Ineffective Slack Emt Jomson In what is known as the contribution-inducement
model the organization
is regarded as a coalition between various participants. pants receive larger inducements
together, what is called organizational ployees also constitute
If certain partici-
than are necessary to hold the coalition slack will arise. Superfluous
em-
slack.
The existence of slack enables the organization
to survive during bad
times. Slack is also said to reduce conflicts and to play a stabilising role in the organization. This theory is questioned in what follows -
the starting point being a
definition of the concept of slack. From the same initial assumptions as the slack theory, the article culminates
The Concept According
in diametrically
opposite conclusions.
ofSlack
to the contribution-inducement
model the organ-
ization is viewed as a coalition of participants. tion receives from each participant
The organiza-
a contribution
in the form
of inputs of various kinds, while in return for his participation in the organization the form
the participant
of money
or other
receives an inducement
benefits,
for example
in
social
status. In the long demands
run the inducements
will tend to coincide.
mutual adjustments
between them are not devoid of friction,
which is connected These
agreement Here,
with imperfections
imperfections
are
between
inducements
between
slack. Certain
receive larger inducements is to be maintained. to keep
them
therefore, (Cyert
& March,
Since ciated
used
additional
@ 1986 Scandimu2an JournalofManagm Studier. November
1986
then
stockholders
receive
slack is usually
In the short run, greater
than zero
1981).
salary and status are frequently
is therefore
positions
asso-
he will go in for
One of the more prominent
in organizations
a
higher wages than is necessary
the organization.
administrative
in the
is what is called
of the coalition
with the size of the department,
empire-building. tactics
necessary
members
1963; cf Pfeffer,
a manager’s
and the
the total inducements
For example,
within
available
of
than those needed if the coalition
or employees
organizational
absence
if the coalition is to continue.
and the inducements
larger dividend
by an
the total inducements
the difference
organizational
in the factor market.
accompanied
that are necessary
organization
and the inducement
In the short run, however, the
slack-creating the creation
of
and titles (Williamson,
1963; 1964; 1975). Before
calling
define the concept
the slack
theory
in question,
one must
of slack on the basis of economic
theory 111
ERNST JONSSON
Definition of th Slack Concept A surplus exists as soon as the participant receives an inducement in excess of his minimum requirement. The meaning attached by economic theory to the concept of surplus or economic rent is therefore identical to organizational slack in the sense of inducements to members of the coalition over and above those needed to keep them in the organization (cf Williamson, 1963; 1964; 1975). The surplus which various participants can receive from an organization are shown in the figure below, which is based on the assumption of imperfect competition on both factor and product markets. Moreover, in the short run labour costs are the only variable costs, whereas the costs of plant are fured. The LS curve in the figure indicates the supply curve in respect of variable factor inputs, i.e. the supply curve for labour inputs. The distance between this curve and the horizontal axis indicates the minimum wage per manufactured unit demanded by each employee in return for his taking part in the organization. As the LS curve shows, it is necessary to increase fie wage per unit manufactured in order to yield .a marginal increase in work inputs and production. The fact is that incoming employees are assumed to have more alternative job opportunities, and hence also a higher alternative value, than those already within the organization. The firm’s marginal cost curve (MC), which includes labour costs only, shows how the wage costs change when one additional unit of the good is produced. Since higher wages must be offered to all labour inputs, not only the marginal ones, the firm’s MC-curve rises faster than the supply curve for labour inputs. In the figure, neither the demand curve for the firm’s product nor the supply curve for labour inputs is perfectly elastic, i.e. horizontal. In such conditions all the members of the group - apart from the marginal member (with the largest alternative value) - will receive inducements exceeding those required to keep them in the organization. For example, where price is AB (i.e. where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost) the various groups of participants receive the following surplus: the customers the horizontally lined area, the employees the vertically lined area and the management and the owners of capital the dotted area, less the alternative value of their contributions. The difference between the customers’ overall willingness to pay and the reservation prices (=the overall alternative value of resources employed) of other participants will be equal to the total surplus the organization generates through 112
INEFFECTIVE
SLACK
Price/Cost
I I
I I I I
I
. r
A
Volume of production
Figure
Simpl+d
illustrahn of swplur receiuedly variouspartici$antc
in an mganization.
