Accepted Manuscript Does “hot money” affect real economy? Evidence from production outputs in China
Yihao Zhang, Fang Chen, Jian Huang, Catherine Shenoy PII: DOI: Reference:
S0927-538X(18)30307-X doi:10.1016/j.pacfin.2018.09.006 PACFIN 1070
To appear in:
Pacific-Basin Finance Journal
Received date: Revised date: Accepted date:
31 May 2018 8 September 2018 21 September 2018
Please cite this article as: Yihao Zhang, Fang Chen, Jian Huang, Catherine Shenoy , Does “hot money” affect real economy? Evidence from production outputs in China. Pacfin (2018), doi:10.1016/j.pacfin.2018.09.006
This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Does “Hot Money” Affect Real Economy? Evidence from Production Outputs in China Yihao Zhanga, Fang Chenb, Jian Huangc, Catherine Shenoyd a.
School of Business, Nanjing University, Nanjing, Jiangsu, China 210093 College of Business, University of New Haven, West Haven, CT 06516 c. College of Business and Economics, Towson University, Towson, MD 21252 d. School of Business, University of Kansas, Lawrence, KS 66045
IP
T
b.
CR
Abstract
PT
ED
M
AN
US
Common wisdom generally associates hot money (short-term international capital) with macroeconomic risk originating from an economy’s financial sector, while its impact on the real economy is ignored. Using the Chinese data from 2000 to 2016, we document the pattern of hot money flows, and empirically examine the relation between hot money and industry, service and agriculture production outputs in China. We find the unidirectional causality from hot money to the industry output, and the bidirectional causality between hot money and the service output. Specifically, with a 1% increase in hot money inflow, there is a 0.29% increase in the industry output and a 0.25% increase in the service output. We further confirm that the short-run variation in hot money is the Granger cause of variation in the industry and service outputs. Moreover, the investigation of six capital-concentrated subsectors provides additional cross-sectional evidence of hot money’s heterogeneous effects. Overall, we provide the first piece of empirical evidence on the impact of short-term international capital on real production outputs in China, pointing to a significant microeconomic risk factor of escalated output volatility. These findings lend regulatory insights into risk management and capital control in China.
AC
CE
Key Words: short-term international capital flow; production output; risk management JEL Classification: F21
_____________________________________________________________________________________
Emails: Yihao Zhang,
[email protected]; Fang Chen,
[email protected]; Jian Huang,
[email protected]; Catherine Shenoy,
[email protected]. Other than the first author, the rest authors are listed alphabetically. The usual disclaimer applies.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
T
“Mass inflows of short-term capital are causing asset bubbles and currency appreciation in developing countries, which make macroeconomic policy difficult and raise the risk of future crises…” - Stephany Griffith-Jones and Kevin Gallagher, The Financial Times, December 17, 2010
IP
1. Introduction
CR
With its dramatic growth from only $82 billion in the early 1970s to a record $1,680 billion approaching the financial crisis in 2008, hot money is considered as a major
US
macroeconomic risk factor and is tightly linked with financial booms and crises in emerging
AN
economies (Chari and Kehoe, 2003). Hot money formally refers to the flow of speculative funds or capital across the border to earn a short-term profit by capitalizing on market differences. 1
M
With the development of financial innovation, hot money is changing into a professional
ED
speculative capital game characterized by high liquidity and secrecy. Particularly in China, the largest emerging economy, it is reported that starting from 2003,
PT
there has been a huge short-term capital inflow that cannot be explained by trade surplus or
CE
foreign direct investment (Prasad and Wei, 2005). The aggregate hot money that flowed into China from 2003 to the first quarter of 2008 surged to about 1.75 trillion dollars (Martin and
AC
Morrison, 2008). Then right after the global financial crisis of 2008, the hot money inflows had another sharp increase (Zhang and Huang, 2011). Moreover, hot money accounts for a large part of the foreign exchange reserves in China. A report published in 2016 by the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences shows the hot money that flowed into China from 2001 to the third quarter of
1
We exclude the regular capital flows due to normal trading or bank financing wh ich are strict ly regulated and accurately tracked in Ch ina. Our measure of short-term international capital flow specifically refers to the speculative capital flo w via varying open and unregulated channels. We thus use the terms of “hot money” and “short-term international capital (or STIC)” interchangeably in this article. More discussion is provided in Section 2. 1
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 2015 reached 2.79 trillion dollars, almost 70% the total foreign exchange reserves in China over the same period. The massive inflow of hot money has exposed emerging economies such as China to risks in the financial sectors, imposing inflation pressures, asset price bubbles, and increased
T
pressures on monetary policy operations and foreign exchange reserve management (Li et al.,
IP
2012). Recent studies have shown its impacts on asset pricing especially in the stock and real
CR
estate markets (Feng et al., 2017; Guo and Huang, 2010a; 2010b) and the exchange rate market in China (Lee et al., 2017). More severely, the volatile short-term capital flow has been
US
associated with financial crises in countries with weak economic fundamentals (Kaminsky and
AN
Reinhart, 1998). Specifically, the excess short-term capital flow can lead to a financial bubble. As the bubble fades and short-term capital leaves, economic panic may ensue, leading to a
M
financial crisis. Such a process has been observed during the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis,
ED
especially in Thailand, Indonesia, and South Korea. Despite the significant effect of hot money, its effect on the real economy is largely
PT
ignored mainly for the following two reasons. First, the common wisdom generally believes that
CE
hot money is restricted in the financial sectors of an economy, while only long-term international capital, especially foreign direct investments (FDI), is believed to increase the productivity of
AC
domestic firms (Bitzer and Gorg, 2009; Girma et al., 2001&2008; Javorcik, 2004; Keller and Yeaple, 2003; Markusen and Venables, 1999). These conjectures regarding the lack of hot money’s impact on the real production outputs have not been examined empirically or theoretically. Second, short-term international capital flow is difficult to measure in emerging economies due to government controls, low currency convertibility, regulatory evasion, and the diversity of channels for short-term capital flow.
2
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT To fill in the gap, this paper assesses the impact of short-term international capital (“hot money”) on real production outputs in China. According to Keynesians, short-term money supply induces changes in output. Our research question is: Does the short-term international capital flow influence production outputs? If so, is there any heterogeneity among its effects on
T
industry, agriculture, and service sectors? To the best of our knowledge, we provide the first
IP
piece of empirical evidence on the impact of short-term international capital on real production
CR
outputs in China.
To identify the channels for hot money to influence the output, we develop a derivation
US
from the C-D production model, in which hot money affects the output through the monetary
AN
supply mechanism. Based on the model and the theory that hot money can increase industry output by improving the domestic financial system of the recipient country and directly promote
M
productivity partly taking the form of FDI, we predict that the short-term international capital
ED
flow has a positive relation with industry, agriculture and service outputs. We first conduct a unit root test and find that the hot money and the output variables are
PT
stationary at their first differences. Next, the Granger causality test shows evidence of
CE
unidirectional causality from short-term international capital flow to industry output, and bidirectional causality between short-term international capital flow and the service output. By
AC
contrast, the result shows no causality between short-term international capital flow and agriculture output. Further, we run the Johansen cointegration relationship test to confirm that the short-term international capital flow has comovement with the industry output as well as service output. It is noteworthy that with a 1% increase in hot money inflow, there is a 0.29% increase in the industry output, while only a 0.25% increase in the service output. With the Vector Error
3
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Correction Model (VECM) test, we find that the short-run variation in the short-term international capital is the Granger cause of variation in the industry and service outputs. A relevant question is whether there are heterogeneous impacts of hot money on the outputs across the subsectors. We repeat the Granger causality test, Johansen cointegration
T
relation test and the VECM test for six capital-concentrated subsectors: banking, energy,
IP
chemical engineering, nonferrous metal, steel, and construction materials. The results indicate
CR
the bidirectional causality between short-term international capital flow and the banking industry output, and the unidirectional causality from short-term international capital flow to the
US
nonferrous metal industry output and to the energy industry. The Johansen cointegration further
AN
reveals that short-term international capital flow has a negative comovement with the banking output, and a positive comovement with the nonferrous metal and energy outputs. The VECM
M
test shows that the short-term international capital flow negatively influence s the banking output
ED
adjustment in the short run but not the nonferrous metal and energy outputs. While the existing research on the short-term international capital concentrates on the
PT
impacts of hot money on financial market (e.g., Guichard, 2017; Larry, 2004; McKinnon and
CE
Huw, 1996), our study extends this stream of research by identifying the relation between hot money and the outputs of the economic sectors –- industry, service, and agriculture, and by
AC
providing possible channels through which hot money affects the real economy. Further, our findings provide regulatory insights into risk management and capital control from the microeconomic perspective. The excessive liquidity, inflation aggravation, asset bubbles, and a cyclical rise in bank loans induced by hot money inflow and the financial vulnerabilities and crises led by hot money outflow, all contribute to macroeconomic risk to recipient countries. Our focus on the relationship of short-term international capital flows and
4
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT real economy belongs to a microeconomic risk of escalated output volatility. This provides evidence for the capital control in China from a different perspective, and corresponds to Griffith-Jones and Gallagher’s call for “curbing hot capital flows to protect the real economy” as early as 2010. These findings also lend support to the Chinese government’s efforts in coping
T
with the capital outflow when “hot money cools on China (Curran et al., 2015).” Finally, by
IP
proposing an ad hoc model on the monetary supply channel and raising the possible mechanisms
CR
via which hot money can affect the real production outputs, we provide further insights into how to put capital control in place to govern capital flows into and out of China, and to minimize its
US
impact on the real production outputs.
