Intergenerational Efficiency of Farmland Conversion and Farmland Resource Loss in China

Intergenerational Efficiency of Farmland Conversion and Farmland Resource Loss in China

CHINA POPULATION, RESOURCES AND ENVIRONMENT Volume 17, Issue 3, May 2007 Online English edition of the Chinese language journal Cite this article as: ...

213KB Sizes 0 Downloads 56 Views

CHINA POPULATION, RESOURCES AND ENVIRONMENT Volume 17, Issue 3, May 2007 Online English edition of the Chinese language journal Cite this article as: Chn Popu Res Envi, 2007, 17(3): 28–34.

SHORT COMMUNICATION

Intergenerational Efficiency of Farmland Conversion and Farmland Resource Loss in China Tan Rong*, Qu Futian China Center for Land Policy Research, Nanjing Agricultural University, Nanjing 210095, China

Abstract: One of the requirements of sustainable utilization of resources is the efficiency of intergenerational allocation, which is important to the long-term utilization of resources. Based on the principle of efficient intergenerational allocation of resource in resource economics, this paper builds an ex post model to measure the efficiency of intergenerational allocation of farmland resource, and points out that with the continuous testing and modifying in practice according to the model results, the allocation of farmland resource in the future can continuously converge at the efficient allocation. This paper employs this model to test the allocation of the farmland resource from 1989 to 2003, and the result shows that if the test sample is divided into 1989 to 1996 period and 1997 to 2003 period, which due to the stricter farmland resource protection policy issued after 1996, the inefficient farmland conversion of the three main regions in China in the period of 1989 to 1996 was 6.58%, 6.84%, 7.85%, respectively. Keywords: intergenerational allocation; farmland conversion; excessive loss

1

Introduction

Scarcity and constrain on renewable natural resources, especially the exhausted resources, lead to the importance of the intergenerational allocation efficiency. Farmland conversion from rural to urban sector is thus an issue of exhausted resource allocation because of the difficulty in reclamation from the urban to the rural after the farmland has been converted. In China most of farmland conversion occurs around the urban area, where the land is more fertile than in the remote area. Although the economic growth needs farmland conversion, only efficient use can meet the harmony between natural resource protection and economic growth. Current studies have paid attention to the incompleteness of market mechanism and the irrational intervention of the government in the market system (Tan, Qu, 2005; Qu, Feng, Zhu, et al, 2004), which causes farmland over-conversion, but there is seldom study focusing on the efficiency of intergenerational allocation of farmland conversion in China. For the moment we do not go further to the topic of equality between generations. Instead, we would like to examine only the efficiency according to the neoclassic rule in resource allocation. Also it should be mentioned

that efficiency not only includes intergenerational allocation efficiency, there are many other aspects related to this issue, but in this paper we only focus on whether current farmland conversion meets the efficiency standard in China aiming to avoid the complexity and difficulties on explanation. This paper also only testifies the ex post data in order to escape the inaccuracy of the forecast of future situations. Sometimes the ex post method is a suitable way for policy makers to access the performance of one policy and make improvement on it according to what have been learned.

2

Model

The principle for efficient allocation of intergenerational allocation is well discussed, and the basic marginal rule can be found in any neoclassic environmental textbooks (Perman, Yue, McGilvray, Commo, 2003; Zhang, 1998; Qu, 2001), which is to ensure the marginal present revenue among different generations are equal. International studies on this topic will have certain assumptions on the revenue and discount rate in the future, and then maximize the total revenue among different generations to obtain the optimal utilization of the resources among different phases (Winjum,

Received date: 2006-11-18 * Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected] Copyright © 2007, Chinese Society for Sustainable Development and Research Center for Sustainable Development of Shandong Province. Electronic version published by Elsevier Limited. All rights reserved.

Tan Rong, et al / China Population, Resources and Environment, 2007, 17(3): 28–34

Brown, Schlamandinger, 1998; Tassone, Wesseler, Nesci, 2002). This inevitably results in the subjective error for the assumptions. The studies on this topic in China mostly remain at the theoretical analysis, e.g. illustrating either the importance of the intergenerational efficiency (Wei, 2002), or importance of how to find a reasonable discount rate in resource utilization (Chen, 2003). Based on the theoretical principle for efficient allocation between generations, this paper builds up a C-D production model to calculate the marginal revenue of urban construction land and the farmland. The C-D production forms are shown as equations (1) and (2).