113
ERNST JONSSON its activities.
This
surplus
above-mentioned
is equal to the sum of the three
areas in the figure less the alternative
of the contributions
of the managers
value
and the owners
of
capital. This surplus increases when price is CD ( = marginal cost). Compared
with a price of AB the surplus of the cus-
tomers, as well as that of the employees,
increase,
whereas the
surplus accruing
to the managers
and the owners of capital is
reduced.
Thus,
the price-furing
principle
portance
as regards both the size of the aggregate
its distribution When
among
price, as shown in the figure, is estab-
lished on the basis of the contributions of a certain group of participants,
made by the members
the surplus accruing
to the
will be equal to zero only when the supply curve for
sellers or the demand implying
is of im-
surplus and
the participants.
equilibrium
members
applied
identical
curve
for buyers
alternative
values
is horizontal,
for members
i.e.
of the
group. Before
the overall surplus can be equal to zero both
these
must,
curves
aggregate
moreover,
willingness
tion corresponds
coincide.
The
to pay for the products
customers’
of the organiza-
exactly, in that case, to the aggregate
native value of resources
alter-
utilized.
[email protected] Normal Slack According
to Cyert
and March
(1963) organizational
slack
tends to be equal to zero in the long run. This is connected with the fact that the requirements organization
adapt themselves
alternatives
of the members
of the
to the actual inducements
outside the organization.
This conclusion
and
may be
questioned. Firstly, the minimum rational participant
requirement
In the long run the minimum to the trend of the alternative actual inducement.
if the number
thereby
members
requirement
is then adjusted
value rather than to that of the
inducement,
value overtakes
the participant
of alternative
also the alternative
value,
in each group of participants,
quirements
of the members
courses of action, vary between
the
the minimum
re-
of the group will find expression
as supply and demand
curves that are imperfectly
that
At the
is, nonhorizontal.
organization, imperfect this kind.
which
114
as a rule
competition, slack
same
time
operates
and
in markets
will therefore
normally
with
by curves of
as well as the long run, also the
elastic,
the individual
appears to be confronted
In the short
organizational participants
will,
leave the organization.
Secondly, and
and
value of his input.
If, in time, the alternative
the more slowly increasing moreover,
of a well-informed
reflects the alternative
the total
slack of the individual be greater than zero. For
INEFFECTIVE example,
in most
production nomic
cases the actual
will be composite
rent (Lipsey
& Steiner,
The total inducements
earnings
of transfer
of a factor
earnings
presented
organizational normal
by an organization
to the organization.
thus
minimum
In other words
slack, in the sense of surplus payments,
feature of the organization.
of slack may tentatively
of
and eco-
1972).
generated
appear, as a rule, to be greater than the aggregate requirements
SLACK
For this reason
be described
as nor&
is a
this type
slack.
“Normal”Slackax Exms Capa+? Slack in the form of surplus payments as excess capacity, organization
i.e. real resources
(Naslund,
1964; Pfeffer,
In an organization
1981).
where all contributions
ticipants are fully and efficiently regularly
is usually also defined not fully utilized by the
utilized, various participants
receive a surplus in relation
keep them
in the organization.
slack does not represent
in a real economic
effective
production,
to what is necessary
Consequently,
unutilized
capacity
made by par-
real resources
or excess
sense. Nor, at a given level of
can the organization
affect the size of
the overall surplus. This surplus is instead determined by the minimum
requirements
tive production,
this surplus
therefore
be termed
of the participants. is of maximum
normal,
of the organization, resources,
since
can
these
without the participants Thus
the management
be interested
size; it may and the owners
however, the surplus payments
participants
solely
In effec-
effective slack.
From the point of view of the management by other
appear
surplus
received
as unutilized
payments
concerned
can
financial
be reduced
leaving the organization.
and owners of the organization
in influencing
to
this type of
the distribution
may
of the aggregate
surplus to their own advantage.