AN
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews the literature on international capital flow, and develops our hypothesis regarding the link between STIC and
ED
M
production outputs. We present empirical evidence in Section 3 and conclude in Section 4.
2. Literature Review and Background Long-term international capital
PT
2.1.
CE
The existing literature differs in their way of gauging international capital. The first stream of literature does not differentiate short-term and long-term international capital, and
AC
examines the motivation and impact of international capital flow on recipient economies using the lumped international capital. On one hand, the positive economic effects hypothesis posits that the international capital flow promotes economic development, through the reduction of capital costs (Henry, 2000), technology spillover (Feldstein, 2000), the increase of domestic deposits (Mishra et al, 2001), and the acceleration of domestic financial innovations (Claessens
5
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT et al., 2001). The economic effect is more obvious in industrial countries than in non-industrial countries due to their differing abilities to absorb foreign capital (Prasad et al, 2006). On the other hand, the negative economic effects hypothesis posits that economies are more prone to overheating and even financial crises. Too much capital may overheat the
T
economy via channels such as monetary expansion and inflation pressure (Larry, 2004),
IP
domestic currency appreciation and deteriorating terms of trade (Athukorala and Rajapatirana,
CR
2003), and a negative effect on aggregate demand (Celasun et al, 1999). Consequently, excess capital inflow might make the financial system fragile (Mckinnon and Pill, 1996), and prone to
US
the financial crisis (Calvo, 1998). These effects can be especially amplified, where poor
AN
corporate governance and financial regulation allow corporates and banks to take excessive risks and expand through international leverage (Guichard, 2017; Lane, 2015).
M
This stream of literature has also been devoted to disentangling global factors (such as
ED
global risk aversion, global liquidity, interest rates, or growth in advanced economies) from local factors in receiving countries (such as domestic macroeconomic fundamentals and s tructural
PT
policy settings) (Avdjiev et al., 2017; Eichengreen et al., 2017; Guichard, 2017; Koepke, 2015).
CE
For example, Avdjiev et al. (2017) split gross debt inflows by the recipient sector (government, the central bank, banks, and NFCs), and find that the impact of global risk aversion varies with
AC
the borrowing sectors and the type of countries. They show that when risk aversion increases, foreign capital borrowed by banks and NFCs in both advanced and emerging economies and by sovereigns in EMEs declines, but that debt inflows to advanced economies and sovereigns increase. Eichengreen et al. (2017) find that, as with non-FDI inflows, non-FDI outflows respond negatively to increases in global risk aversion and that FDI outflows from emerging markets also respond negatively to increases in global risk aversion while FDI inflows into emerging markets
6
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT are mostly driven by pull factors. They also show that the sensitivity of outflows from EMEs to global risk aversion has increased over time. The second stream of literature differentiates long-term international capital from the short-term capital, and particularly focuses on the impact of FDIs on economic development and
T
industrial output. Many theoretical studies on the FDI-productivity link are not conclusive. On
IP
the one hand, theories suggest that host productivity may be promoted by FDIs through linkages,
CR
imitation, new products or processes, technology spillover and worker training (Grossman and Helpman, 1991; Kokko, 1992; Markusen and Venables, 1999; Romer, 1990). On the other hand,
US
it is suggested that host productivity may not benefit from FDI, since multinational corporations
AN
may restrict diffusion of technology, especially advanced ones, to their subsidiaries abroad by reducing linkage effects or keeping skills and know-how a secret (Caves, 1996; Das, 1987; and
M
Teece, 1977). Bitzer and Gorg (2009) investigate the productivity effects of inward and outward
ED
FDI using industry-and country- level data for 17 OECD countries over the period 1973 to 2001. Their results show that there are productivity benefits from inward FDI, but outward FDI is
PT
negatively related to productivity. Urata and Kawai (2000) find that labor costs, infrastructure,
CE
and industry clustering are key determinants of FDI for small and medium-sized Japanese firms. In the context of China, attracted by the increase in both the volume and volatility of
AC
China’s international capital flows, recent long-term international capital literature identifies the relation of FDI with industrial output in China. Zhao and Zhang (2010) posit that FDI has positive direct and spillover effects on China’s industrial productivity level and growth, and the contribution of FDI to productivity is enhanced by its interaction with China’s human capital. While labor- intensive industries benefit more from FDI direct effects, capital- intensive industries gain more from FDI spillover effects. Along the same line, Li and Qi (2016) measure the
7
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT magnitude and direction of the different effects on the path of FDI and document a negative FDI scale effect, a negative FDI composition effect, and a positive FDI technique effect. Zhang (2014) suggests that FDI has large positive effects on China's industrial performance; such effects are much greater on low-tech manufacturing than medium and high-tech industries, and
T
the contribution is enhanced by FDI’s interaction with local human capital. All of the above
IP
results support the FDI-industry nexus in China like other emerging markets, such as Mauritius,
Short-term international capital (hot money)
US
2.2.
CR
India, and Nigeria (Fauzel et al., 2015; Kumar and Dehradun, 2016).
AN
Although China has adopted various measures to restrict volatile international short-term capital flows that are speculative in nature, investors continue to circumvent Chinese laws and
M
regulations (Guo and Huang, 2010a; 2010b). Consequently, China is not isolated from hot
ED
money inflows as capital controls cannot reach all capital account transaction categories and several of these categories are loosely managed (Xie, 2004). The hot money usually takes
PT
advantage of varying open and unregulated channels, such as cargo trade, service trade, and
CE
direct investments. The violators cover up their illegal purposes with seemingly legal transactions, breaking or sidestepping the regulations as necessary, in their chameleon channels
AC
which can be summarized as follows. The first transmission channel of hot money is through the trad ing. This channel conveniently allows hot money to enter by reporting fraudulently high export prices and low import prices, providing advance export payments and entrepôt trade. For example, Zhang and Huang (2011) find that most short-term capital flows into China are via illegal channels such as misinvoicing in the trade transaction.
8
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT The second is through highly organized underground banks. The underground banks transfer hot money into or out of foreign countries through foreign currency cash smuggling across country borders, personal foreign exchange transactions, non-resident foreign exchange settlement, and financial institutions’ business transactions.
T
The third transmission channel of hot money is through fraudulent foreign investment.