NRAMi NRUi

F

G

A u K AMi u LAMi u Land AMi D

E

B u KUi u LUi u LandUi

H

J

(1) (2)

Where, NRAMi is the net revenue of agricultural sector. NRUi is the net revenue of urban sector. K is the capital investment. L is the labor input. Land is the land resource input. The subscript Ui denotes the urban sector in i phase, and the subscript AMi is the rural sector in i phase. If the coefficients of the equations (1) and (2) are estimated, the marginal revenue of farmland conversion can be calculated through the deduction of marginal revenue of urban sector and the marginal revenue of rural sector, where the latter includes the marginal non-market value of the agricultural land resource. The calculation formula is shown as (3). MRi

w(TRi ) w( Land)

w( NRUi ) w( NRAMi ) w(RANMi )   w(LandUi ) w( LandAMi ) w(LandAMi )

(3)

Where, MRi is the marginal revenue of farmland conversion in i phase. TRi denotes the total revenue of farmland revenue in i phase. NRUi is the total revenue of urban construction land in i phase. NRAmi is the total revenue of farmland revenue in i phase. RANMi is the non-market value of farmland resource in i phase. LandUi is the amount of urban construction land in i phase, and LandAmi is the amount of farmland in i phase. After the above calculation, the inefficient farmland loss according to the efficiency principle can be calculated. The relation between farmland conversion quantities with the marginal revenue should be estimated first. Assume the demand and supply curves of farmland conversion are the forms like equations (4) and (5). (4) QD a u P  b , b >0

Q

S

c u P

d

, d >0

(5)

Then, according to the basic pricing formulas in microeconomics, which are P=MC/(1+(1/Ed))and P=MR/(1+ (1/Es)), the equations (4) and (5) can be changed into equa-

tions (6) and (7). logLANDcovi C1  C2 u logMRUi

(6)

logLANDcovi C3  C4 u log(MRAMi  MRANMi)

(7)

Where, LANDcovi is the amount of farmland conversion. MR denotes the marginal revenue. The subscripts are the same meaning as above. After the estimation of C1C2C3C4, and make equal of the marginal revenue in different phases, then the ratio of farmland conversion in each phase is obtained, which meets the requirement of efficiency standard. If comparing the calculated efficient results with those in reality, then the inefficient farmland conversion loss can be calculated. So far, the model for accessing the efficiency allocation of farmland conversion between different generations is built, while the measurement of non-market value of farmland resource is still missing, which will be discussed in the next section. The fourth part of this paper will be the employment of the model on provincial panel data in China from 1989 to 2003.

3

Marginal non-market value of farmland

Many categories of value belong to farmland resource besides the function supporting the agricultural production, which are excluded from the traditional market system. For example, farmland resource has the functions of water regulation, gas regulation, erosion control, biological control, and even amusement of the landscape. So far, a study of Costanza (1997) is concerned and cited frequently on the value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital (Costanza, d’Arge R, de Groot R, et al, 1997). It can be seen as a completed and detailed research on ecosystem services and natural capital of natural resource based on former studies. This paper will also cite some results of the Costanza (1997)’s study combined with the real conditions in China to estimate the marginal ecological revenue of the China’s farmland resource. Some results of the Costanza (1997) on the ecological value of the farmland resource according to 1994 constant price are given as follows: the ecological value of the farmland resource in forestry was 969 US$ha-1yr-1 on average, 2007 US$ha-1yr-1 in tropic area, 302 US$ha-1yr-1 in temperate area; the ecological value of the farmland resource in grassland was 232 US$ha-1yr-1; the ecological value of the farmland resource in water was 8498 US$ha-1yr-1; the ecological value of the farmland resource in cropland (including the cultivated land and garden plot) was 92 US$ha-1yr-1. The method to calculate the ecological value of farmland resource in China is shown in the following steps: First, find the acreage of different categories of farmland resources in different provinces. The grassland and water data can be

