexation amplify these effects. (For interpretation of the references to color in this figure legend, the reader is referred to the web version of this article.)
The inverse of the denominator in (5) and (6) is the familiar “multiplier” arising from two endogenous variables with positive feedback. This then implies that exogenous shocks are “multiplied” or “financially accelerated”, and that the degree of this multiplication depends upon the level of indexation. The effect of indexation on the financial multiplier is highly nonlinear. Fig. 1 plots the multiplier for κ ¼2, and p¼0.45, both of these values roughly correspond to the general equilibrium analysis below. Note that moving from χ ¼0 to χ ¼1, has an enormous effect on the multiplier. But there are sharp diminishing returns so the multiplier is little changed as we move from χ ¼1 to χ ¼2. This suggests, and we confirm below, that the data can distinguish χ ¼0 from, say, χ ¼1, but that indexation values in excess of unity will have similar business cycle characteristics and thus be difficult to identify. Consider three special cases of indexation: χ ¼ 0, χ ¼ 1, and χ ¼ κ =ðκ 1Þ The first is the implicit assumption in BGG; the second implies complete indexation; the third eliminates the financial accelerator altogether. In these cases, net worth and asset prices are given by: Indexation
Net worth
Capital price
Multiplier (p¼ 0.45,
χ ¼0
nwt 1 þ ϵnt þ κϵdt 1 pκ
pðnwt 1 þ ϵnt Þ þ ϵdt 1 pκ
10
χ ¼1 χ ¼ κ=ðκ 1Þ
nwt 1 þ ϵnt þ ϵdt 1p nwt 1 þ nt
pðnwt 1 þ ϵnt Þ þ ϵdt 1p pðnwt 1 þ nt Þ þ dt
ϵ
ϵ
ϵ
κ ¼2)
1.82 1
For both χ ¼ 0 and χ ¼ 1, exogenous shocks to asset prices and net worth have multiple effects on the equilibrium levels of net worth and capital prices. Since κ 4 1, this effect is much larger under BGG's assumption of no indexation ð1=ð1 pκ Þ b 1=ð1 pÞÞ. Further, under the BGG assumption, exogenous shocks to asset prices (ϵdt ) have an added effect as they are weighted by leverage. But for all levels of indexation, there are always agency cost effects in that the price of capital is affected by the level of entrepreneurial net worth. The financial multiplier effects are traced out in Fig. 2: an exogenous shock to asset prices has a much larger effect on both net worth and asset prices in the BGG framework. Finally, since κ 2 the financial accelerator largely disappears when χ ¼ 2: Before proceeding, it is helpful to emphasize the two parameters that are crucial in our simple example as they will be manifested below in the richer general equilibrium environment. Our reduced form parameter p in Eq. (1) is the agency cost parameter. In a Modigliani-Miller world we would have p ¼0, as the distribution of net worth would have no effect on asset prices or real activity. Second, the indexation parameter χ determines the size of the financial accelerator, i.e., how do unexpected movements in asset prices feed in to net worth? These are two related but logically distinct ideas. That is, one can imagine a world with agency costs (p 40), but with very modest accelerator effects (χ ¼ κ =ðκ 1Þ:). To anticipate our empirical results, this is the parameter set that wins the model horse race. That is, the data is consistent with an agency cost model but with trivial accelerator effects. In such an environment, financial shocks (e.g., shocks to net worth) will affect real activity, but other real shocks (e.g., MEI shocks) will not be accelerated. 3. The model The benchmark model follows the JPT framework closely. The model of agency costs comes from BGG with the addition of exogenous contract indexation. The BGG loan contract is between lenders and entrepreneurs, so we focus on these two agents first before turning to the familiar framework of JPT. 3.1. Lenders The representative lender accepts deposits from households (promising a sure real return Rdt ) and provides loans to the continuum of entrepreneurs. These loans are intertemporal, with the loans made at the end of time t being paid back in time
134
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
t þ1. The realized gross real return on these loans is denoted by RLt þ 1 . Each individual loan is subject to idiosyncratic and aggregate risk, but since the lender holds an entire portfolio of loans, only the aggregate risk remains. The lender has no other source of funds, so the level of loans will equal the level of deposits. Hence, real dividends are given by Divt þ 1 ¼ ðRLt þ 1 Dt Rdt Dt Þ. The intermediary seeks to maximize its equity value which is given by:
β j Λt þ j Divt þ j Λt j¼1 1
Q Lt ¼ Et ∑
ð7Þ
where Λt is the marginal utility of real income for the representative household that owns the lender. The FOC of the lender's problem is: i Λt þ 1 h L Et Rt þ 1 Rdt ¼ 0
Λt
ð8Þ
The first-order condition shows that in expectation, the lender makes zero profits, but ex-post profits and losses can occur.2 We assume that losses are covered by households as negative dividends. This is similar to the standard assumption in the Dynamic New Keynesian (DNK) model, e.g., Woodford (2003). That is, the sticky price firms are owned by the household and pay out profits to the household. These profits are typically always positive (for small shocks) because of the steady state mark-up over marginal cost. Similarly, one could introduce a steady-state wedge (e.g., monopolistic competition among lenders) in the lender's problem so that dividends are always positive. But this assumption would have no effect on the model's dynamics so we dispense from it for simplicity.3 3.2. Entrepreneurs and the loan contract There are a continuum of entrepreneurs, but as in BGG there is sufficient linearity in preferences and technology such that we can abstract to a representative entrepreneur. Entrepreneurs are the sole accumulators of physical capital. At the beginning of period t, the entrepreneurs sell all of their accumulated capital to “capital agencies” at beginning-of-period capital price Q beg t . At the end of the period, the entrepreneurs purchase the entire capital stock K t , including any net additions to the stock, at end-of-period price Q t . This re-purchase of capital is financed with entrepreneurial net worth (NW t ) and external financing from a lender. Loan size or credit is thus defined as Credit t Q t K t NW t . This external finance takes the form of a one period loan contract. The gross return to holding capital from time-t to time tþ1 is given by: Rktþ 1
Q beg t þ1 : Qt
ð9Þ
Below we show that Q beg t þ 1 ¼ Q t þ 1 ð1 δÞ þ ½ρt þ 1 ut þ 1 aðut þ 1 Þ, where ρt þ 1 and ut þ 1 denote the rental rate and utilization rate of capital, respectively. Variations in Rktþ 1 are the source of aggregate risk in the loan contract. The external financing is subject to a costly-state-verification (CSV) problem because of idiosyncratic risk. In particular, one unit of capital purchased at time-t is transformed into ωt þ 1 units of capital in time tþ1, where ωt þ 1 is a idiosyncratic random variable with density ϕðωÞ and cumulative distribution ΦðωÞ. The realization of ωt þ 1 is directly observed by the entrepreneur, but the lender can observe the realization only if a monitoring cost is paid, a cost that is fraction μmc of the project outcome. Assuming that the entrepreneur and lender are risk-neutral, Townsend (1979) demonstrates that the optimal contract between entrepreneur and intermediary is risky debt in which monitoring only occurs if the promised payoff is not forthcoming. Payoff does not occur for sufficiently low values of the idiosyncratic shock, ωt þ 1 o ϖ t þ 1 . Let Rptþ 1 denote the promised gross rate-of-return so that Rptþ 1 is defined by Rptþ 1 ðQ t K t NW t Þ ϖ t þ 1 Rktþ 1 Q t K t :
ð10Þ
We find it convenient to express this in terms of the leverage ratio κ t ðQ t K t =NW t Þ so that (10) becomes Rptþ 1 ϖ t þ 1 Rktþ 1
κt κt 1
ð11Þ
Let f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ and gðϖ t þ 1 Þ denote the entrepreneur's share and lender's share of the project outcome: Z 1 f ðϖ Þ ωϕðωÞdω ½1 ΦðωÞϖ ϖ
gðϖ Þ ½1 Φðϖ Þϖ þ ð1 μmc Þ
Z ϖ 0
ωϕðωÞdω
ð12Þ
ð13Þ
Using these expressions, the lender's ex post realized tþ1 return on the loan contract is defined as: 2 In contrast, BGG assume that bank profits are always zero ex post so that the lender's return is pre-determined. This is not a feature of the optimal contract. See Carlstrom et al. (2013) for details. 3 Alternatively we could make the deposit rate state-contingent (and thus equal to the lending rate) so that profits are always zero. This alternative decentralization would have no effect on the model.