IP
For example, Martin and Morrison (2008) find that more than half of the hot money flowed into
CR
China takes the form of over-reported or forged FDIs. The methods for overseas hot money to flow into and out of China under the guise of foreign investments are diversifying daily. The
US
main forms of transmission used by foreign- invested enterprises include transfer pricing, false
AN
profit reporting, short-term foreign debt financing, and fraudulent domestic enterprise financing. Next, we discuss the hot money’s impact on macroeconomic risk globally and
M
domestically. Chari and Kehoe (2003) find that economic booms and crises in emerging
ED
economies are tightly linked to hot money flows. Similarly, McKinnon (2014) points out that hot money has a first-order impact on global financial stability while waves of hot money crowd into
PT
Emerging Markets (EM) with convertible currencies. When each EM central bank intervenes to
CE
prevent its individual currency from appreciating, collectively they lose monetary control, inflate, and cause an upsurge in primary commodity prices internationally. When the good times roll in
AC
the economy, speculators and investors can make whopping profit margins. For example, Ferreira and Matos (2008) suggest that foreign institutional investors are more prone to chase shares with recent positive stock return performance in “hot” markets. However, when the outflow of hot money begins and the asset bubble bursts, the effect can be devastating, and the entire economy can be destabilized. Although the inflow of hot money builds up gradually over time, the outflow tends to occur simultaneously, with each
9
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT player struggling to be the first to exit (Domowitz et al., 1997). As a good example, Sarno and Taylor (1999) show that a sudden capital outflow was a major factor in the 1997 East Asian financial crisis. The massive flow of hot money brings dramatic impacts to China too. The speculative
T
capital inflows to China have fueled inflation, driven up stock prices, and accelerated a
IP
worrisome bubble in the real estate market (Guo and Huang, 2010a; 2010b). Wang et al. (2017)
CR
further explain that the relation between short-term international capital inflows and asset prices is self- fulfilling and mutually reinforcing. The unsterilized portion of the monetary base further
US
exacerbates asset price bubbles, which suggests that short-term international capital inflows and
AN
excess liquidity gradually escalate the severity of asset price bubbles. Further, hot money also increases the fluctuation in business cycles in China. Guo and
M
Huang (2010a;2010b) document a considerable degree of long-run cointegration and
ED
bidirectional causality effects between hot money and business cycle volatility. The liquidity shock stemming from hot money is shown to be the primary factor responsible for the
PT
significantly enhanced fluctuation in business cycles during the most recent global financial
CE
crisis period. A similar effect has been documented in Malaysia, Thailand, and Singapore (see,
2.3.
AC
for example, Yang and Hamori, 2016).
Hot money and production outputs As shown in the previous sections, relevant studies either focus on long-term
international capital or the impacts of hot money on asset prices, especially stock and house prices in China (Feng et al., 2017; Guo and Huang, 2010a; 2010b; Lee et al., 2017). Little is known about hot money’s impact on the real economy in China. With its impact on monetary
10
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT supply, short-term international capital flow can play a significant role in the real economy. Yang and Liu (2011) apply a monetary supply model with the international capital flow to the reform of the foreign exchange system in China and investigate the influence of international capital flow on monetary supply. However, they do not distinguish long-term capital flow from
T
short-term capital flow or “hot money.” According to Keynesians, short-term money supply
IP
induces changes in output (e.g., Blanchard, 1987). International empirical evidence supports the
CR
view that hot money affects money supply. For example, Fuertes et al. (2016) examine hot money and bank credit in 18 emerging markets during 1988-2012 and reveal that hot money has
US
gained importance as a way of financing relative to bank credit during the 2000s.
AN
To formally establish the link between hot money and production output via the mechanism of monetary supply, we set up an ad hoc model to explain this mechanism and derive
M
our prediction. The flow chart of the mechanism is provided as follows (see the Appendix for a
ED
full description of the model).
1) STIC inflows into China which is a fixed exchange regime country. 2) The Chinese central bank intervenes in the foreign exchange market, and increases
CE
monetary supply.
PT
→
3) Interest rate drops and bank credit becomes more available.
→
4) Production outputs in the real economy increase.
AC
→
Derived from the ad hoc model, when short-term international capital inflow in previous periods increases, industry output at period t increases. Besides the above model-derived “monetary supply mechanism,” there are other possible mechanisms. First, hot money can improve the domestic financial system of the recipient country, which in turn increases production output. For example, Levine (2001) finds that international
11
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT capital flows promote international financial integration, economic development, and industry output by encouraging improvements in the domestic financial system such as the banking system. Second, hot money, which partly takes the form of FDI, can directly promote productivity. There is much literature on the well-established FDI-productivity link. For example,
T
using an extensive dataset, Kose et al. (2009) examine the link between productivity and
IP
financial openness for a large sample of countries. Specific ally, they find that FDI and portfolio
CR
equity liabilities boost productivity growth (measured by TFP) while external debt is negatively correlated with TFP growth. All the above mechanisms point to a positive link between hot
US
money and production outputs.
AN
In the next section, we empirically test the conjecture derived from the above discussion and further investigate whether the impact of hot money is heterogeneous across the three major
3. Data and Empirical Tests Data
PT
3.1.
ED
M
sectors.
CE
We use quarterly data from the WIND database, a leading financial database provider in China (www.wind.com.cn). Our sample consists of 68 quarterly observations of short-term
AC
international capital balances and industrial, agriculture and services output from the first quarter of 2000 to the fourth quarter of 2016.
3.1.1. Short-term international capital balance It is difficult to measure the short-term international capital balance in China due to government controls, low currency convertibility, regulatory evasion, and the diversity of
12
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT channels for short-term capital flow (Zhang et al., 2007). Hot money flows are often mixed or concealed in current account as imports, exports, or other international trade because the Chinese government imposes strict capital account controls and looser current account controls (Guo and Huang, 2010a; 2010b). Hot money cannot easily flow in or out of China through investment or
T
other financial channels (Feng et al., 2017). While it is difficult to get an accurate measure of hot
IP
money flow due to its complexity and secrecy, we can estimate its size. There are three
CR
estimation methods: direct computation (Cuddington, 1986; Kant, 1996), foreign reserve income
US
estimation (Cline, 1987), and computation based on abnormal trade surplus (Dooley, 1986). The direct computation uses the balance of payments and is defined as:
AN
Short-term International Capital Inflow = Net Errors & Omission in Balance of International Payments + Short-term Capital Inflow in Non-bank Private Sector + Short-term Capital Inflow
M
through Other Normal Channels
(1).
FDI and actual trade surplus.
ED
The Chinese Statistics Bureau modified this method in 2006 by using new reserves minus
PT
The foreign reserve income estimation method adds the capital gain or loss induced by
CE
foreign reserve income and currency changes to the direct computation method. It is defined as: Short-term International Capital Inflow = New Foreign Currency Reserve – Capital Gains or
AC
Losses of Reserves – Earnings – (Net Export + FDI)
(2).
The foreign reserve income estimation method is mainly based on the trade surplus, earnings, and the size of FDI. If the domestic trade surplus increases sharply, a large amount of hot money flows into China through seemingly “legal” channels. We assume the trade surplus would not have increased without a large amount of short-term international capital, but would rather have increased at a normalized pace. Based on monthly data, Zhang and Shen (2008)
13
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT modified the State Statistics Bureau method by omitting the concealed short-term international capital inflow in actual trade surplus. Because of these concerns, we modify the method of calculating short-term international capital flow (Zhang and Shen, 2008). We develop the following method: STICt = STICt-1 + ΔSTICt
T
(3),
CR
international capital balance at the end of the quarter.
IP
where STICt is the short-term international capital net stock in month t, defined as the short-term
ΔSTICt = (ΔForeign Exchange Reservet - FDIt –Trade Surplust – Foreign Exchange Reserve
US
Proceedst ) × Nominal RMB/$
(5),
AN
ΔForeign Exchange Reservet = Foreign Exchange Reservet – Foreign Exchange Reservet-1
(4).
where Trade Surplust is the weighted moving average of foreign trade surplus in the previous 12
M
months.
ED
Zhang and Shen (2008) use a moving average, and this paper improves their method by using weighted moving average with the weight of 1.15. We estimate monthly trading surp lus for
PT
2001 to 2004 as the moving average of trade surpluses in the previous 12 months. We divide the
weights.2 Thus,
CE
corresponding actual trading surplus by the estimates and use the average of these ratios as
AC
Foreign Exchange Reserve Proceedst = Foreign Exchange Reservet-1 × (Annualized Foreign Exchange Reserve Proceeds Rate)/12
(6).
Figure 1 shows the short-term international capital (STIC) during the first quarter of 2000
2
Short-term international cap ital flow is more much volatile than long -term flow. Consequently, it is much harder for domestic countries to respond to and deal with the short-term cap ital flo w. Based on this attribute of capital flows and the focus of this study, Function (2) emphasizes the effect of short-term international cap ital flow on h ighpowered money, and puts the effect of long-term capital flow together with other factors into Ct.