Tan Rong, et al / China Population, Resources and Environment, 2007, 17(3): 28–34

the relation between the gross value and the quantity of the farmland is a simple equation, or linear equation, which means the gross value equals to the quantity of the farmland times the value of the unit quantity. The differential coefficient of the gross value (marginal revenue) is exactly the value of per unit quantity (a constant), so the average value can be seen as the marginal revenue. It can also be explained intuitionally that the loss of the ecological value of the last unit of the converted farmland is exactly the average eco logical value of this unit.

gained directly in the government report; the forestry should be subdivided according to the different climate zones, and the cropland is the sum of cultivated land and garden plot. Second, with the data in Table 1, calculate the average ecological value of different provinces in different years weighted by the acreage of farmland resource. Last, eliminate the inflation and change it into the 2003 constant price. The result is shown in Table 1. The ecological value of farmland resource in Table 2 is an average value, and it is not equal to the marginal value in theory. But the ecological value is a non-market value, and

Table 1 Ecological value of farmland resource in different provinces in China Unit: 104yuan RMB ha-1 yr-1 (2003 constant price) City

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Beijing

0.44

0.46

0.52

0.57

0.68

0.86

1.01

1.38

1.18

1.21

1.22

1.26

1.30

1.28

1.28

Tianjin

1.75

1.80

1.99

2.22

2.72

3.36

3.85

4.21

4.33

4.31

4.26

4.24

4.29

4.28

4.32

Hebei

0.46

0.48

0.51

0.56

0.66

0.82

0.93

1.06

1.03

1.02

1.00

0.99

1.00

0.99

1.01

Shanxi

0.33

0.33

0.36

0.38

0.44

0.55

0.64

0.71

0.72

0.71

0.70

0.73

0.73

0.72

0.73

Inner Mongolia 0.22

0.26

0.27

0.30

0.34

0.42

0.50

0.54

0.56

0.56

0.56

0.56

0.57

0.57

0.58

Liaoning

0.53

0.57

0.66

0.71

0.81

0.97

1.13

1.24

1.21

1.18

1.16

1.16

1.16

1.15

1.17

Jilin

0.43

0.45

0.47

0.51

0.58

0.70

0.81

0.89

0.90

0.89

0.88

0.86

0.87

0.87

0.88

Heilongjiang

0.47

0.40

0.44

0.50

0.59

0.73

0.87

0.95

0.97

0.97

0.94

0.93

0.93

0.93

0.93

Shanghai

1.29

1.37

1.52

1.70

2.07

2.61

3.10

5.95

3.48

3.48

3.53

3.62

3.62

3.64

3.64

Jiangsu

1.67

1.61

1.84

1.80

2.33

2.86

3.44

4.18

3.82

3.80

3.75

3.75

3.78

3.75

3.79

Zhejiang

0.52

0.53

0.54

0.59

0.81

1.38

1.13

1.24

1.20

1.18

1.17

1.18

1.18

1.16

1.19

Anhui

0.98

1.02

1.06

1.12

1.27

1.73

1.72

1.85

1.83

1.80

1.76

1.77

1.78

1.76

1.79

Fujian

0.45

0.45

0.45

0.48

0.54

1.20

0.79

0.88

0.85

0.85

0.84

0.86

0.85

0.85

0.85

Jiangxi

0.61

0.62

0.64

0.69

0.77

1.42

1.09

1.24

1.16

1.15

1.13

1.13

1.13

1.13

1.14

Shandong

0.89

0.95

0.99

1.03

1.16

1.42

1.67

1.88

1.88

1.87

1.85

1.86

1.89

1.88

1.90

Henan

0.71

0.71

0.71

0.75

0.86

0.98

1.14

1.30

1.30

1.27

1.23

1.22

1.23

1.23

1.25

Hubei

0.81

0.85

0.92

1.19

1.10

1.76

1.85

2.02

2.09

2.05

2.01

1.99

2.00

1.99

2.03

Hunan

0.61

0.61

0.64

0.73

0.87

1.64

1.38

1.46

1.52

1.53

1.53

1.56

1.54

1.53

1.57

Guangdong

0.54

0.52

0.54

0.59

0.74

2.01

1.02

1.13

1.11

1.09

1.07

1.09

1.08

1.07

1.07

Guangxi

0.33

0.33

0.34

0.36

0.43

1.69

0.71

0.77

0.76

0.73

0.72

0.72

0.72

0.71

0.72

Hainan

0.30

0.29

0.31

0.34

0.46

1.48

0.78

1.10

0.82

0.80

0.78

0.79

0.78

0.77

0.78

Sichuan

0.36

0.37

0.38

0.41

0.48

0.89

0.64

0.69

0.74

0.74

0.73

0.73

0.74

0.74

0.75

Guizhou

0.23

0.23

0.24

0.26

0.31

0.70

0.45