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
RLt þ 1
Rktþ 1 gðϖ t þ 1 ÞQ t K t Q t K t NW t
κt κt 1
¼ Rktþ 1 gðϖ t þ 1 Þ
135
ð14Þ
Similarly, the ex post t þ1 payoff to the entrepreneur with net worth NW t is given by: Entrepreneur0 s payoff ¼ κ t NW t Rktþ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ
ð15Þ
The optimal loan contract will maximize the entrepreneur's payoff subject to the lender's participation constraint. Entrepreneurs have linear preferences and discount the future at rate β. Given the high return to internal funds, they will postpone consumption indefinitely. To limit net worth accumulation and ensure that there is a need for external finance in the long run, we assume that fraction (1 γ) of the entrepreneurs die each period, where death entails eating their accumulated net worth and exiting the economy. These dying entrepreneurs are replaced by an inflow of new entrepreneurs each with a trivial initial level of net worth. CFP show that the entrepreneur's value function is linear in net worth. Let V t NW t denote this value function after loans have been repaid, but before the death shock is realized. Given the trivial consumption-savings decision, the Bellman equation is given by: V t NW t ¼ ð1 γ ÞNW t þ maxκ t ;ϖ t þ 1 γβEt V t þ 1 κ t NW t Rktþ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ
ð16Þ
where the maximization is subject to the lender's participation constraint. Recall that the lender's stochastic discount factor comes from the household, and the lender's return is linked to the return on deposits via (8), so that the lender's participation constraint is given by: Et RLt þ 1 Λt þ 1 ¼ Rdt Et Λt þ 1
ð17Þ
Hence, the end-of-time-t contracting problem can be written as: maxκt ; ϖ t þ 1 fEt V t þ 1 Rktþ 1 κ t f ðϖ t þ 1 Þg
ð18Þ
subject to Et Rktþ 1
κt Λ gðϖ t þ 1 Þ Z Rdt Et Λt þ 1 κt 1 t þ 1
ð19Þ
An important observation is that the choice of ϖ t þ 1 can be made contingent on public information available in time tþ1. Indexation of this type is optimal. After some re-arrangement, the contract optimization conditions include: 0 E t V t þ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ 0 V t þ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ ¼ Λt þ 1 g0 ðϖ t þ 1 Þ ð20Þ Et Λt þ 1 g 0 ðϖ t þ 1 Þ ðκ t 1ÞEt V t þ 1 Rktþ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ ¼ Et Λt þ 1 Rktþ 1
0 E t V t þ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ Et Λt þ 1 Rktþ 1 gðϖ t þ 1 Þ 0 Et Λt þ 1 g ðϖ t þ 1 Þ
κt gðϖ t þ 1 Þ ¼ Rdt Et Λt þ 1 κt 1
ð21Þ
ð22Þ
A key result is given by (20). The optimal monitoring cut-off ϖ t þ 1 is independent of innovations in Rktþ 1 . The second-order 0 condition implies that the ratio ð f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ=ðg 0 ðϖ t þ 1 ÞÞÞ, is increasing in ϖ t þ 1 . Hence, another implication of the privately optimal contract is that ϖ t þ 1 (and thus the optimal repayment rate Rptþ 1 ) is an increasing function of (innovations in) the marginal utility of wealth Λt þ 1 , and a decreasing function of (innovations in) the entrepreneur's valuation V t þ 1 . The monitoring cut-off implies the behavior of the repayment rate (see (11)). In log deviations, the repayment rate under the optimal contract is given by: p d r^ t ¼ r^ t 1 þ
ð1 Θg Þ½1 νðκ 1Þ 1 1 κ^ t 1 þðr^ kt Et 1 r^ kt Þ þ ðλ^ t Et 1 λ^ t Þ ðv^ t Et 1 v^ t Þ Θg ðκ 1Þ Ψ Ψ
1
jþ1 k v^ t ¼ Et ∑ β ðΞκ^ t þ j þ r^ t þ j þ 1 Þ
ð23Þ
ð24Þ
j¼0
where the hatted lower case letters denote log deviations of their uppercase counterparts, and the positive constants Θg , ν, Ξ, and Ψ are defined in the appendix. The analysis of CFP demonstrates that the latter two terms in (23) largely cancel out quantitatively. That is, shocks that lead to positive innovations in the marginal utility of wealth also lead to symmetric innovations in the return to internal funds. Hence, for parsimony we will estimate an indexation rule of the form: p d r^ t ¼ r^ t 1 þ
ð1 Θg Þ½1 νðκ 1Þ κ^ t 1 þ χ k ðr^ kt Et 1 r^ kt Þ Θg ðκ 1Þ
ð25Þ
As noted in the example sketched in Section 2, different indexation values will have dramatic effects on the financial accelerator. The original BGG model assumes that the lender's return was pre-determined. From (14), this implies that χ k is small but modestly negative (χ k ¼ 0:05, in our benchmark calibration).
136
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
Summing across all entrepreneurs, aggregate net worth accumulation is described by NW t ¼ γ NW t 1 κ t 1 Rkt f ðϖ t Þηnw;t
ð26Þ
where ηnw;t is an exogenous disturbance to the distribution of net worth. This disturbance follows the stochastic process 4
log ηnw;t ¼ ρnw log ηnw;t 1 þ εnw;t ;
ð27Þ
Eq. (26) implies that NW t is determined by the realization of and the response of ϖ t to these with εnw;t i.i.d. N(0,σ realizations. NW t then enters the contracting problem in time t so that the realization of Rkt is propagated forward. As in Christiano et al. (2010, 2014), and Gilchrist et al. (2009), we also consider time variation in the variance of the idiosyncratic shock ωt . The variance of ωt is denoted by σ t and follows the exogenous stochastic process given by Rkt
2 nw ).
log σ t ¼ ρσ log σ t 1 þ εσ ;t ;
ð28Þ
Shocks to this variance will alter the risk premium in the model. 3.3. Final good producers Perfectly competitive firms produce the final consumption good Yt combining a continuum of intermediate goods according to the CES technology: "Z #1 þ λp;t 1
Yt ¼
Y t ðiÞ1=ð1 þ λp;t Þ di
ð29Þ
0
The elasticity λp;t follows the exogenous stochastic process log λp;t ¼ ð1 ρp Þlog λp þ ρp log λp;t 1 þ εp;t θp εp;t 1 ;
ð30Þ
where εp,t is i.i.d. N(0,σ 2p ). Fluctuations in this elasticity are price markup shocks. Profit maximization and the zero profit condition imply that the price of the final good, Pt, is the familiar CES aggregate of the prices of the intermediate goods. 3.4. Intermediate goods producers A monopolist produces the intermediate good i according to the production function α
Y t ðiÞ ¼ max fA1t α K t ðiÞα Lt ðiÞ1 α At ϒ1t α F; 0g;
ð31Þ
where Kt(i) and Lt(i) denote the amounts of capital and labor employed by firm i. F is a fixed cost of production, chosen so that profits are zero in steady state. The variable At is the exogenous non-stationary level of TFP progress. Its growth rate (zt Δ ln At ) is given by zt ¼ ð1 ρz Þγ z þ ρz zt 1 þ εz;t ;
ð32Þ
with εz,t i.i.d. N(0,σ The other non-stationary process ϒt is linked to the investment sector and is discussed below. Every period a fraction ξp of intermediate firms cannot choose its price optimally, but resets it according to the indexation rule 2 z ).