14
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT through the fourth quarter of 2016. The STIC balance changes are consistent with the development of the Chinese economy and the global economy. During 2000-2010, STIC flowed into China aggressively, due to global factors such as the global financial crisis, and the domestic issues such as RMB appreciation, real estate property price surging, state-owned enterprise
T
restructuring, and loose capital controls in China. After 2010, STIC inflow slowed down or even
IP
reversed, due to the reasons such as the volatile stock/real estate/currency markets, and the
CR
shrinking arbitrage opportunities from the state-owned enterprise restructuring in China. --Insert Figure 1 here--
US
The long-term international capital balance (FDI) from the first quarter of 2000 through
AN
the fourth quarter of 2016 is shown in Figure 2. There is a sustainable increase in the long-term international capital balance. Comparing Figure 1 with Figure 2, short-term international capital
M
is more volatile.
PT
3.1.2. Production output
ED
--Insert Figure 2 here--
CE
Following the classification method provided by the WIND database, we use the industrial, agriculture and services sectors in our analysis. Since there is strong seasonality in the
AC
sector outputs, we produce seasonally adjusted series using the X12 seasonal adjustment procedure (Pakko, 2008). Figure 3 shows the sector outputs are an increasing trend during the period of 2000 to 2016. --Insert Figure 3 here-Within the industry sector, we further examine five subsectors: energy, chemical
15
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT engineering, nonferrous metal, steel, and building materials. 3 They are also the major sectors in the Chinese State Council’s Industrial Revitalization Plan. 4 Within the service industry, we select the banking subsector. These six subsectors are characterized by high capital concentrations. For the proxies of the subsector outputs, we use bank loan balance for banking, coal
T
output for energy, ethane output for chemical engineering, aluminum output for the nonferrous
IP
metals, steel output for steel, and cement output for building materials. Figure 4 shows the
CR
increasing trend of the seasonally-adjusted outputs of the six subsectors from 2000 to 2016. --Insert Figure 4 here--
US
We list the definition of the variables in Table 1 and provide the descriptive statistics and
AN
correlation of the variables in Table 2 and Table 3 respectively.
--Insert Tables 1-3 here--
M
In Table 2, we show that service has the largest output, followed by industry, and
Empirical tests
PT
3.2.
ED
agriculture output is the lowest among all three sectors.
CE
First, we test all variables for time series stationarity with unit root tests using an augmented Dickey-Fuller test (ADF). The variables include STIC, industry output, agriculture
AC
output, service output, steel output, loan output, coal output, ethane output, aluminum output,
3
The output from these six subsectors accounts for more than 30% o f the production output. Moreover, since the end of 2008, the Chinese State Council started a stimulus package including Industrial Revitalizat ion Planning. The plan covers logistics and nine industries: text ile, steel, auto, shipping, equipment manufact uring, electronic informat ion, light manufacturing, petrochemicals, and nonferrous metal. Statistics show that the added value of these nine industries accounts for 90% of the total national industrial added value, and 1/3 of GDP. 4 The standard classification of industries can be grouped into two systems. The first classification system serves the purpose of management, which is based on internal structure and development condition of the national economy. Examples are ISIC (UN), NAICS (North A merica), and GB/T4754-2002 (P.R. Ch ina). The second system is for the purpose of investment, which includes investment analysis, performance evaluation, and allocation of assets such as Global Industries Classificat ion Standard (GICS), FTSE. The classification system used in this study, WIND, is designed based on GICS, and modified slightly to match China’s actual condition. 16
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT and cement output. The results are shown in Table 4. For all the variables, the ADF test shows that all variables are found to be non-stationary at levels but stationary at their first differences, implying the first-order differences cointegration and Granger causality. We will employ the first-order differences in the following cointegration and Granger causality test to meet their
IP
CR
--Insert Table 4 here--
T
stationarity requirement.
3.2.1. Granger causality test for the relation between short-term international capital and
US
sector outputs
AN
Next, we use Granger causality, a well-known test for bivariate, to test the influence of the past of one time series on the present and future of another time series (Hiemstra and Jones,
M
1994). Specifically, a standard join test (F-test) is used to determine whether lagged Y has
PT
result is presented in Table 5.
ED
significant linear predictive power for current X in a test of the relation between Y and X. The
--Insert Table 5 here--
CE
Focusing on rejections of the null hypothesis that there is no Granger causality at the 5% significant level, the Granger tests show evidence of unidirectional causality from short-term
AC
international capital flow to the industry output. Moreover, the result indicates bidirectional causality between short-term international capital flow and the service output. In contrast, the result shows no causality between short-term international capital flow and agriculture output. Therefore, the following tests will focus on the impact of short-term international capital flow on industry and service sectors only.
17
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 3.2.2. Cointegration test for short-term international capital and sector outputs Since the test in Section 3.2.1 shows the causality between short-term international capital and the industry and service outputs, we further use the Johansen cointegration test to examine the long-run relationship between short-term international capital and the industry and
T
service outputs. The test results are sensitive to the lag length chosen. We select the number of
IP
lags based on the Pantula criteria (Pantula et al., 1994). When the selection cannot be made by
CR
AIC or SC, we apply L.R. statistic (Neyman-Pearson). Based on the above criteria, we construct three VAR (1) models to test the cointegration relations between STIC (short-term international
US
capital) flow and Y (Industrial, Agriculture or Service), respectively.
(7),
AN
𝑌𝑖,𝑡 = 𝐶 + 𝛼𝑌𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝛽𝑆𝑇𝐼𝐶𝑡−1 + 𝜖
where Y is the output, i = sector (industry, agriculture, or service), C is a constant, and ε is the
M
residual.
ED
The results of the Johansen cointegration test are shown in Table 6. The test result shows
PT
that there is a cointegration relation between STIC and the industrial output, as well as a cointegration relationship between STIC and the Service sector. The results imply that the short-
--Insert Table 6 here—
AC
CE
term international capital flow contributes to both the industry output and the service output.
The cointegration equation shows that the magnitude of the contribution of STIC to the industry output is larger than that of the service sector. Specifically, with a 1% increase in hot money inflow, there is a 0.29% increase in the industry output, while only a 0.25% increase in the service outputs. Thus, STIC has the strongest effect in the industry sector, possibly indicating that hot money flows into the industry sector more than either the service sector or the agriculture sector.
18
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT The regulation and productivity can explain the flow of hot money. First, due to the strict capital control in China, hot money inflow is commonly mixed with trading and FDI items which are mostly related to manufacturing. Further, the service sector, especially the finance industry, is highly regulated, while the Chinese government encourages the marketization of the industrial
T
sector, attracting hot money into relevant industries. Finally, the productivity in the industry
IP
sector is the highest among all the three sectors and the productivity is positively related to the
CR
return on investment. For example, Li et al. (2012) finds that the productivity is RMB 15,268.8/per capita, RMB 11,300.7/per capita, and RMB 2,485.2/per capita in the industry,
AN
US
service, and agriculture sectors, respectively.
3.2.3. VECM test for short-term international capital and sector outputs
M
Engle and Granger (1987) indicate that an error-correction representation always exists in
ED
the presence of cointegration. Since variables STIC and the industry and services output move together in the long run, we further run Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) to examine the
PT
impact of the hot money on the short-term industry and service output adjustment.
CE
The VECM model used is:
Yi ,t ECM t 1 Yi ,t 1 STICt 1 C
(8),
AC
where i=sector (industry or service), C is the constant, and is the random error term. The dependent variable of the VECM is expressed regarding the first difference. The right- hand side of each equation includes a one-period lagged output first difference and a one-period lagged STIC first difference. The coefficient of error correction term (EC T) is derived from the long run cointegration relationship and reflects the adjustment speed as the output variables return to their long-term values after a shock. The one-period lagged variables are the indication of the short-
19
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT term causal effects (Masih and Masih, 1999). The result is presented in Table 7. The coefficient of ECT is -0.01 for the industry output and 0.002 for the service output. Both are statistically significant at the 5% level. The small magnitude of coefficients of ECT implies a slow self-adjustment from the long run cointegration
T
relationship. The coefficient of a one-period lagged STIC first difference is 0.05 for the industry
IP
output and 0.03 for the service output. Both are statistically significant, suggesting that short-run
CR
variation in the short-term international capital is the Granger cause of variation in the industry and service outputs.
US
--Insert Table 7 here--
AN
We further conduct variance decomposition of STIC on the outputs in an attempt to gauge to what extent shocks to certain outputs are explained by its innovations and STIC.
M
Consistently, we use the first-order difference for STIC, industry output and service output. The
ED
result is presented in Table 8. For the industry output, the explanatory power of the variance of STIC on that of the industry output increases over time, peaking at the 10th period when the
--Insert Table 8 here--
CE
PT
variance of STIC accounts for 16.79% of the variance of industry output.