0.50

0.51

0.51

0.51

0.50

0.51

0.51

0.51

Yunnan

0.26

0.26

0.27

0.30

0.38

1.79

0.56

0.62

0.63

0.64

0.64

0.63

0.62

0.62

0.63

Tibet

0.32

0.33

0.57

0.63

0.71

1.02

1.09

1.17

1.23

1.24

1.24

1.24

1.24

1.24

1.25

Shaanxi

0.27

0.27

0.28

0.31

0.34

0.44

0.52

0.58

0.6

0.59

0.58

0.57

0.58

0.57

0.58

Gansu

0.27

0.29

0.31

0.35

0.40

0.50

0.60

0.59

0.68

0.67

0.66

0.65

0.68

0.68

0.69

Qinghai

0.30

0.40

0.49

0.52

0.69

0.88

1.11

1.31

1.3

1.31

1.3

1.29

1.33

1.36

1.39

Ningxia

0.23

0.25

0.29

0.32

0.42

0.53

0.62

0.66

0.69

0.69

0.68

0.68

0.69

0.68

0.69

Xinjiang

0.34

0.41

0.44

0.50

0.64

0.81

1.08

1.21

1.24

1.25

1.21

1.21

1.25

1.25

1.25

Source: Calculated by the authors.

Tan Rong, et al / China Population, Resources and Environment, 2007, 17(3): 28–34

4

Estimation and results

4.1 Data The land resource data used to estimate the model comes from the statistic data of the land administration of China (19891995) and land yearbook of China (19941997) compiled by the former National Land Management Bureau, and the annals on the land resource of China (19992003) compiled by the Ministry of Land and Resources of China. The data of the other variables come from the Statistic Yearbook of China (19902004). In order to get the comparable data of the agricultural and non-agricultural sectors, indexes of each variable are chosen that can be found in the subdivided data in each industry. The gross revenue of the agricultural sector NRAMi is the primary industry (agriculture) data of GDP, and the other part of the GDP is the gross revenue of the non-agricultural sector NRUi. The capital investment K is the sum of new basic construction investment, new renewal and reconstruction investment, and the fixed capital investment by urban and rural collective communities in each year. The total investment includes four aspects: the basic construction, renewal and reconstruction, real estate development, and the other fixed capital investment. So the data used in this paper underestimates the investment of the production. But for the aim of the model is to calculate the MR (marginal revenue) and MC (marginal cost) of the land resource, so the estimation will not influenced by the error of the investment, for the error is considered in the constant term. The labor data is the data of the employed person in each production sector. The land resource input data in the agricultural sector LandAMi includes the acreage of forestry, grassland, cultivated land, garden plot, and water area. The land input data in the non-agricultural sector LandUi is the acreage of the construction land. The conversion data of farmland resource QD and QS are the data of the cultivated land occupied by the construction land each year. Since farmland resource not only includes the cultivated land, so this index underestimates the quantity of farmland conversion. The underestimation of the farmland conversion data leads to the underestimation of the slope of the MC and overestimation of the slope of MR curves, so it overestimate the expense loss and excessive loss I, which causes the underestimation of the excessive loss II. Since the limitation of the data and the cultivated land to be occupied is the main proportion of the total conversion data, this index is acceptable. All the price data are changed into the 2003 constant price. The provincial panel data of 30 provinces, municipalities, and autonomic regions from 1989 to 2003 are used to estimate the model, which excludes the data of Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan. Chongqing’s data is also excluded for its incompleteness.