ι
P t ðiÞ ¼ P t 1 ðiÞπ tp 1 π 1 ιp ;
ð33Þ
where πt Pt/Pt 1 is gross inflation and π is its steady state. The remaining fraction of firms chooses its price Pt (i) optimally, by maximizing the present discounted value of future profits ( " #) ! s 1 s ι s β Λt þ s =P t þ s Et ∑ ξp P t ðiÞ ∏ π tpþ k 1 π 1 ιp Y t þ s ðiÞ W t þ s Lt þ s ðiÞ P t þ s ρt þ s K t þ s ðiÞ ð34Þ Λt =P t s¼0 k¼1 where the demand function comes from the final goods producers, Λt =P t is the marginal utility of nominal income for the representative household, and Wt is the nominal wage. 3.5. Employment agencies Firms are owned by a continuum of households, indexed by j ϵ ½0; 1. Each household is a monopolistic supplier of specialized labor, Lt(j), as in Erceg et al. (2000). A large number of competitive employment agencies combine this specialized labor into a homogenous labor input sold to intermediate firms, according to "Z #1 þ λw;t 1
Lt ¼
Lt ðjÞ1=ð1 þ λw;t Þ dj
ð35Þ
0
4
This disturbance to net worth is assumed to only alter the net worth of the new entrepreneurs so that it does not enter the Bellman equation above.
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
137
As in the case of the final good, the desired markup of wages over the household's marginal rate of substitution, λw;t ; follows the exogenous stochastic process log λw;t ¼ ð1 ρw Þlog λw þ ρw log λw;t 1 þ εw;t θw εw;t 1 ;
ð36Þ
with εw;t i.i.d. N (0, σ 2w ). This is the wage markup shock. Profit maximization by the perfectly competitive employment agencies implies that the wage paid by intermediate firms for their homogenous labor input is "Z # λw;t 1
Wt ¼
W t ðjÞ 1=λw;t dj
ð37Þ
0
3.6. Capital agencies The capital stock is managed by a collection of perfectly competitive capital agencies. These firms are owned by households and discount cash flows with Λt , the marginal utility of real income for the representative household. At the beginning of period t, these agencies purchase the capital stock K t 1 from the entrepreneurs at beginning-of-period price Q beg t . The agencies produce capital services by varying the utilization rate ut which transforms physical capital into effective capital according to K t ¼ ut K t 1 :
ð38Þ
Effective capital is then rented to firms at the real rental rate ρt :The cost of capital utilization is aðut Þ per unit of physical capital. The capital agency then re-sells the capital to entrepreneurs at the end of the period at price Q t . The profit flow is thus given by: Q t ð1 δÞK t 1 þ ½ρt ut aðut ÞK t 1 Q beg t Kt 1
ð39Þ
Profit maximization implies Q beg ¼ Q t ð1 δÞ þ ½ρt ut aðut Þ t
ð40Þ
ρt ¼ a0 ðut Þ
ð41Þ
In steady state, u ¼1, a(1)¼0 and
ϑ a” (1)/a'(1). Hence, in the neighborhood of the steady state
Q t ð1 δÞ þ ρt Q beg t
ð42Þ
which is consistent with BGG's definition of the intertemporal return to holding capital ððρt þ ð1 δÞQ t Þ=ðQ t 1 ÞÞ. These capital agencies also augment the capital stock by producing investment goods. Investment goods are produced with a linear technology that transforms one consumption good into ϒt investment goods. The exogenous level of productivity ϒt is non-stationary with a growth rate (υt Δ log Yt) given by Rkt
υt ¼ ð1 ρυ Þγ υ þ ρυ υt 1 þ ευ;t :
ð43Þ
The constant returns production function implies that the price of investment goods (in consumption units) is equal to P It ¼ ð1=ϒt Þ. These investment goods are transformed into new capital via a concave technology that takes It investment goods and transforms them into μt ½1 SðI t =I t 1 ÞI t new capital goods. The time-t profit flow is thus given by It Q t μt 1 S ð44Þ I t P It I t It 1 where P It is the relative price of the investment good. The function S captures the presence of adjustment costs in investment, as in Christiano et al. (2005). The function has the following convenient steady state properties: S¼ S' ¼0 and S”40. These firms are owned by households and discount future cash flows with Λt, the marginal utility of real income for the representative household. JPT refer to the investment shock mt as a shock to the marginal efficiency of investment (MEI) as it alters the transformation between investment and installed capital. JPT conclude that this shock is the primary driver of output and investment at business cycle frequencies. The investment shock follows the stochastic process log μt ¼ ρμ log μt 1 þ εμ;t ;
ð45Þ
where εμ;t is i.i.d. N ð0; σ 2μ Þ: 3.7. Households Each household maximizes the utility function ( " #) 1 Lt þ s ðjÞ1 þ ψ s ; Et ∑ β bt þ s lnðC t þ s hC t þ s 1 Þ φ 1þψ s¼0
ð46Þ
138
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
where Ct is consumption, h is the degree of habit formation and bt is a shock to the discount factor. This intertemporal preference shock follows the stochastic process log bt ¼ ρb log bt 1 þ εb;t ;
ð47Þ
with εb;t i.i.d. N (0, σ 2b ). Since technological progress is nonstationary, utility is logarithmic to ensure the existence of a balanced growth path. The existence of state contingent securities ensures that household consumption is the same across all households. The household's flow budget constraint is C t þ T t þ Dt þ
Bt Rt 1 Bt 1 W t ðjÞ r þ Lt ðjÞ þRdt 1 Dt 1 þ prof itst ; Pt Pt Pt
ð48Þ
where Dt denotes real deposit at the lender, Tt is lump-sum taxes, and Bt is holdings of nominal government bonds that pay gross nominal rate Rt. The term prof itst denotes the combined profit flow of all the firms owned by the representative agent including lenders, intermediate goods producers, and capital agencies. Every period a fraction ξw of households cannot freely set its wage, but follows the indexation rule α
α
W t ðjÞ ¼ W t 1 ðjÞðπ t 1 ezt 1 þ 1 αυt Þιw ðπ eγ z þ 1 αγ υ Þ1 ιw ; The remaining fraction of households chooses instead an optimal wage Wt(j) by maximizing ( " #) 1 Lt þ S ðjÞ1 þ ψ Λt þ s s s þ W t ðjÞLt þ s ðjÞ Et ∑ ξw β bt þ s φ 1þψ Pt þ s s¼0
ð49Þ
ð50Þ
subject to the labor demand function coming from the firm. 3.8. The government A monetary policy authority sets the nominal interest rate following a feedback rule of the form " #1 ρR Rt Rt 1 ρR π t ϕπ X t ϕx Xt =X t 1 ϕdx ¼ ηmp;t ; R R π X nt Xnt =Xnt 1
ð51Þ
where R is the steady state of the gross nominal interest rate. The interest rates responds to deviations of inflation from its steady state, as well as to the level and the growth rate of the GDP gap (X t =X nt ). The monetary policy rule is also perturbed by a monetary policy shock, ηmp;t , which evolves according to log ηmp;t ¼ ρmp log ηmp;t 1 þ εmp;t ; where εmp;t is i.i.d. N ð0; σ 1 Gt ¼ 1 Yt; gt
2 mp Þ.
ð52Þ
Public spending is determined exogenously as a time-varying fraction of output. ð53Þ
where the government spending shock gt follows the stochastic process log g t ¼ ð1 ρg Þlog g þ ρg log g t 1 þ εg;t ;
ð54Þ
with εg;t i:i:d: Nð0; σ 2g Þ. The spending is financed with lump sum taxes. 3.9. Market clearing The aggregate resource constraints are given by: Ct þ
It
ϒt
þGt þ aðut ÞK t 1 ¼ Y t
Z ϖt I K t ¼ ð1 δÞ 1 μmc ωϕðωÞdω K t 1 þ μt 1 S t It ; It 1 0
ð55Þ
ð56Þ
In (55), we follow Christiano et al. (2014), and assume that the trivial level of entrepreneurial consumption is transferred to households for their consumption. This completes the description of the model. We now turn to the estimation of the linearized model. 4. Estimation The linearized version of the model equations are collected in the appendix. The three fundamental agency cost parameters are the steady state idiosyncratic variance ðσ ss Þ, the entrepreneurial survival rate (γ), and the monitoring cost fraction (μmc ). In contrast to DeGraeve (2008), we follow Christiano et al. (2010), and calibrate these parameters to be consistent with long run aspects of US financial data. We follow this calibration approach because these parameters are
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
139
Table 1 Models estimations and models comparisons with BAA – T10 credit spread and return to capital data. All models have autocorrelated measurement errors in the credit spread and return to capital series.