For the service output, the explanatory power of the variance of STIC on that of the
AC
service output first increases over time, peaking at the 6th period, and then decreases. In the 6 th period, the variance of STIC accounts for 9.29% of the variance of industry output. We use impulse response analysis to examine the speed of adjustment of industry and service outputs to long-run equilibrium following a shock in STIC, which is another indicator to gauge the impact of STIC on the outputs. The result is presented in Figure 5. The result shows that STIC affects both industry and service outputs differently. Specifically, the impact of STIC
20
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT on the industry output increases and peaks during the second period, while the impact of STIC on the service output peaks in the second period and the eighth period. --Insert Figure 5 here--
T
3.2.4. Short-term international capital and subsector outputs
IP
To further investigate the heterogeneous impact of hot money, we repeat the Granger
CR
causality test, the cointegration relation test, and the VECM test for six capital- intensive subsectors: banking, energy, chemical engineering, nonferrous metal, steel, and building
US
materials, which are believed to be sensitive to capital inflows.
AN
The Granger test for the subsectors is presented in Table 9 Panel A. The result indicates bidirectional causality between short-term international capital flow and the bank ing industry
M
output (loan). Also, the results show evidence of unidirectional causality from short-term
ED
international capital flow to nonferrous metal industry output (aluminum) and energy industry
PT
output (coal).
--Insert Table 9 here--
CE
The Johansen cointegration tests of three subsectors with the Ganger causality with the short-term international capital flow are shown in Table 9 Panel B. The result confirms that there
AC
is a statistically significant cointegration relation between STIC and output in the banking, nonferrous metal, and energy subsectors. Specifically, STIC flow has a negative comovement with the banking output and a positive comovement with the nonferrous metal and energy output. We apply a Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) to examine the contribution of the short-term international capital flow to the adjustment speed of three subsector outputs. The result is reported in Table 9 Panel C. The coefficient of one-period-lagged STIC for the banking
21
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT (loan) is -1.37 and significant at the 1% level, implying that the short-term international capital flow negatively influences the banking output in the short run. We do not find such impact of the short-term international capital flow on the nonferrous metal (aluminum) and energy output (coal).
T
Finally, we examine the pattern of the impact of STIC on the banking, nonferrous metal
IP
and energy subsector outputs following a shock in STIC. The results are presented in Figure 6.
CR
The result shows that STIC affects the banking (loan) most in the first period and energy (coal) outputs in the third period. For nonferrous metal (aluminum) outputs, the strongest effect from
US
STIC shock is in the second period and the tenth period.
AN
--Insert Figure 6 here--
M
4. Conclusion and Risk Management Implications
ED
The dramatic flows of hot money into and out of emerging economies have exposed these financial systems to vulnerability and the possibility of financial crises. While common wisdom
PT
generally associates hot money with macroeconomic risk originating from an economy’s
CE
financial sector, we propose and empirically document the impact of hot money on the real economy in China. Specifically, we document the unidirectional causality from hot money to the
AC
industry output, and the bidirectional causality between hot money and the service output, while we do not find that such effects exist in the agriculture sector. Further investigation of six capital- intensive subsectors provides cross-sectional evidence of hot money’s heterogeneous effects. These findings have meaningful policy implications for risk management in China given that the scale of rapidly growing short-term international capital outflow has reached $1 trillion
22
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT U.S. dollars in the recent two years. 5 This is in sharp contrast with the rapid growth of hot money before 2010. Based on the positive link between hot money and production outputs documented in this study, the observed pattern of sharp increase/decrease of hot money can escalate microeconomics risks and induce greater production output volatility followed by an economic
T
recession. Because the annual growth rate of China’s GDP has fallen to 6.9% in 2017 from 9.6%
CR
international capital (“hot money”) flows as follows.
IP
in 2007, it is critical for China’s policymakers to take precautions against the risk of short-term
First, Chinese authorities (e.g., State Administration of Foreign Exchange, or SAFE)
US
should adopt differentiated capital flow management policies. On the one hand, greater attention
AN
should be paid to the dynamics of speculative capital flows as they are volatile and, therefore, susceptible to a sudden stop and reversal. For example, more systemic reforms can be put in
M
place to eliminate distortions and motives for speculative capital flows. Macro-prudential
ED
policies and proactive financial supervisory oversight should be put in place to safeguard against the increasing volatility of international capital flows. 6 On the other hand, policymakers can
PT
continue to cultivate the incentives that have helped to attract FDI which is believed to be long-
CE
term oriented and thus more stable.
Relatedly, although Prasad and Wei (2005) suggest that China should move towards
AC
greater exchange rate flexibility to deal with domestic and external shocks, the capital account liberalization in China should be implemented cautiously and gradually, due to the weaknesses in the domestic financial system.
5
Between June 2014 and January 2017, Ch ina’s foreign exchange reserves have fell by 25% fro m $3.9932 trillion to $2.9982 trillion. The main reason is the net excessive outflow o f short-term international cap ital fro m China with shrinking arbitrage opportunities. 6 Macro-prudential policies are much wider than capital flow management (CFM ) measures as they include measures to reduce financial instability not all linked to international capital flo ws (Claessens, 2014; Guichard, 2017). 23
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Finally, as one of the largest economies, China also needs to pay close attention to its policies’ international spillover effect, and actively take responsibility for international cooperation and coordination of policies. The collaboration can aim to deal with international speculative capital, including efforts in the three main areas as proposed by Giordani et al.
T
(2014): a) monetary policy, b) capital control management and more broadly financial policies,
IP
and c) the global financial safety net (GFSN). Similarly, on the international level, to better
CR
preserve financial and exchange rate stability, the big four central banks–-Fed, ECB, Bank of England, and Bank of Japan–-can consider moving jointly to phase in a common minimum target
US
for their basic short-term interbank rates.
AN
Overall, large fluctuations in China’s capital flows can be detrimental to its international trade and the smooth operation of financial markets. However, given that China runs a strict
M
financial management system, chances that massive movement of hot money will induce a
ED
financial crisis are rather slim. Regardless, it is critical for policy- makers to take precautions
AC
CE
PT
against the speculative factors in their future policy decisions.
24
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Appendix: Model of the relation between short-term international flow and production outputs The exchange rate regime will affect the monetary consequences of the international capital inflows. In most models, consumption and investment booms will be accompanied by a
T
rise in money demand. In a small open economy operating under a free float, capital inflows will
IP
be associated with a nominal exchange rate appreciation and no change in either reserves or the
CR
monetary aggregates. Under a fixed exchange rate regime, money market equilibrium will be achieved via an accumulation of international reserves at the central bank and arise in the money
US
supply. For intermediate cases, the degree of monetary expansion following a rise in capital
AN
inflows will be smaller to the extent that the inflows are sterilized, or that the nominal exchange rate is allowed to appreciate ( Calvo et al., 1996).7
M
China’s fixed or band foreign exchange regime and high costs are associated with
ED
sterilized intervention result in the positive influence of international capital inflow on the monetary supply of the People's Bank of China (Zhang et al., 2007). Via the channel of monetary
PT
supply, we set up an ad hoc model to derive our prediction that when short-term international
CE
capital flow (STIC) in previous periods increases, industry output at period t increases. The model is to derive a mechanism to explain the influence of short-term international
AC
capital flow (STIC) on industry output. According to the multiplier theory of monetary supply, if short-term monetary supply, M2, is exogenous, then monetary supply is determined by base
7
Calvo et al. (1996) present the most important aspects of the largest recipients of capital inflows in Asia and Latin America, including Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colo mbia, Indonesia, Malaysia, Mexico, Ph ilippines and Thailand. They find six effects of capital inflows on other key economic variab les: First, a substantial portion of the surge in capital inflows has been channeled to the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves. Second, in most countries the capital inflo ws have been associated with widening current account deficits. Third, as one would expect fro m the fall in national saving, there has been a rise in private consumption spending. Fourth, in almost all th e countries examined there is rap id gro wth in the money supply in both nominal and real terms. Fifth, the surge in portfolio flows to the Asian and Lat in A merican countries was accompanied by sharp increases in stock and real estate prices. Sixth, the evidence on the behavior of the real exchange rate presents a mixed picture. 25
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT money supply, H, and a monetary multiplier, λ. Broadly-defined monetary supply at time t, is
M 2t * Ht a , for 0
(9),
where M 2t is short-term monetary supply at time t, and H t a is base monetary supply at time (ta). We assume, in a country with fixed exchange rates, the change in short-term international
IP
T
capital, STIC, is the inflow and outflow of short-term international capital. This change induces a
Ht STICt Ct
CR
variation of the monetary base, H.