4.2 Estimation method and result Due to the different situations between different provinces in China, and the lopsided policy on farmland conversion in each region, this study divided the whole country into three regions according to the national standard, which are as follows: (a) Eastern China: municipalities of Beijing, Tianjin, and Shanghai, Hebei, Liaoning, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Fujian, Shandong, Guangdong, Guangxi and Hainan provinces. (b) Central China: Shanxi, Jilin, Heilongjiang, Anhui, Jiangxi, Henan, Hubei, and Hunan provinces, the autonomous region of Inner Mongolia (c) Western China: Sichuan, Guizhou, Yunnan, Shaanxi, Gansu, and Qinghai provinces, autonomous regions of Tibet, Ningxia, and Xinjiang. First, estimate the equation (1) and (2), then calculate the marginal revenue of the two sectors with the equation (3) and (4). To estimate the (1) and (2), first change the equation into a logarithmic style, then employ the general least squares method with the first order component of autocorrelation, AR (1), which indicates an autoregressive component. In the estimation of the equation (1), a cross-section weight by the dummy variables of each province is used to estimate the coefficients of AR (1) and Landagr because of the contribution of farmland resource in different provinces are different, and then different coefficients for each province can be obtained. In the estimation of the equation (2), only the AR (1) is estimated with the cross-section weight, for the construction land is not influenced by the terrain and climate. In addition, White Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Standard Errors and Covariance method is employed in the estimation to reduce the Heteroskedasticity. The result is shown in Table 2. The regression result is shown in Table 2. Each coefficient is significant at 1% level, and each statistic index passes the test. The marginal revenue of each period can be calculated with the original data with the coefficients in Table 2 and the data in Table 1. The result is shown in Table 3. The marginal revenue of farmland conversion between 1989 and 1996 was lower than that between 1997 and 2003 in the whole three regions, which has verified that the inefficiency of inter-generational allocation occurred in that period. The over-conversion of the farmland in the beginning of the 1990s caused the total intergenerational allocation inefficiency in the sample range of this study. In other words, if reducing the conversion amount before 1996, and (or) leaving them to the 19972003 period, farmland conversion would be at least a Pareto improvement, even if the allocation in the later period didn’t meet the efficient one, which still needed to be tested several years later. If we only focus on 19892003 period, the over conversion of the farmland in 19891996 can be calculated by the steps in the above model to estimate the equation (6) and (7)

Tan Rong, et al / China Population, Resources and Environment, 2007, 17(3): 28–34

2003. The over conversion proportions were 6.58%, 6.84% and 7.85% respectively, which showed that the central government farmland conversion decision in that period was not reasonable. Actually, from the beginning of the 1990s the large increase of the built-up area all over the country swallowed a large amount of farmland resource, while the utilization was inefficient. The central government began to relocate and reclaim the built-up area in the suburban area and forbid illegal or inefficient built-up projects after 1996, which has done some positive effect to prevent the farmland from over-use.

with the same data but in different sample range. The result is shown in Table 4. Each coefficient is significant at 1% level, and each statistic index passes the test. Based on the estimation of the equation (6) and (7), the efficient intergenerational allocation ratio between the two samples can be obtained. Then with the real conversion amount from 1989 to 2003, the over-conversion amount between 1989 and 1996 can be calculated. The result is shown in Table 5. From Table 5 we can see that the inefficiency of the intergenerational allocation existed in all the three regions from 1989 to 1996 if set sample range is set from 1989 to

Table 2 Result of the regression of equation (1) and (2)

Region

Eastern China (t test)

Central China (t test)

Western China (t test)

Period

19891996 19972003 19891996 19972003 19891996 19972003

Equation (1) A

Į

ȕ

2.382

0.003

0.028

(68.65)

(20.89)

(28.94)

3.892

0.004

0.042

(45.27)

(17.89)

(25.56)

2.087

0.002

0.022

(60.23)

(21.34)

(22.85)

3.012

0.003

0.031

(55.45)