Log data density
JPT Modela 1429.1
BGG Modelb 1383.1
Indexation to Rk Modelc 1339.6
Posterior model probability
0%
0%
100%
Posteriorse
Posteriors
Posteriors
Coefficient Description
α ιp ιw γz γυ h λp λw log Lss 100(π - 1) 100(β-1 - 1) Ψ ξp ξw ϑ S̈ ϕπ ϕx ϕdx ρR ρmp ρz ρg ρυ ρp ρw ρb θp θw ρσ ρnw ρμ ρrpme ρrkme ν χk
Prior
Capital share Price indexation Wage indexation SS technology growth rate SS IST growth rate Consumption habit SS mark-up goods prices SS mark-up wages SS hours SS quarterly inflation Discount factor Inverse frisch elasticity Calvo prices Calvo wages Elasticity capital utilization costs Investment adjustment costs Taylor rule inflation Taylor rule gap Taylor rule gap growth Taylor rule smoothing Monetary policy Neutral technology growth Government spending IST growth Price mark-up Wage mark-up Intertemporal preference Price mark-up MA Wage mark-up MA Idiosyncratic variance Net worth Marginal efficiency of investment Risk premium measurement error Rk measurement error Elasticity risk premium Indexation to Rk
Prior densityd
Prior mean
pstdev post. mean
5%
95%
Post. mean
5%
95%
Post. mean
N B B N N B N N N N G G B B G
0.30 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.15 0.15 0.00 0.50 0.25 2.00 0.66 0.66 5.00
0.05 0.15 0.15 0.03 0.03 0.10 0.05 0.05 0.50 0.10 0.10 0.75 0.10 0.10 1.00
0.16 0.31 0.18 0.51 0.50 0.87 0.18 0.17 0.34 0.64 0.11 2.43 0.72 0.50 5.62
G
4.00
1.00
N N N B B B B B B B B B B B B B
1.70 0.13 0.13 0.60 0.40 0.60 0.60 0.60 0.60 0.60 0.60 0.50 0.50 0.60 0.60 0.60
B B N U
5%
95%
0.15 0.12 0.10 0.47 0.48 0.83 0.13 0.14 0.18 0.49 0.05 1.62 0.67 0.40 4.28
0.17 0.54 0.26 0.54 0.52 0.91 0.25 0.20 1.08 0.82 0.17 3.18 0.77 0.61 6.89
0.17 0.13 0.12 0.49 0.49 0.85 0.20 0.15 0.40 0.63 0.14 4.64 0.79 0.87 4.68
0.15 0.05 0.06 0.48 0.47 0.81 0.15 0.11 0.02 0.57 0.07 4.28 0.73 0.81 4.15
0.18 0.21 0.19 0.51 0.51 0.88 0.25 0.20 0.73 0.69 0.22 5.02 0.85 0.93 5.12
0.16 0.15 0.17 0.49 0.51 0.88 0.18 0.08 0.33 0.72 0.14 3.39 0.74 0.66 5.17
0.15 0.07 0.11 0.46 0.48 0.86 0.14 0.04 0.03 0.67 0.07 2.53 0.70 0.60 4.30
0.17 0.23 0.23 0.53 0.54 0.91 0.23 0.12 0.64 0.77 0.22 4.09 0.78 0.71 5.91
2.96
2.55 3.33
1.09
0.83
1.33
2.43
1.90
2.96
0.30 0.05 0.05 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.20
1.94 0.06 0.18 0.77 0.05 0.38 1.00 0.26 0.95 0.99 0.54 0.61 0.82 – – 0.70
1.65 0.04 0.13 0.73 0.00 0.29 1.00 0.17 0.91 0.98 0.44 0.49 0.70 – – 0.65
2.27 0.10 0.23 0.81 0.09 0.48 1.00 0.36 1.00 1.00 0.64 0.71 0.93 – – 0.76
1.35 0.04 0.27 0.83 0.06 0.24 0.99 0.43 0.91 0.95 0.56 0.75 0.95 0.94 0.79 0.17
1.19 0.01 0.24 0.80 0.01 0.13 0.99 0.31 0.83 0.91 0.44 0.66 0.89 0.88 0.73 0.04
1.51 0.07 0.30 0.87 0.11 0.33 1.00 0.52 0.98 0.99 0.70 0.84 1.00 1.00 0.86 0.28
2.11 0.11 0.20 0.86 0.05 0.37 1.00 0.35 0.95 0.96 0.58 0.71 0.99 0.87 0.78 0.89
1.91 0.09 0.16 0.84 0.01 0.30 0.99 0.26 0.91 0.94 0.50 0.62 0.98 0.77 0.71 0.77
2.31 0.13 0.23 0.89 0.10 0.44 1.00 0.44 0.99 0.98 0.66 0.81 1.00 0.96 0.85 0.99
0.60
0.20
0.75
0.52 0.97
0.95
0.91
0.99
0.72
0.61
0.83
0.60 0.05 0.00
0.20 0.02 2.00
0.59 0 0
0.48 0.70 – – – –
0.60 0.19 BGG
0.48 – –
0.73 – –
0.79 0.19 2.24
0.65 – 1.70
0.91 – 2.82
Standard deviation of shocks
σmp σz σg συ σp σw σb σσ σnw σμ
Monetary policy Neutral technology growth Government spending IST growth Price mark-up Wage mark-up Intertemporal preference Idiosyncratic variance Net worth Marginal efficiency of investment
Prior density
Prior mean
Pstdev Post. mean
5%
95% Post. mean
5%
95% Post. mean
5%
95%
I I I I I I I I I I
0.20 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.50 0.50 0.50
1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
0.24 0.80 0.33 0.53 0.19 0.24 0.03 – – 4.76
0.30 0.98 0.40 0.63 0.27 0.33 0.05 – – 6.28
0.22 0.80 0.33 0.53 0.23 0.25 0.02 0.06 0.69 1.80
0.27 0.98 0.40 0.64 0.31 0.36 0.05 0.08 1.07 3.01
0.20 0.79 0.33 0.53 0.21 0.31 0.02 0.07 1.12 2.96
0.25 0.97 0.40 0.64 0.28 0.39 0.04 0.09 1.74 4.41
0.27 0.89 0.36 0.58 0.23 0.29 0.04 – – 5.59
0.25 0.89 0.36 0.59 0.27 0.31 0.03 0.08 0.87 2.39
0.22 0.88 0.36 0.58 0.24 0.35 0.03 0.08 1.43 3.67
140
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
Table 1 (continued ) Standard deviation of shocks
σrpme Risk premium measurement error σrkme Rk measurement error
Prior density
Prior mean
Pstdev Post. mean
5%
95% Post. mean
5%
95% Post. mean
5%
95%
I
0.50
1.00
0.19
0.17 0.20 0.08
0.07 0.09 0.08
0.06 0.08
I
0.50
1.00
2.35
2.12 2.59 2.67
2.39 2.99 1.52
1.08 2.08
Note: Calibrated coefficients: δ ¼0.025, g implies a SS government share of 0.22.For the agency cost models (BGG and Indexation) the following parameters are also calibrated: entrepreneurial survival rate γ¼ 0.94, a SS risk premium rp¼ 0.02/4, and a SS leverage ratio κ¼ 1.95. a In JPT model there are not financial (risk premium and net worth) shocks. The elasticity of risk premium, ν, is set to 0, and the indexation parameter χk is irrelevant and set to 0. b In BGG model there are financial shocks and the elasticity of risk premium, ν, is calibrated to 0.19, while the indexation to the return of capital parameter, χk, is set to the implied in BGG, χk ¼(Θg 1)/Θg where Θg ¼ 0.95. c In the Indexation to Rk model there are financial shocks and the elasticity of risk premium, ν, is calibrated to 0.19 and the indexation to the return of capital parameter, χk, is estimated. d N stands for Norman, B-Beta, G-Gamma, U-Uniform, I-Inverted-Gamma distribution. e Posterior percentiles are from 2 chains of 100,000 draws generated using a Random Walk Metropolis algorithm. We discard the initial 50,000 and retain one every 5 subsequent draws.