(10),
US
where C is all other factors influencing the monetary base, including long-term international capital flow.
AN
Using Equation (10) in Equation (9), we obtain:
(11).
M
M 2t *(STICt a Ct a )
ED
The real interest rate, i, is the cost of capital. We assume the interest rate is mainly influenced by monetary supply. Equation (12) shows the relation:
M2
(12),
, and θ is a constant and θ>0.
CE
where f ( M 2)
PT
it f (M 2t b ) , f (M 2 ) 0
AC
We use a Cobb-Douglas production function to examine production output, Y. Production output can be written as:
Yt AKt L , 0 , 0 , + =1
(13),
where A is technological capability, K is capital stock, L is labor, and α and β are constants. We assume A and L are constant in the short term. The capital stock of a country at period t, Kt, is determined by capital stock Kt-1 , investment It, and depreciation Kt 1 , where η is depreciation rate. Kt is shown as: 26
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Kt (1 ) Kt 1 It
(14).
The capital stock I t at period t is jointly determined by the real interest rate, I, at the same period, and capital stock Kt 1 at period t-1, as follows: It Kt 1 i , 0 , 0
T
and are constants.
IP
where
(15),
CR
Inserting Equation (15) into Equation (14) obtains: Kt (i) (1 ) Kt 1 i
(16).
( STICt a b Ct a b )
] L
(17).
AN
Yt A[(1 ) Kt 1
US
From Equations (11), (12), (13) and (16), we derive Equation (17):
M
We then transform both sides into a logarithm, and take derivatives on both sides to obtain:
PT
ED
ln Yt ln Yt Kt it M 2t b 0 STICt a b Kt it M 2t b STICt a b Kt M 2t b 2
(18).
Since Equation (18) is positive, when short-term international capital flow (STIC) at the
AC
CE
period (t-a-b) increases, production output at period t increases.
27
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT References: Athukorala, P., Rajapatirana, S., 2003. Capital flows and the real exchange rate: A comparative study of Asia and Latin America. World Economy. 26(4), 613-637. Avdjiev, S., Hardy, B., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., Serven. L., 2017. Gross capital inflows to banks, corporates and sovereigns. CEPR Discussion Paper. No.11806.
T
Bitzer, J., Gorg, H., 2009. Foreign direct investment, competition and industry performance. World Economy. 32(2), 221-233.
IP
Blanchard, O.J., 1987. Why does money affect output? A survey. NBER Working Paper. No.2285.
CR
Blind, K., Jungmittag, A., 2004. Foreign direct investment, imports and innovations in the service industry. Review of Industrial Organization. 25, 205-227.
US
Calvo, G. A., 1998. Capital flows and capital market crises: The simple economics of sudden stops. Journal of Applied Economics. 1, 35-54. Calvo, G.A., Leiderman, L., Reinhart.C. M., 1996. Inflows of capital to developing countries in the 1990s. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 10, 123-139.
AN
Caves, R., 1996. Multinational enterprises and economic analysis, 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
M
Celasun, O., Denizer, C., He, D., 1999. Capital flows, Macroeconomic management and the financial system: The Turkish case, 1989-1997. World Bank Working Paper.
ED
Chari, V.V., Kehoe. P. J., 2003. Hot money. Journal of Political Economy. 111(6), 1262-1292. Claessens, S., 2014. An overview of macroprudential policy tools. IMF Working Paper, No. WP/14/214.
PT
Claessens, S., Klingebiel, D., Schmukler, S., 2001. FDI and stock markets in emerging economies: going local or global? Mimeo. World Bank Working Paper.
CE
Cline, W., 1987. Discussion in Donald Lessard and John Williamson eds., Capital flight and third world debt (of Chapter 3). Institute for International Economics. Washington D.C.
AC
Cuddington, J., 1986. Capital flight: estimates, issues and explanation. Princeton Studies in International Finance. 58, December. Das, S., 1987. Externalities and technology transfer through multinational corporations: a theoretical analysis. Journal of International Economics. 22, 171-82. Domowitz, I., Glen, J., Madhavan, A., 1997. Market segmentation and stock prices: Evidence from an emerging market. Journal of Finance. 52, 1059-1085. Dooley, M., 1986. Country specific risk premiums, capital flight and net investment income payments in selected developing countries. IMF Departmental Memorandum. No.86 /17. Edison, H., Reinhart, C. M., 2001. Stopping hot money. Journal of Development Economics. 66, 533-553. Eichengreen, B., Gupta, P., Masetti, O., 2017. Are capital flows fickle? increasingly? and does the answer still depend on type? World Bank Policy Research Paper. No.7972. 28
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Emmanuel S. A., Gamaliel, O. E., 2017. Foreign direct investment and industrial sector performance: assessing the long-run implication on economic growth in Nigeria. Journal of Mathematical Finance.7, 391-411. Engle, R.F., Granger, C.W.J., 1987. Cointegration and error correction: Representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica. 55, 251-276.
T
Fauzel, S., Seetanah, B., Sannasee, R. V., 2015. Productivity spillovers of FDI in the manufacturing sector of Mauritius, evidence from a dynamic framework. Journal of Development Areas. 49, 295-316.
IP
Feldstein, M., 2000. Aspects of Global Economic integration: outlook for the future. NBER Working Paper. No. 7899.
CR
Feng, L., Lin, C.Y., Wang, C., 2017. Do capital flows matter to stock and house prices? evidence from China. Emerging Markets Finance & Trade. 53, 2215-2232.
US
Ferreira, M. A., and Matos, P. , 2008, The colors of investors’ money: The role of institutional investors around the world, Journal of Financial Economics, 88,.499-533.
AN
Fuertes, A. M., Phylaktis, K., Cheng. Y., 2016. Hot money in bank credit flows to emerging markets during the banking globalization era, Journal of International Money and Finance, 60, 29-52.
M
Girma, S. and Gong, Y., 2008. FDI, linkages and the efficiency of state-owned enterprises in China. The Journal of Development Studies, 44(5), 728-749.
ED
Girma, S., Greenaway, D. and Wakelin, K., 2001. Who benefits from foreign direct investment in the UK?. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 48(2), 119-133 Goldberg, L., Krogstrup, S., 2018. International capital flow pressures. IMF Working Paper. WP/18/30.
PT
Griffith-Jones, S. and Gallagher, K.P., 2011. Curbing hot capital flows to protect the real economy. Economic and Political Weekly, pp.12-14.
CE
Grossman, G., Helpman, E., 1991. Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
AC
Guichard, S., 2017. Findings of the recent literature on international capital flows: Implications and suggestions for further research. Economics Department Working Papers. No. 1410. Guo, F., Huang, S. Y., 2010a. Does “hot money” drive China’s real estate and stock markets? International Review of Economics & Finance. 19 (3), 452-66. Guo, F., Huang, S.Y., 2010b. Hot money and business cycle volatility: Evidence from China. China & World Economy. 18(6), 73-89. Curran, Enda, Li, F., Coy, P., 2015, The Hot Money Cools on China, Bloomberg Businessweek, May 17, 2015. Henry, P. B., 2000. Stock market liberalization, economic reform, and emerging market equity prices, Journal of Finance. 55, 529-564. Hiemstra, C., Jones, J.D., 1994. Testing for linear and nonlinear Granger causality in the stock price volume relation. Journal of Finance. 49(5), 1639-1664. 29
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Huang, S. Y., 2010. What causes the inflow of speculative funds to China? The Chinese Economy. 43(5), 50-61. Javorcik, B. S., 2004. Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages. American economic review, 94(3), 605-627. Jungnickel, R. and Keller, D., 2003. German FDI and Integration of Production in the EU
T
Kaminsky, G. L., 1999. Currency and banking crises: The early warnings of distress. IMF Working Paper. No. 99/178.
IP
Kaminsky, G. L., Reinhart, C. M., 1998. Financial crises in Asia and Latin America: then and now. American Economic Review. 88, 444-449.
CR
Kant, C., 1996. Foreign direct investment and capital flight. Princeton Studies in International Finance. No.80.
US
Keller, W. and Yeaple, S.R., 2009. Multinational enterprises, international trade, and productivity growth: firm- level evidence from the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(4), 821-831.