(20.28)

(21.89)

1.968

0.004

0.019

(58.56)

(19.24)

(25.54)

2.789

0.004

0.033

(45.67)

(18.62)

(28.53)

Equation (2) Ȗ

R2

DW

Omit

0.999

2.231

Omit

0.998

2.182

Omit

0.999

2.151

Omit

0.999

2.193

Omit

0.999

2.255

Omit

0.997

2.221

B

Ȥ

į

İ

0.387

0.042

0.114

0.022

(4.93)

(7.30)

(9.01)

(5.28)

0.512

0.053

0.194

0.034

(5.28)

(6.76)

(8.89)

(6.45)

0.312

0.038

0.108

0.019

(5.12)

(8.30)

(8.35)

(4.78)

0.478

0.041

0.134

0.033

(6.89)

(7.92)

(9.67)

(5.56)

0.313

0.032

0.098

0.016

(4.93)

(6.30)

(7.25)

(6.12)

0.402

0.038

0.145

0.029

(5.67)

(6.89)

(8.34)

(7.56)

R2

DW

0.999

1.887

0.997

1.821

0.998

1.781

0.998

1.883

0.992

1.872

0.999

1.923

Source: Calculated by the authors.

Table 3 Net marginal revenue of farmland conversion in different areas in China in two different periods Unit: yuan ha-1 yr-1(2003 constant price) Region Eastern China

19891996

19972003

Region

41 646

54 313

Central China

19891996

19972003

Region

19891996

19972003

12 335

Western China

8 033

10 083

Sichuan

4 077

7 164

3 983

4 171

Guizhou

14 478

18 329

Jilin

5 995

6 679

Yunnan

10 043

13 660

21 359

Heilongjiang

8 818

13 535

Tibet

11 654

14 180

Beijing

69 584

75 065

Shanxi

Tianjin

38 637

40 283

Inner Mongolia

Hebei

13 348

18 073

Liaoning

18 146

8 979

8 998

11 034

Shanghai

119 611

146 062

Anhui

5 752

6 423

Shaanxi

9 640

12 932

Jiangsu

25 456

29 276

Jiangxi

9 950

11 995

Gansu

5 661

8 718

Zhejiang

59 659

61 174

Henan

9 235

13 047

Qinghai

6 624

7 804

Fujian

32 998

48 383

Hubei

14 501

18 478

Ningxia

7 664

8 713

Hunan

15 073

Xinjiang

1 883

3 146

Shandong

16 127

20 478

Guangdong

43 059

48 278

Guangxi

10 127

14 378

Hainan

12 710

12 265

Source: Calculated by the authors

13 478

Tan Rong, et al / China Population, Resources and Environment, 2007, 17(3): 28–34

Table 4 Result of the regression of equation (6) and (7)

Region

Eastern China (t test)

Central China (t test)

Western China (t test)

Period

Equation (6) C1

19891996

omit

19972003

omit

19891996 19972003 19891996 1997~2003

omit

C2 0.471 (5.14) 0.812 (4.28) 0.413 (6.34)

omit

0.678 (5.23)

omit

0.327 (4.64)

omit

0.562 (6.89)

Equation (7)

R2

DW

0.984

2.034

0.991

2.156

0.982

2.052

0.987

2.146

0.991

2.037

0.995

2.198

C3

C4

omit

0.112 (2.75)

omit

0.233 (4.13)

omit

0.097 (2.86)

omit

0.198 (3.46)

omit

0.078 (4.22)

omit

0.146 (4.98)

R2

DW

0.987

2.097

0.982

2.121

0.992

2.086

0.998

2.034

0.983

2.043

0.987

2.056

Source: Calculated by the authors.