pinned down by long run or steady state properties of the model, not the business cycle dynamics that the Bayesian estimation is trying to match. In any event, these three parameters are calibrated to match the steady state levels of the risk premium (Rp Rd ), leverage ratio (κ ), and default rate ðΦðϖ ss ÞÞ. In particular, they are chosen to deliver a 200 bp annual risk premium (BAA-Treasury spread), a leverage ratio of κ ¼ 1:95, and a quarterly default rate of 0.03/4. These imply an entrepreneurial survival rate of γ ¼0.944, a standard deviation of σ ss ¼ 0:2865, and a monitoring cost of μmc ¼0.63.5 A key expression in the log-linearized model is the reduced-form relationship between leverage and the investment distortion: k d Et r^ t þ 1 r^ t ¼ νðq^ t þ k^ t n^ t Þ þ σ^ t
ð57Þ
(See the Appendix for details.) The value of ν implied by the previous calibration is ν ¼0.19. This is thus imposed in the estimation of the financial models.6 For JPT we have ν ¼0. Steady state relationships also imply that we calibrate δ ¼0.025, and (1 1/g) ¼0.22. The remaining parameters are estimated using familiar Bayesian techniques as in JPT. For the nonfinancial parameters of the model we use the same priors as in JPT. We treat as observables the growth rates of real GDP, consumption, investment, the real wage, and the relative price of investment. The other observables include employment, inflation, the nominal rate, the return on capital (Rkt Þ, and the risk p d premium (Et r^ t þ 1 r^ t Þ. Employment is measured as the log of per capita hours. Inflation is the consumption deflator, and the nominal rate is the federal funds rate. The series for Rkt comes from Gomme et al. (2011). The risk premium is the spread between the BAA and ten year Treasury. The time period for the estimation is 1972:1–2008:4. We choose the end of the sample period to avoid the observed zero bound on the nominal rate. We estimate three versions of the model. Along with all the exogenous shocks outlined in the paper, we also include autocorrelated measurement error between the model's risk premium and the observed risk premium. Autocorrelated measurement error is also included for Rkt . The first model we label JPT as it corresponds to the model without agency costs (ν ¼0). Note that the JPT model will assign all risk premium variation to autocorrelated measurement error. The remaining two models have operative agency costs (ν ¼0.19). Recall that the optimal contract has the form given by: p d r^ t ¼ r^ t 1 þ
ð1 Θg Þ½1 νðκ 1Þ κ^ t 1 þ χ k ðr^ kt Et 1 r^ kt Þ Θg ðκ 1Þ
ð58Þ
For both models, we impose the values of ν, κ , and Θg , as these are pinned down by the steady state of the model. In the model labeled BGG we also impose the level of indexation implicitly assumed by BGG: χ k ¼ 0:05. For the model labeled Rk-indexation, we estimate the value of χ k . We use diffuse priors on the indexation parameters with a uniform distribution centered at 0 and with a standard deviation of 2. The agency cost models also include two financial shocks: (i) time-varying movements in idiosyncratic risk, and (ii) exogenous redistributions of net worth. Both of these shocks are irrelevant in the JPT model in which lending is not subject to the CSV problem. We posit priors for the standard deviation and autocorrelation of these financial shocks in a manner symmetric with the non-financial exogenous processes in JPT. Rϖ This monitoring cost is not as large as it seems. In Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), monitoring costs are given by μmc 0 t ϕðωÞdω ¼ μmc Φðϖ t Þ. This is of course larger than the expression in (56). Using this expression for monitoring costs, the calibration in the text would require μmc ¼0.29, within the range of reasonable numbers suggested by Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997). It is unclear which expression for monitoring costs is more appropriate. 6 As a form of sensitivity analysis, we also estimated ν in the financial models. We found that the estimation is quite sensitive to priors, again suggesting that it is not well identified by business cycle dynamics. 5
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
141
Table 2 Variance decomposition at different horizons in the JPT, BGG and Rk Indexation Models.
The estimation results are summarized in Table 1. The BGG and Rk-indexation agency cost models easily dominate the JPT model as the JPT model cannot capture the forecastability of the risk premium that is in the data. Comparing BGG and Rk-indexation, the data rejects the BGG level of indexation preferring a level of contract indexation that is economically
142
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
significant: χ k ¼ 2:24 with a 90% confidence interval between 1.70 and 2.82. As suggested by the example in Section 2, indexation in excess of unity will imply significantly different responses to shocks compared to the BGG assumption. We will see this manifested in the IRF below. Two other differences in parameter estimates are worth some comment. First, the BGG model estimates a significantly smaller size for investment adjustment costs ( S″) in the table: S″ ¼ 1:09 for BGG, but 2.43 for Rk-indexation, and 2.96 for JPT. The level of adjustment costs has two contrasting effects. First, lower adjustment costs will increase the response of investment to aggregate shocks. Second, lower adjustment costs imply smaller movements in the price of installed capital (Q t ) and thus smaller financial accelerator effects in the BGG model. A second important difference in parameter estimates is in the standard deviation of the shocks. Compared to JPT, the BGG model estimates a significantly smaller volatility in the MEI shocks, and instead shifts this variance on to net worth shocks. Recall that the principal conclusion of JPT is the importance of the MEI shocks in the business cycle. But we once again end up with the JPT conclusion with regards to the importance of MEI shocks in the Rk-indexation model. An interesting question we take up below is why the BGG model downplays these shocks so significantly. Table 2 reports the variance decomposition of three key variables: GDP, investment, and the risk premium. The JPT results are replicated here: the MEI shocks account for a substantial amount of business cycle variability in GDP (55% at the 4-quarter horizon) and investment (82% at the 4-quarter horizon). This conclusion is essentially unchanged with Rkindexation. As anticipated by the example in Section 2, the estimated level of indexation results in real behavior similar to a model without agency costs. This is particularly clear in the IRFs presented in Fig. 3 that we discuss below. In contrast to the Rk-indexation, BGG places much less weight on the MEI shocks and instead shifts this variance to the financial shocks (the idiosyncratic variance and net worth shocks) and the monetary policy shock. For the case of
Consumption
Output
Investment 3
0.2
0.6 0.5
2.5
0.15
0.4
2
0.3
0.1
1.5
0.2
0.05
0.5
1
0.1 0 -0.1
5
9
13
17
-0.05
1
5
9
Inflation
0.25
0 5
9
13
17
0.1
0.04
0.05
1
5
9
13
17
13
17
0 -0.2
0 -0.1 1
5
9
13
17
-0.6
-0.8
-0.7
-1
1
5
9
13
17
13
17
13
17
1 0.5 0
-3
-0.5
-4
-1
-5
-1.5
-6
9
Credit
-2
JPT
5
1.5
-1
_______
17
-0.5
-0.5
-2
1
Promised Repayment
17
13
-0.3
-0.6
0 13
9
-0.4
1
-1.5
5
-0.2
Return on Capital (R k) 0.5
9
1
Price of Capital
-0.4
5
-0.1
0.1
0.2
1
Federal Funds
Net Worth 0.4
9
17
0 -0.05
0.6
5
13
0.2
Spread
1
9
0.15
0.06
0
5
0.25
0.02 1
1
-1
0.3
0.1
0.05
-0.5
0.35
0.08
0.1
0
17
Wages
0.15
0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 -0.02 -0.04 -0.06 -0.08 -0.1 -0.12
13
0.12
0.2
-0.05
0
0 1
……........ BGG
-2
1
5
9
_____
Indexation to Rk
Fig. 3. (a) Impulse response functions to a one standard deviation marginal efficiency of investment shock using the estimated parameter values for each model and normalizing the standard deviation of the shock to the BGG model estimate.