AN
Kim, D., Iwasawa, S., 2017. Hot money and cross-section of stock returns during the global financial crisis. International Review of Economics and Finance. 50, 8-22.
M
Kim, E. H., Vijay, S., 2000. Stock market openings: Experience of emerging economies. Journal of Business. 73(1), 25-66.
ED
Koepke, R., 2015. What Drives Capital Flows to Emerging Markets: A Survey of the Empirical Literature. IMF Working Paper, April. Kokko, A., 1992. Foreign direct investment, host country characteristics and spillovers. Stockholm: The Economic Research Institute.
PT
Korinek, A., 2011. Hot money and serial financial crises. IMF Economic Review. 59(2), 306-339.
CE
Kose, M. A., Prasad, E.S., Terrones, M. E., 2009. Does openness to international financial flows raise productivity growth? Journal of International Money and Finance. 28(4), 554-580. Kumar, S., Dehradun, M., 2016. FDI flow and industrial production: An impact analysis of make in India. International Journal of Research in Economics and Social Sciences. 6, 75-84.
AC
Lane, P., 2015. Cross-border financial linkages: Identifying and measuring vulnerabilities. VoxEU, 26 January. Larry, H. F., 2004. Large capital inflows to Korea: the traditional developing economy story? Journal of Asian Economics. 15, 99-110. Lee. Y.H., Huang, Y.L., Chen, T.H., 2017. Does hot money impact stock and exchange rate markets on China? Asian Academy of Management Journal of Accounting and Finance. 13(2), 95-108. Levine, R., 2001. International financial liberalization and economic growth. Review of International Economics. 9(4), 688-702. Li, C., Chang, P., Li, S., Shi, X., 2015. Cross-border M&A and the marketing timing of economic crisis. China Finance Review International. 5(4), 421-439. 30
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Li, J.J., Liu, Y.L., Ge, S., 2012. China’s alternative remittance system: Channels and size of “hot money” flows. Crime Law Soc Change. 57, 221-237. Li, K., Qi, S. Z., 2016. Does FDI increase industrial energy consumption of China? based on the empirical analysis of Chinese provinces industrial panel data. Emerging Markets Finance & Trade. 52, 1305-1314. Li, X., Chang, H. L., Su, C. W., Dai, Y., 2017. Does foreign direct investment promote exports in China? China Finance Review International. 7 (2), 185-202.
IP
T
Markusen, J., Venables, A., 1999. Foreign direct investment as a catalyst for industrial development. European Economic Review. 43, 335-56.
CR
Martin, M., Morrison, W., 2008. China's “hot money” problems. Congressional Research Service Reports. No. RS22921.
US
Masih, A.M., and Masih, R., 1999. Are Asian stock market fluctuations due mainly to intraregional contagion effects? Evidence based on Asian emerging stock markets. PacificBasin Finance Journal. 7(3-4), 251-282. McKinnon, R., 2012. Carry trades, interest differentials, and international monetary reform. Journal of Policy Modeling. 34, 549-567.
AN
McKinnon, R., 2013. The unloved dollar standard: From Bretton Woods to the rise of China. Oxford, UK and New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
M
McKinnon, R., 2014. Hot money flows, cycles in primary commodity prices, and financial control in developing countries. IDEAS Working Paper Series from RePEc, St. Louis.
ED
McKinnon, R., and Huw, P., 1996. Credible liberalizations and international capital flows: The over borrowing syndrome. NBER East Asia Seminar on Economics. 5, 7-42.
PT
McKinnon, R.I. and Pill, H., 1996. Credible Liberalizations and International Capital Flows: The" Overborrowing Syndrome". In Financial Deregulation and Integration in East Asia, NBER-EASE Volume 5 (pp. 7-50). University of Chicago Press.
CE
Mishra, D., Mody, A., Murshid, A. P., 2001. Private capital flows and growth. Finance and Development. 38(2), 2-5.
AC
Pakko, M.R., 2008. No smoking at the slot machines: the effect of a smoke-free law on Delaware gaming revenues. Applied Economics. 40(14), 1769-1774. Pantula, S. G., Gonzalez-Farias, G., Fuller, W. A., 1994. A comparison of unit-root test criteria. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics. 12(4), 449-59. Prasad E., Rajan R., Subramanian A., 2006. Patterns of International Capital Flows and Their Implications for Economic Development. IMF Working Paper, September. Prasad, E., Wei, S., 2005. China's approach to capital inflows: Patterns and possible explanations. IMF Working Paper. 05/79. Prasad, E., Rajan, R., Subramanian, A., 2006. Foreign capital and economic growth. IMF Working Paper. Romer, P., 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy. 98, 71-102. Sarno, L., Taylor, M, P., 1999. Moral hazard, asset price bubbles, capital flows, and the East 31
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Asian crisis: the first tests. Journal of International Money and Finance. 18, 637-657. Taylor, M. P., Sarno, L., 1997. Capital flows to developing countries: long and short-term determinants. The World Bank Economic Review. 11(3), 451-70. Teece, D. J., 1977. Technology transfer by multinational firms: The resource cost of transferring technological know-how. Economic Journal. 8, 242-61.
T
Tsai, I. C., Chiang, M. C., Tsai, H. C., Liou, C. H., 2014. Hot money effect or foreign exchange exposure? Investigation of the exchange rate exposures of Taiwanese industries. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money. 31, 75-96.
IP
Umar, M. and Sun, G., 2016. Determinants of different types of bank liquidity: Evidence from BRICS countries. China Finance Review International. 6(4), 380-403.
CR
Urata, S., Kawai, H., 2000. The determinants of the location of foreign direct investment by Japanese small and medium-sized enterprises. Small Business Economics. 15(2), 79-103.
US
Wang, C.H., Hwang, J.T., Chung, C. P., 2017. Do short-term international capital inflows drive China’s asset markets? The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance. 60, 115-124.
AN
Xie, P., 2004. China’s monetary policy: 1998-2002. Stanford Center for International Development Working Paper. No. 217. Stanford University. Yang, L., Hamori, S., 2016. Hot money and business cycle volatility: Evidence from selected Asian countries. Emerging Markets Finance & Trade. 52, 351-363.
M
Yang S.G., Liu Z.H., 2001. Analysis on the international capital flow’s effect on China monetary policy and its policy. World Economy. 6, 61-66.
ED
Zhang, K. H., 2014. How does foreign direct investment affect industrial competitiveness? Evidence from China. China Economic Review. 30, 530-539.
PT
Zhang, L., Huang, Z., 2011. Do capital flows fuel asset bubbles in China? Workshop Financial Stability in Emerging Market. 1-16.
CE
Zhang, Y., Shen, X.H., 2008. An empirical research on appreciation of RMB, rising of stock price and hot money inflow. Journal of Financial Research. 11, 87-98.
AC
Zhang, Y., Pei, P., Fang, X. M., 2007. An empirical analysis on short-term international capital inflow and its motivation in China: Basing on triple-arbitration model. Studies of International Finance. 9, 41-52. Zhao, Z.X., Zhang, K. H., 2010. FDI and industrial productivity in China: Evidence from panel data in 2001-06. Review of Development Economics. 14 (3), 656-665.
32
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 1 Variable Definitions
Definition
Units
Explanation
Industry
Industry output
100 million RM B
The outputs of three main industries and most sectors
Agriculture
Agriculture output
100 million RM B
(except chemical engineering and banks) have strong
Service
Services output
100 million RM B
seasonality, so we use seasonally adjusted variables.
Coal
Coal output
10 thousand tons
Quarterly loan balance is second-order stationary, while
Aluminum
Aluminum output
10 thousand tons
the quarterly short-term international balance is the first-
Steel
Steel output
10 thousand tons
order stationary. Therefore, we cannot use them in the
Cement
Cement output
10 thousand tons
integration test. Instead, we use monthly loan balance
Ethane
Ethane output
10 thousand tons
Loan
Loan balance (monthly)
100 million RM B
100 million RM B
M
capital balance (quarterly) Short-term international
100 million RM B
AC
CE
PT
capital balance (monthly)
ED
STIC1
IP
CR
US
AN
Short-term international STIC
T
Variable
33
and monthly short-term international capital balance during the period.
STIC1 of the third month of the contemporary quarter.