Table 5 Inter-generational allocation loss of farmland conversion between 1989 and 1996 (sample as19892003) Region

Ratio(%)

Amount(ha)

Region

Ratio(%)

Amount(ha)

Region

Ratio(%)

Amount(ha)

Eastern China

6.58

31 142

Central China

6.84

21 402

Western China

7.85

12 590

Beijing

5.19

920

Shanxi

6.14

1 426

Sichuan

9.05

5 004

Tianjin

6.04

486

Inner Mongolia

8.36

1 748

Guizhou

8.29

1 058

Hebei

4.93

2 389

Jilin

6.94

723

Yunnan

5.81

1 398

Liaoning

6.98

3 161

Heilongjiang

7.07

2 927

Tibet

7.75

423

Shanghai

7.07

2 838

Anhui

6.51

4 511

Shaanxi

7.49

1 903

Jiangsu

6.33

5 353

Jiangxi

4.04

402

Gansu

8.41

979

Zhejiang

4.84

2 470

Henan

6.85

4 162

Qinghai

3.19

56

Fujian

2.87

711

Hubei

8.42

4 415

Ningxia

8.28

374

Shandong

7.92

4 562

Hunan

6.63

1 619

Xinjiang

9.11

1 770

Guangdong

5.05

3 165

Guangxi

7.41

1 669

Hainan

8.84

894

Source: Calculated by the authors.

It should be mentioned that the potential application value of the above model is that farmland conversion between 1989 and 1996 is inefficient according to the marginal revenue between 1997 and 2003, which means the farmland protection policy after 1996 in China did improve the efficient generational allocation of farmland conversion. But the result does not offer the evidence that we should convert more farmland after 1996, because we do not know whether the marginal revenue is as equal as the later period, say 20042010. We cannot draw the conclusion until we reach 2010 and test the reality data again. So at this moment we’d better keep the same rate of farmland conversion like 19972003, and check it after 2010. If the marginal revenue of 19972003 was higher than that of 20042010, then we can convert more farmland for the equal revenue principle

requirement, otherwise we should control more strictly on the farmland conversion than in 19972003. Under this rule, farmland conversion will converge gradually at the efficient standard.

5

Conclusions

This paper sets up a model to measure the intergenerational efficiency of farmland conversion in China between 19891996 and 19972003. The finding of this paper is that if the sample range was set from 1989 to 2003, there would exist an over conversion of farmland resource on intergenerational allocation before 1996. The over-conversion ratios of the eastern, central and western regions are 6.58%, 6.84% and 7.85% to each total conversion amount respectively.

Tan Rong, et al / China Population, Resources and Environment, 2007, 17(3): 28–34

Although farmland conversion after 1996 was not verified to meet the efficient one, which depends on the future conversion revenue, to control the conversion speed and constrain the conversion quantity is an appropriate way to ensure the intergenerational allocation efficiency for the utilization of farmland resource nowadays.

[5] Qu, F. T., Feng, S. Y., Zhu, P. X., et al, 2004. Institutional arrangements, price system and farmland conversion. China Economics Quarterly, 1, 229248 [6] Tan, R., Qu, F. T., 2005. How to harmonize the contradiction between utilization of natural resources and the sustainable development of economy. Journal of Natural Resources, 6, 197205

References

[7] Tassone, V. C., Wessele, J., Nesci, F. S., 2002. Diverging incentives for afforestation from carbon sequestration: an eco-

[1] Chen, A. N., 2003. Approach to issues of discount rate in the utilization of natural resources. Resources Science, 3, 1316

nomic analysis of the EU afforestation program in the south of Italy. Forest Policy and Economics, 1, 567578

[2] Costanza, R., d’Arge R., R. de Groot, et al, 1997. The value of

[8] Wei, X. P., 2002. Study on problems of intergenerational alloca-

the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Nature,

tion of mineral resource. Journal of China University of Min-

387, 253260

ing & Technology (Social Sciences), 2, 7579

[3] Perman, R., Yue, M., McGilvray, J., Common, M., 2003. Natu-

[9] Winjum, J. K., Brown, S., Schlamandinger, B., 1998. Forest

ral Resource and Environmental Economics. The 3rd edition,

harvest and wood products: sources and sinks of atmospheric

Addison-Wesley Publishers, UK, 359361 [4] Qu, F. T., 2002. Resource Economics. China Agricultural Press, Beijing, 6068

carbon dioxide. Forest Science, 44, 272284 [10] Zhang, F., 1998. Environment and Natural Resources Economics. Shanghai People Press, Shanghai, 3742