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
Output
Consumption
0.6
1.2
5
0.4
4
0.3
3
0.6
0.2
2
0.4
0.1
0.2
0
1
0
1
5
9
13
17
-0.1
1 1
5
9
Inflation
0.06
0.08
0.04
0.06
13
17
0 -0.02
0.4
0 1
9
13
17
Net Worth
1
5
9
13
17
2.5 2
-0.15
1.5
-0.2 -0.25
1
-0.3
0.5
-0.35
0
-0.4
1
k
Return on Capital (R ) 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 -0.5 -1
5
3
-0.1
5
9
13
17
5
9
13
-0.2
0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 -0.1
1
5
17
……........ BGG
17
1
5
9
13
17
13
17
Credit 1
3
0.5
2
0
1
-0.5
0
13
1.5
4
-1
9
Price of Capital
Promised Repayment 5
1
17
0.2
Spread
0.05
13
0.6
0.02
0
9
1
0.04
0.02 9
5
0.8
0.1
5
1
Federal Funds
0.12
1
0 -1
1.2
0.14
0.1
-0.05
17
0.16
0.08
0
13
Wages
0.12
-0.02
Investment
6
0.5
0.8
143
1
5
9
13
17
1
5
9
-1 -1.5
_____
Indexation to Rk
Fig. 3. (continued) (b) Impulse response functions to a one standard deviation net worth shock using the estimated parameter values for each model and normalizing the standard deviation of the shock to the BGG model estimate.
investment at the 4-quarter horizon, the BGG model places 4% of the variance on the MEI shocks (compared to 72% for the Rk-indexation model, and 82% for JPT). The importance of the two financial shocks increases from 20% under Rk-indexation, to 74% for BGG. The estimated level of financial shocks depends critically upon the estimated level of indexation. The advantage of the financial models is showcased in the variance decomposition of the risk premium. By assumption, JPT assigns 100% of this variation to measurement error. In contrast, the financial models explain large portions of the risk premia movement by forces within the model. For example, at the 4-quarter horizon, the Rk indexation model assigns about 40% to measurement error, while this is only 24% for BGG. This predictability of the risk premium is echoed by DeGraeve (2008). Why does the BGG model downplay the MEI shocks and thus shift variance to the other shocks? The answer is quite apparent from Fig. 3a. The figure sets all parameter values equal to those estimated for each model. To make the shocks comparable, the size of the impulse is set to the estimated SD under BGG. Returning to Fig. 3a, a positive innovation in MEI leads to a fall in the price of capital. Since the BGG contract is not indexed to the return to capital, the shock leads to a sharp decline in entrepreneurial net worth, and thus a sharp increase in the risk premium. This procyclical movement in the risk premium is in sharp contrast to the data. Hence, the Bayesian estimation in the BGG model estimates only a small amount of variability coming from the MEI shocks. Notice that in the Rk-indexation model net worth rises in response to an MEI shock, so that the impact effect on the risk premium is countercyclical. The main difference among models is the behavior of the repayment that under Rk-indexation is lowered in response to the drop in the return on capital, while in BGG it remains unchanged. The Rk-indexation model is thus consistent with MEI shocks driving the cycle, and the risk premium being countercyclical. The similarity of the Rk-indexation and JPT model is also apparent: the two IRFs to an MEI mirror each other
144
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
Output 0
1
5
9
Consumption 13
17
-0.05
0 -0.02
1
5
9
13
Investment 17
-0.04
-0.1
-0.06 -0.15
-0.08
-0.2
-0.1
-0.25
-0.12
-0.02
1
5
9
13
17
-0.04 -0.06 -0.08 -0.1 -0.12 -0.14 -0.16
0.002 0 -0.002 -0.004 -0.006 -0.008 -0.01 -0.012 -0.014 -0.016 -0.018
0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 5
9
13
17
1
0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.6
5
13
17
0
1
5
9
1
5
13
17
-0.4
-0.5 -1
-0.6
-1.5
-0.8 -1
-2
-1.2
-2.5
……........ BGG
9
13
17
-0.04 -0.06 -0.08
Price of Capital 0.05 0 -0.05
1
5
9
13
17
1
5
9
13
17
13
17
-0.1 -0.15 -0.2 -0.25 -0.3
Credit 0 -0.05
0.5 0
17
0.02
Promised Repayment
0.2 0
9
1
0.4
13
Federal Funds
-0.02
Return on Capital (R k ) 0.6
-0.2
9
Net Worth
0.35
1
5
0.04
Spread 0.4
0
1
Wages
Inflation 0
0.1 0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.6 -0.7 -0.8 -0.9
1
5
9
-0.1 1
5
9
13
17
-0.15 -0.2 -0.25 -0.3 -0.35 -0.4 -0.45
_ _ _ _ _ Indexation to R
k
Fig. 3. (continued) (c) Impulse response functions to a one standard deviation idiosyncratic variance shock using the estimated parameter values for each model and normalizing the standard deviation of the shock to the BGG model estimate.
closely except that there is amplification in the agency cost model because of the decline in the risk premium (recall also that the IRFs are plotted for each model's estimated parameters). Since the BGG model downplays the importance of MEI shocks, it must shift this variance to other shocks. Figs. 3b-3c plot the IRFs to the two financial shocks. Consider first the net worth shock. This shock has a larger effect on net worth and prices in the BGG model because of the multiplier mechanism outlined in Section 2. This effect is entirely absent in the indexation model. Further, the estimated level of nominal wage rigidity is higher under BGG so that production responds more sharply to this demand shock. There is similar amplification with the risk shock. The good news with the two financial shocks is that the spread is now countercyclical. The problem with the risk shock is that a fairly large movement in the spread has a very modest effect on real behavior, so that the estimation puts little weight on these shocks. As for net worth shocks, it is clear why the BGG model places such weight upon them: they lead to significant movement in output, co-movement among the aggregates, and a countercyclical risk premium. But for the indexation model, the lack of a financial accelerator means that these shocks have a fairly modest effect. Fig. 3d plots the IRF to a monetary shock. In the case of BGG, the IRFs exhibit plausible co-movement and countercyclical spreads. The estimation does not put more weight on these policy shocks because the funds rate is an observable, and thus limits possible interest rate variability. One interesting and unique implication of the indexation model is that the risk premium is procyclical in response to monetary shocks. This conditional correlation is consistent with the evidence presented in Furlanetto et al. (2013). The reason BGG and the indexation model deliver different risk premium behavior has to do with the response of net worth to a monetary shock. The monetary contraction leads to a decline in investment demand (for the usual reasons) and a corresponding decline in the price of capital. Taken by itself, this decline in investment
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
Output 0 -0.1
1
5
9
13
17
0 -0.05
1
5
9
-0.4
-0.25
0
Wages 0
9
13
17
-0.01
1
5
9
-0.1
17
-0.03 -0.04 -0.05
-0.2
-0.06
-0.25
-0.07
0.05
0.1
0.2
0
0 5
9
13
17
-0.05
-0.1 1 1
5
9
13
17
-0.1 -0.15
1
9
-1 -1.5 -2
13
17
-0.7
-1.2
-0.8
0
1
-0.2 5
-5
17
9
13
17
1
5
9
13
17
-0.4 -0.6 -0.8
-3
-3
_______ JPT
1
-2
-2.5
13
Credit
2
-4
9
-0.5 -0.6
-1
17
-0.4
-1
0 5
5
Promised Repayment
0.5
13
-0.2
-0.8
Return on Capital ( R k) 1.5
9
-0.3
-0.4 -0.6
1
5
Price of Capital
0.4
-0.2 1
0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 -0.1 1
Net Worth
Spread 0.1
0
13
-0.02
-0.15
17
Federal Funds
0.01 5
13
-2.5
Inflation 0.05
9
-2
-0.4
1
5
-1
-0.45
-0.7
1
-1.5
-0.35
-0.6
0.5
-0.5
-0.3
-0.5
-0.5
17
-0.15 -0.2
0
13
-0.1
-0.3
-0.05
Investment
Consumption
-0.2
0
145
-1 -1.2
……........ BGG
_ _ _ _ _ Indexation to R k
Fig. 3. (continued) (d) Impulse response functions to a one standard deviation monetary policy shock using the estimated parameter values for each model and normalizing the standard deviation of the shock to the BGG model estimate.
demand would lower the risk premium. But in BGG, this decline in the price of capital also leads to a sharp fall in net worth, and thus an increase in the risk premium. In contrast, the indexation model implies that the effect on net worth is largely sterilized as the repayment rate varies with the observed price of capital.