To this end they could con-
ceivably, for example,
a price and wage policy that
implement
would result in their surplus increasing surpluses
accruing
to customers
at the expense of the
and employees.
Normal Slack as a Stub&w? According
to Cyert and March
of particular
with changes in external improve pants
so rapidly
factors. During
that the aspiration
have no time to adjust
extent, resources
and
(1963) the concept
use when dealing with the problems
so the organization
upwards
a boom these factors levels of the particito a corresponding
is able to assure
over and above its requirements.
recession organizational
of slack is associated
itself of
In the subsequent
slack will instead operate as a cushion, 115
ERNST JONSSON
and so, as a result of the fact that reserve resources represented by slack are available, the aspiration levels of the participants need not be reduced. Because of the unfavourable trend of the external factors, there will instead be a reduction in the surplus payments accruing to the organization during the boom. In this way organizational slack largely neutralizes the potential changes in the organization’s operational environment, and thus enables the organization to survive during bad times (Cyert & March, 1963). A recession tends to be accompanied by a strengthening of the buyers’ position at the expense of that of the sellers, while the opposite tendency would seem to prevail during a boom. In other words, the number of alternative courses of action open to the sellers seems to vary with the state of business, whereas the opposite applies to the buyers. Both the buyers’ willingness to pay and the sellers’ reservation prices will in that case be covariant with the state of business. If the willingness to pay and the reservation prices vary to the same extent, the total surplus will develop independently of the state of business activity A well-informed and rational participant also adjusts his negotiating requirement to the cyclical variation of the minimum requirement (=opportunity cost), For those participants who sell goods and services to the organization, the area of action vis-&is the management will, similarly, follow the business fluctuations. For that reason the inducements of these participants may also be expected to follow suit. However, if the participants, excluding the management and owners of capital, are unaware of or underestimate the increase in the opportunity cost during the boom, their inducement will be less than it would otherwise be. Instead, the inducement payable to the management and the owners of capital will increase by a corresponding extent. During the subsequent recession this increased inducement will, according to Cyert and March (1963) be transferred in return to the other participants, thus making it unnecessary to reduce their inducement in spite of the falling opportunity cost. However, in contrast to what is maintained, this state of affairs does not affect the organization’s chances of survival. Given an alternative pattern of behaviour where the participants are well-informed concerning the trend of the minimum requirement as economic activity fluctuates, they would in fact receive an enhanced inducement during the boom and a lower one during the recession. The opposite would apply for the owners of capital. Since the lower inducement during the recession is a consequence of the drop in the opportunity cost ( = the minimum requirement), the participants would nevertheless remain with the organization. In 116
INEFFECTIVE
SLACK
other words, the cushioning function which, it is claimed, the capital-owners’ slack fulfils affects only the distribution of the overall surplus over the period of the business cycle. Even if those participants who are sellers were to be unaware of the trend as regards the relative scope of action during economic fluctuations, there is still no reason to expect a counter-cyclical redistribution of the surplus. The fact is that, in their capacity as professional participants, the managers are likely to be aware that their scope of action vis-a-vis these participants will diminish during the boom and expand during the recession. For this reason it is hardly to be expected that the managers will increase the surplus payable to these participants during a recession if this means taking a cut in their own surplus.
Y@ectiue
Slack” as a Stubiher?