See section 4.2 for details.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 2 Descriptive Statistics
Minimum
39,568
37,404
77,411
8,740
8,132
16,253
Service
41,107
34,333
100,085
Coal
62,804
64,802
527
377
Steel
15,853
14,834
Cement
38,950
34,872
Ethane
275
264
1,213,637
STIC
-77
27,578
97,394
19,337
26,672
1516
38
475
30,085
3,018
9,084
74,157
14,298
18,063
456
111
118
858,558
3,190,889
283,738
864,683
8,468
27,378
-96,396
26,826
IP
9,436
AC
CE
PT
ED
Loan
22,295 4,255
US
Aluminum
10,870 3,578
AN
Agriculture
Std. Dev.
T
Maximum
M
Industry
Median
CR
Mean
34
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 3 Correlation
Agriculture
Service
C
AL
Steel
Cement
C2H2
0.995
Service
0.982
0.992
Coal
0.951
0.925
0.886
Aluminum
0.964
0.980
0.994
0.847
Steel
0.994
0.987
0.972
0.962
0.953
Cement
0.989
0.983
0.968
0.948
0.955
Ethane
0.983
0.973
0.955
0.959
0.937
0.986
0.977
Loan
0.968
0.982
0.997
0.858
0.995
0.956
0.954
0.938
STIC
-0.627
-0.684
-0.756
-0.384
-0.791
-0.591
-0.601
-0.559
Loan
IP
T
Agriculture
CR
Industry
US
AN
M ED PT CE AC
35
0.991
-0.793
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 4 Unit Root Test
ADF Test Critical values (1%, 5%)
First Difference ADF test
Critical values (1%, 5%)
STIC
2.48 (0,0,1)
(-2.60, -1.95)
-5.29 (1,1,0)***
(-4.10, -3.48)
Agriculture
-2.37 (1,1,0)
(-4.10, -3.48)
-8.05 (1,1,0)***
(-4.10, -3.48)
Industry
-2.56 (1,1,1)
(-4.10, -3.48)
-3.36 (1,0,0)**
(-3.53, -2.90)
Service
28.96 (0,0,0)
(-2.60, -1.95)
-5.34 (1,1,0)***
(-4.11, -3.48)
Steel
4.16 (0,0,0)
(-2.60, -1.95)
-6.38 (1,0,0)***
(-2.60, -1.95)
Loan
32.77 (0,0,0)
(-2.60, -1.95)
-4.49 (1,1,1)***
(-4.11, -3.48)
Coal
0.16 (1,1,1)
(-4.10, -3.48)
-9.17 (1,0,0)***
(-3.53, -2.91)
Ethane
-0.69 (1,0,0)
(-3.53, -2.91)
-7.98 (0,0,0)***
(-2.60, -1.95)
Aluminum
-1.15 (1,1,0)
(-4.10, -3.48)
-5.16 (0,0,0)***
(-2.60, -1.95)
Cement
-2.71 (1,1,1)
(-4.10,-3.48)
-10.54 (0,0,0)***
(-2.60,-1.94)
M
AN
US
CR
IP
T
(C, T, K)
ED
Variable
AC
CE
PT
***, ** and * represent significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.
36
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 5 Granger Causality Test for the Relation between Short-term International Capital and Sector Outputs
F value 4.03
d(Industry) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
d(Service) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
0.17
0.84
0.29
0.75
5.17
0.01**
3.90
0.03*
CR
AN
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Service)
US
d(Agriculture) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
***, ** and * represent significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.
37
0.02*** 0.13
2.09
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Agriculture)
P value
IP
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Industry)
T
Null Hypothesis
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 6 Cointegration Test for Short-term International Capital and Sector Outputs
Cointegration
Cointegration Function
Cointegration Trace Statistic
34.18
Industryt = 0.29STIC t +2383.58Trend (0.22)
6.55
(317.37)
Servicet = 0.25STIC t -4574.14Trend (Service, STIC) (1077.21)
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
***, ** and * represent significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.
38
None**
12.52
At most 1
37.41
25.87
None**
7.69
12.52
At most 1
US
(0.45)
25.87
CR
(Industry, STIC)
Function
T
(Standard Errors)
IP
Variables
5% Critical Value
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 7 VECM Test for Short-term International Capital and Sector Outputs
D(STIC(-1))
0.54***
ECT
0.05**
T
-0.01**
Variables D(Service)
D(Industry(-1))
D(Service(-1))
0.002***
D(STIC(-1))
IP
D(Industry)
ECT
0.39***
0.03**
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
US
***, ** and * represent significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.
CR
Variables
39
constant 535.9*** constant 887.9***
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 8 Variance Decomposition of STIC to Industry and Service Outputs
Industry
STIC
Service
STIC
01
100.00
0.00
100.00
0.00
02
97.65
2.35
97.07
03
96.00
4.00
94.56
04
95.00
5.00
93.06
6.94
05
94.39
5.61
92.28
7.72
06
94.04
5.96
07
93.85
6.15
08
93.76
6.24
09
93.75
6.25
10
93.79
6.21
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
US
CR
IP
T
Period
40
2.93 5.44
91.95
8.05
91.89
8.11
92.00
8.00
92.26
7.77
92.51
7.49
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 9 Short-term International Capital and Subsector Outputs
Panel A. Granger Causality Test for Subsectors
F value 7.78
d(Loan) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
P value 0.00***
IP
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Loan)
T
Null Hypothesis
0.02**
0.52
0.60
3.4
0.04
4.27
0.02**
d(Aluminum) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
0.19
0.83
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Cement)
0.59
0.56
0.30
0.75
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Coal)
2.72
0.07*
d(Coal) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
2.00
0.14
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Ethane)
0.22
0.8
3.72
0.03
CR
4.41
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Steel)
US
d(Steel) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
M
AN
d(STIC) does not Granger Cause d(Aluminum)
CE
PT
ED
d(Cement) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
d(Ethane) does not Granger Cause d(STIC)
AC
***, ** and * represent significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.
41
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Panel B. Cointegration Test for Subsectors Cointegration
Cointegration Function
Trace
Cointegration 5% Critical Value
Variables
(Standard Errors)
Statistic
Loan t = -0.20STIC t
Function
18.97
15.49
None**
2.30
3.84
At most 1
38.48
25.87
None**
12.52
At most 1
20.26
None**
9.16
At most 1**
(0.04) Aluminumt = 0.005STICt -29.4Trend
T
(Loan, STIC)
(9.15)
6.81
Coal t = 41205.58+1.63S TICt
33.77
(Coal, STIC) (11221.4) (0.49)
CR
(0.01)
IP
(Aluminum, STIC)
15.33
US
***, ** and * represent significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.
ECT -0.01***
Aluminum
-0.01
Coal
-0.01
ED
Loan
Industry(-1)
M
Variable
AN
Panel C. VECM Test for Subsectors
0.50***
-1.37***
0.001
-0.001
PT
-0.03
AC
CE
***, ** and * represent significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.
42
STIC(-1)
-0.10
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Figure 1
US
Figure 2
CR
IP
T
Short-term International Capital Balance (in RMB 100 billion)
PT
ED
M
AN
Long-term International Capital Balance (in RMB billion)
Note: We use FDI balance as the long-term international capital flow. For the convenience, we use
AC
CE
relative ratio here by assuming FDI prior to the year of 2000 was zero.
Figure 3
Industry, Agriculture and Service Outputs (in RMB trillion)
43
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Figure 4 Subsector Outputs
CR
IP
T
Panel A. Steel, Coal, and Cement Outputs (in 10 million tons)
ED
M
AN
US
Panel B. Aluminum and Ethane Outputs (in million tons)
AC
CE
PT
Panel C. Loan Balance (in trillion RMB)
44
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Figure 5 Impulse Responses of the Effects of STIC on Industry and Service
US
CR
IP
T
Panel A. Response of d(Industry) to d(STIC)
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
Panel B. Response of d(Service) to d(STIC)
45
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Figure 6 Impulse Responses of the Effects of STIC on Loan, Aluminum, and Coal
US
CR
IP
T
Panel A. Response of d(Loan) to d(STIC)
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
Panel B. Response of d(Aluminum) to d(STIC)
AC
Panel B. Response of d(Coal) to d(STIC)
46
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Does “Hot Money” Affect Real Economy? Evidence from Production Outputs in China
Highlights: Our model shows that hot money affects the production outputs via monetary supply
T
CE
PT
ED
M
AN
US
CR
Hot money has heterogeneous impacts on six capital-concentrated subsectors
AC
IP
We find the causality between hot money and the industry and service optputs
47