5. Sensitivity analysis We have conducted a significant level of sensitivity analysis focusing on alternative observable variables, alternative steady-state calibrations, and an alternative definition of the risk premium. We summarize these results here. Our focus will be on the estimated level of indexation. Table 3 presents a summary of the sensitivity analysis as we vary the financial variables used as observables. The series for leverage comes from Gilchrist et al. (2009). When net worth is treated as an observable, we follow Christiano et al. (2014) and link the model's growth rate of net worth with the growth rate in the Dow. In all cases we include serially correlated measurement error between the financial variables and their empirical counterparts. Note first that the indexation model dominates the BGG model from the measuring stick of log data density (JPT is always a distant third and is not reported). The basic conclusion from Table 3 is the robustness of the estimated level of indexation across the observables. Recall from Fig. 1, that there is a significant difference between an indexation level of 0 and 1, but very little quantitative difference in the financial accelerator as we move from, say, 1 to 2. Remarkably all the estimated indexation values imply essentially no financial accelerator. The final row of Table 3 returns to the baseline set of observables but imposes the monitoring cost value estimated by Christiano et al. (2014), μmc ¼0.21. We hold the other primitives constant, so the steady state annual risk
146
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
Table 3 p
d
Sensitivity analysis. (Risk premium¼E t r^ t þ 1 r^ t ).
p
d
Baseline with model's risk premium defined as E t r^ t þ 1 r^ t . k Replace r^ t with leverage as observable k Replace r^ t with net worth as an observable
Add net worth as an observable Add leverage as an observable Baseline but with monitoring costs of μmc ¼ 0:21
Estimated indexationa
BGGb
Rk indexationb
2.24 (1.70, 2.82) 2.14 (1.46, 2.65) 0.90 (0.79, 1.01) 3.14 (2.80, 3.46) 2.96 (2.51, 3.46) 3.20 (2.88, 3.46)
1383.1 0% 1527.5 75% 1512.6 0% 1862.9 0% 1965.5 0% 1368.5 0%
1339.6 100% 1534.4 25% 1491.6 100% 1839.3 100% 1875.6 100% 1336.4 100%
Note: Unless otherwise noted, the financial observables include the risk premium and the return on capital series estimated by Gomme et al. (2011). The series for leverage comes from Gilchrist et al. (2009). When net worth is treated as an observable, we link the model's growth rate of net worth with the growth rate in the Dow. In all cases we include serially correlated measurement error between the financial variables and their empirical counterparts. The time period for the estimation is 1972:1–2008:4. a In each cell, the first row is the point estimate, and the second row is the 90% confidence interval. b In each cell, the first row is the log data density, and the second row is the posterior model probability.
Table 4 k
d
Sensitivity analysis. (Risk premium¼E t r^ t þ 1 r^ t ).
k
d
Baseline with risk premium defined as E t r^ t þ 1 r^ t . k Replace r^ t with leverage as observable k Replace r^ t with net worth as an observable
Add net worth as an observable Add leverage as an observable
Estimated indexationa
BGGb
Rk indexationb
2.84 (2.37,3.32) 1.70 (1.36, 2.05) 1.51 (1.20, 1.90) 2.40 (1.91, 2.88) 2.18 (1.84, 2.54)
1394.5 0% 1555.8 0% 1586.4 0% 1854.5 0% 1922.6 0%
1348.3 100% 1511.1 100% 1557.1 100% 1818.8 100% 1893.4 100%
Note: Unless otherwise noted, the financial observables include the risk premium and the return on capital series estimated by Gomme et al. (2011). The series for leverage comes from Gilchrist, Ortiz and Zakrajsek (2009). When net worth is treated as an observable, we link the model's growth rate of net worth with the growth rate in the Dow. In all cases we include serially correlated measurement error between the financial variables and their empirical counterparts. The time period for the estimation is 1972:1–2008:4. a In each cell, the first row is the point estimate, and the second row is the 90% confidence interval. b In each cell, the first row is the log data density, and the second row is the posterior model probability.
premium is now just 84 bp, and the external finance elasticity is ν ¼ 0:071: As with the rest of the table, the estimation again implies no financial accelerator. k d Table 4 presents the complementary evidence for an alternative measure of the risk premium, ðEt r^ t þ 1 r^ t Þ. This expression was used, for example, by DeGraeve (2008) in his comparison of the model's risk premium to its empirical counterpart. Note that this expression for the risk premium is, up to a linear approximation, proportional to the previous: p d Et r^ t þ 1 r^ t ¼
ð1 Θg Þ½1 νðκ 1Þ k d ðEt r^ t þ 1 r^ t σ^ t Þ νΘg ðκ 1Þ
ð59Þ
This constant of proportionality is a fraction, equal to 0.23 for our baseline calibration. This alternative measure of the risk premium also implies a different calibration of the steady state. That is, to match a 200 bp annual spread of (Rk Rd Þ, a leverage ratio of κ ¼ 1:95, and a quarterly default rate of 0.03/4, we need an entrepreneurial survival rate of γ ¼0.98, a standard deviation of σ ss ¼ 0:28, and a monitoring cost of μmc ¼ 0:12. This then implies that the agency cost elasticity is given by ν ¼ 0:041. In any event, Table 4 presents the complementary set of results. The outcome is as in Table 3: the indexation model dominates, and the estimated level of indexation implies a trivial financial accelerator. 6. Conclusion This paper began as an empirical investigation of the importance of agency costs and contract indexation in the business cycle. To reiterate, our principal results include the following. First, the financial models appear to be an improvement over the financial-frictionless JPT. Second, Rk-indexation appears to be an important characteristic of the data. Third, the
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
147