The concept of slack is usually also given another meaning: the organization employs more employees than necessary and there is, for example, management slack, or it is in other respects inefficient in its resource utilization. In other words, this state of affairs may be denoted in&&ive slack. This form of slack corresponds to what Leibenstein calls X-inefficiency, that is the internal inefficiency of firms (1966). As X-inefficiency refers to the ratio of inputs to output, the existence of such slack can in fact be said to imply real excess capacity. As a result of ineffective slack there is an overall surplus generated by the organization, smaller than it would be in the case of effective production. It is also said that this type of slack increases during the boom, since the pressure to be efficient is in fact less at such times than it would otherwise be. The slack created during the boom is instead taken into use during the subsequent recession, thus making it easier for the organization to survive this period with its falling profits. Thus this form of slack also is said to fulfd a stab&sing function (Cyert & March, 1963; Naslund, 1964; Cohen & Cyert, 1965). This view is challenged in the following. Let us assume that the organization has an opportunity to introduce labour-saving measures during a boom. The net effect of these is that the supply curve for labour inputs and the marginal cost curve per unit manufactured show a proportionally equal fall at all levels of production. As long as ineffective slack is not allowed to arise during the boom, the total surplus will thus be greater than it woukl be in a hypothetical situation where the. laboursaving measures are not introduced. From the point of view of the organization, as well as that 117
ERNST JONSSON
of society, it might therefore be more efficient to prevent ineffective slack from arising during the boom than to eliminate it later on during the recession. Those resources that are taken into use to prevent slack must not then give a higher yield through being taken into use in some other part of the organization. In such conditions it seems that the existence of ineffective slack will tend to reduce the organization’s chances of survival rather than increase them. It would also appear that the danger of conflict within the organization will be greater if employees are dismissed during a recession than during a boom when more alternative jobs are available. In contrast to what is usually claimed, it therefore seems that the existence of ineffective slack will increase the conflicts within the organization (see, for example, Pfeffer, 1981).
DiamtrikalJyApposite Conduxions As long as a participant receives an inducement larger than is necessary to keep him in the organization there is, according to Cyert and March (1963), what is known as organizational slack. With economic theory as the starting point, this slack may be described as being synonymous with the concept of economic rent. It is therefore a question of the surplus in relation to his opportunity cost that the participant receives as a result of his taking part in a certain organization. In contrast to what is maintained, this type of slack does not represent unutilized real resources. Irrespective of whether the organization’s real resources are fully and efficiently utilized, it would seem instead that it is usual for the participants to receive slack payments in both the short and the long run. For this reason these payments may be described as normal slack (surplus). The organization’s chances of survival, moreover, are not affected by the way in which this slack is distributed among the participants over the period of the business cycle. Slack in the sense of real excess capacity arises in an organization only when the personnel strength is greater than is necessary or where resource utilization is inefficient in other respects. Such ineffective slack can, for example, arise during a boom period when the insistence on efficiency is less than it would otherwise be. The overall surplus generated by the organization will, by the same token, be smaller than is the case with effective production. In contrast to what is maintained it would seem that this ineffective slack (i.e. owing to loss of surplus) is likely to reduce the organization’s chances of survival and increase the danger of conflicts. It may therefore be argued that ineffective slack should be kept at as low and even a level as possible. 118
INEFFECTIVE
Cohen,
K.J., and R.M.
1965
Pfeffer, J.
Cyert
Theory of theFirm Resource Allocation in a Market
1981
Cyert, R.M., 1963
Inc.
1986
1958
Prentice-Hall,
Inc.
E. “An integration
Williamson, 1963
of the contribution-induce-
Company
0.E
“Managerial
discretion and business
behaviour.” A&an LIII:1032-1057
ment model and economic theory” Scandinavian Joumal ofManagement Studies, Vol. 2, no. 314.
Adminictmtive Behaviou,: New York: The Macmillan
A Behavioral T&eoy of the Finn. Englewood
Jonsson,
1964
Ob$ives
1972
Cliffs, New Jersey:
Economics New York: Harper & Row, Publishers
1975
March, J.G., and H.A. Simon
Economic Reviq
The Economtcs ojL&xtionny
Lipsey, R.G., and PO. Steiner
1963
Massachu-
Inc.
Simon, H.A.
and J.G. March
Cliffs, New Jersey:
Rxuer in Organizntions. Marshfield, setts: Pitman Publishing
Economy. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall,
SLACK
in a Theoy
Behaviour: Manage&l
ofthe Finn.
Englewood
Prentice-Hall,
Inc.
Markets and Hiemrchti: Analysis and Antitrust Implicatbnr.
New York: Free Press.
Or~anizationr, New York: John Wiley
Naslund, B. 1964 “Organizational
slack.” Ekonomisk Tidskrzft,
1964:i
119