importance of financial shocks (net worth and idiosyncratic variance) in explaining the business cycle is significantly affected by the estimated degree of Rk-indexation. In short, we find evidence for the importance of financial shocks in the business cycle. But the evidence also suggests that the effect of non-financial shocks on real activity is unaffected by the inclusion of financial forces in the model. That is, the results suggest the importance of financial shocks, but not the existence of a financial accelerator. This analysis thus implies that Bayesian estimation of financial models should include estimates of contract indexation. Empirical analyses that impose zero contract indexation likely distort both the source of business cycle shocks and their transmission mechanism. Appendix A A.1. Linearized system of equations
y^ t ¼
i yþ F h ^ αkt þ ð1 αÞL^ t y
ðA1Þ
ρ^ t ¼ w^ t þ L^ t k^ t
ðA2Þ
^t s^ t ¼ αρ^ t þ ð1 αÞw
ðA3Þ
β
π^ t ¼ λ^ t ¼
1 þ βιp
Et π^ t þ 1 þ
ιp
1 þ βιp
hβ eγ z
π^ t 1 þ
^
ð1 βξp Þð1 ξp Þ s^ t þ λ^ p;t ð1 þ βιp Þξp
e2γ z þ h β 2
^
ðA4Þ heγ z
^
Et ct þ 1 γ ct þ γ ct 1 ðeγz hβÞðeγ z hÞ ðe z hβ Þðeγ z hÞ ðe z hβÞðeγ z hÞ
hβeγ z ρz heγ z eγz hβρb ^ hβeγ z ρυ heγ z α ^t þ z b þ γ þ υ^ t t ðe z hβÞðeγz hÞ ðeγ z hβÞ ðeγ z hβÞðeγ z hÞ 1 α
λ^ t ¼ R^ t þ Et λ^ t þ 1 z^ t þ 1 π^ t þ 1
α υ^ t þ 1 1α
ρ^ t ¼ ϑu^ t
ðA6Þ ðA7Þ
α Et υ^ t þ 1 1α 1 1 q^ t ¼ μ^ t þ e2ðγ z þ γ ν Þ S″ ^it ^it 1 þ z^ t þ υ^ t βe2ðγz þ γ ν Þ S″Et ^it þ 1 ^it þ z^ t þ 1 þ υ^ t þ 1 1α 1α k Et r^ t þ 1 ¼ λ^ t Et λ^ t þ 1 þEt z^ t þ 1 þ
^ k^ t ¼ u^ t þ kt 1 z^ t
1 υ^ t 1α
ðA8Þ ðA9Þ
1 ^ ^ kt ¼ ð1 δÞe ðγ z þ γ ν Þ kt 1 z^ t υ^ t þ 1 ð1 δÞe ðγ z þ γ ν Þ ðμ^ t þ ^it Þ 1α ^t¼ w
ðA5Þ
1 β ð1 βξw Þð1 ξw Þ ιw ^ 1 þ βιw β ^ t 1 þ ^ t þ1
Et w πt 1 π^ t þ Et π^ t þ 1 w g^ w;t þ 1þβ 1þβ 1þβ 1þβ 1þβ 1 þ βιw ξw α 1 þ βι βρ ιw ^ 1 þ βιw βρν α w z^ zt 1 þ zt þ υ^ t 1 υ^ t þ λ^ w;t 1α 1α 1þβ 1þβ 1þβ
ðA10Þ
ðA11Þ
ðA12Þ
^ t ðψ L^ t þ b^ t λ^ t Þ g^ w;t ¼ w
ðA13Þ
n n n R^ t ¼ ρR R^ t 1 þ ð1 ρR Þ½ϕπ π^ t þ ϕx ðx^ t x^ t Þ þ ϕdx ½ðx^ t x^ t 1 Þ ðx^ t x^ t 1 Þ þ η^ mp;t
ðA14Þ
x^ t ¼ y^ t
ρk ^ y
ut
ðA15Þ
1 1 c i ρk y^ ¼ g^ þ c^ t þ ^it þ u^ t g t g t y y y
ðA16Þ
d r^ t ¼ R^ t Et π^ t þ 1
ðA17Þ
148
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149 k r^ t ¼ βe ðγ z þ γ ν Þ ð1 δÞq^ t þ ½1 β e ðγ z þ γ ν Þ ð1 δÞρ^ t q^ t 1
ðA18Þ
For the agency cost model, we replace (A8) with α k Et υ^ t þ 1 þ νðq^ t þ k^ t n^ t Þ þ σ^ t Et r^ t þ 1 ¼ λ^ t Et λ^ t þ 1 þ Et z^ t þ 1 þ 1α And add the following equations:
γ β
γ β
k l l n^ t ¼ κ ðr^ t r^ t Þ þ ðr^ t þ n^ t 1 Þ þ γκ
rp ^ k ðkt 1 þ q^ t 1 þ r^ t Þ z^ t
β
1 υ^ t þ η^ nw;t 1α
ðA80 Þ
l d k k r^ t ¼ r^ t 1 þ½1 þ θg ðχ k 1Þðr^ t Et 1 r^ t Þ
ðA19Þ ðA20Þ
A.2. The derivation of (A8) and (A20) The optimal contract can be expressed as 0 E t V t þ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ 0 V t þ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ ¼ Λt þ 1 g0 ðϖ t þ 1 Þ 0 Et Λt þ 1 g ðϖ t þ 1 Þ
κ t Et Rktþ 1 V t þ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ ¼ Et Λt þ 1 Rktþ 1
ðA21Þ
0
E t V t þ 1 f ðϖ t þ 1 Þ d R Et Λt þ 1 Et Λt þ 1 g 0 ðϖ t þ 1 Þ t
ðA22Þ
κt gðϖ t þ 1 Þ ¼ Rdt Et Λt þ 1 κ t 1
ðA23Þ
0
It is convenient to define Fðϖ t þ 1 Þ ðð f ðϖ t þ 1 ÞÞ=ðg 0 ðϖ t þ 1 ÞÞÞ, where Ψ ððϖ ss F 0 ðϖ ss ÞÞ=ðFðϖ ss ÞÞÞ4 0, by the second order condition. Linearizing (A21)-(A23) we have
Ψðϖ t þ 1 Et ϖ t þ 1 Þ ¼ ðλt þ 1 Et λt þ 1 Þ þ ðvt þ 1 Et vt þ 1 Þ
ðA24Þ
Et ðr^ t þ 1 r^ t Þ þ κ t ¼ ðΨ θf ÞEt ϖ t þ 1
ðA25Þ
k
d
k
d
Et ðr^ t þ 1 r^ t Þ ¼
1 κ θ E ϖ κ 1 t g t t þ 1
ðA26Þ 0
where θg ððϖ ss g 0 ðϖ ss ÞÞ=ðgðϖ ss ÞÞÞ, with 0 o θg o1, and θf ððϖ ss f ðϖ ss ÞÞ=ðf ðϖ ss ÞÞÞo 0. Solving (A25) and (A26) we have: Et ϖ t þ 1 ¼
κ 1 κ κ 1 ðΨ θf þ θg Þ t "
k d Et ðr^ t þ 1 r^ t Þ ¼
# ðΨ θf þ θg Þ κθg κ t νκ t ðκ 1ÞðΨ θf þ θg Þ
ðA27Þ
ðA28Þ
Using the definition of leverage and the deposit rate, (A28) is the same as (A8'). The linearized lender return and promised payment are given by: 1 l k r^ t þ 1 ¼ r^ t þ 1 þ θg ϖ t þ 1 κ ðA29Þ κ 1 t p k r^ t þ 1 ¼ r^ t þ 1 þ ϖ t þ 1
1 κ κ 1 t
ðA30Þ
Combining (A24) and (A30) we have: p r^ t ¼ r dt 1 þ
ð1 Θg Þ½1 νðκ 1Þ 1 1 κ t 1 þ ðr^ kt Et 1 r^ kt Þ þ ðλ^ t Et 1 λ^ t Þ ðv^ t Et 1 v^ t Þ Θg ðκ 1Þ Ψ Ψ
ðA31Þ
where from (18) we have 1
jþ1 k v^ t ¼ Et ∑ β ðΞκ^ t þ j þ r^ t þ j þ 1 Þ
ðA32Þ
j¼0
where Ξ ½1 þ ðβ =γ Þðν ð1=ðκ 1ÞÞÞ. For parsimony we will estimate a promised payment of the form p p k k r^ t ¼ Et 1 r^ t þ χ k ðr^ t Et 1 r^ t Þ
ðA33Þ
C.T. Carlstrom et al. / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 46 (2014) 130–149
149
Combining this with (A29) and (A30) we have: l d k k r^ t ¼ r^ t 1 þ½1 þ θg ðχ k 1Þðr^ t Et 1 r^ t Þ
ðA34Þ
This is just (A20). References Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1999. The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In: Taylor, J.B., Woodford, M. (Eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1C. , North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 1999. Carlstrom, C., Fuerst, T., 1997. Agency costs, net worth, ad business fluctuations: a computable general equilibrium analysis. Am. Econ. Rev. 87, 893–910. Carlstrom, C., Fuerst, T., Paustian, M., 2013. Privately optimal contracts and sub-optimal outcomes in a model of agency costs. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper, 12–39R. Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C., 2005. Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J. Polit. Econ. 113, 1–45. Christiano, L., Motto, R.,Rostagno, M., 2010. Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations, ECB Working Paper No. 1192 (May). Christiano, L., Motto, R., Rostagno, M., 2014. Risk shocks. Am. Econ. Rev. 104 (1), 27–65. DeGraeve, Ferre, 2008. The external finance premium and the macroeconomy: US post-WWII evidence. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 32, 3415–3440. Furlanetto, Francesco, Francesco Ravazzolo, and Samad Sarferaz, 2013. Identification of Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations, Working Paper (February). Gilchrist, S., Ortiz, A., Zakrajšek, E., 2009. Credit Risk And The Macroeconomy: Evidence From an Estimated DSGE Model. Mimeo, Boston University. Gomme, Paul, Ravikumar, B., Rupert, Peter, April 2011. The return to capital and the business cycle. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 14 (2), 262–278. Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G., Tambalotti, A., 2011. Investment shocks and the relative price of investment. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 14, 102–121. Shiller, R.J., Weiss, A.N., 1999. Home Equity Insurance. J. Real Estate Finance Econ. 19 (1), 21–47.