0
(Kllh71XS/Y2 $5.00+(1 00 1YY2 Pergamon Press Ltd
International Production in a Volatile Regulatory Environment: the Influence of National Regulatory Policies on the Spatial Strategies of Transnational Corporations
PETER
DICKEN,*
Manchester,
U.K.
In face of the globalising strategies of transnational corporations (TNCs) it has become conventional wisdom in some quarters to regard the nation-state as an increasing irrelevance. TNCs. it is often implied, slice their way at will through national boundaries, rendering virtually all state economic policies ineffective. Although there is a kernel of truth in this viewpoint, it is a gross misrepresentation of current reality. Differential state regulatory (and deregulatory) policies in the areas of trade, industry and foreign investment remain highly significant. They are exceptionally important to the strategic behaviour of TNCs which, of course, attempt to take advantage of national differences in regulatory regimes in their pursuit of global competitive advantage. The result is a dynamic bargaining process in which each party attempts to capture the greatest gains. Current developments in the international political economy, notably the strengthening of regional economic integration in Europe and North America and the continuing GATT negotiations. are transforming the geographical scale and nature of the ‘regulatory surface’ on which TNCs operate. In exploring the relationship between regulatory environments and TNC strategies examples will be drawn from a variety of sectors, including automobiles, electronics, textiles and clothing, and pharmaceuticals. Abstract:
1. Introduction In face of the globalising strategies of transnational corporations (TNCs) it has become conventional wisdom in some ‘quarters to regard the nation-state as increasingly irrelevant to economic activity at the global scale. TNCs. it is often implied, slice their way at will through national boundaries, rendering virtually all state economic policies ineffectual. Although there is a kernel of truth in this viewpoint it is a gross misrepresentation of current reality. In fact, there is a renewed recognition, among writers across
“School of Geography, University of Manchester, Road, Manchester Ml3 YPL, U.K.
a broad spectrum of ideological positions, that the state’s role, though much changed by the increasing complexity of both its internal and external relations, remains highly significant as one of the primary shapers of the global economy. For example, BINA and YAGHMAIAN (1991), CERNY (1991), PICCIOTTO (1991), PITELIS (1991) and POOLEY (1991) all eschew the notion that the nation-state is no longer a significant global actor. From a different perspective, PORTER (1990) argues strongly that the nation-state is an especially important ‘container’ of the various sources of corporate competitive advantage within the global economy. Differential state regulatory (and deregulatory) policies in the areas of trade, industry and foreign invest-
Oxford
303
304
Geoforum/Volume
merit, therefore, remain highly significant. They are exceptionally important to the strategic behaviour of TNCs which, of course, attempt to take advantage of national
differences
in regulatory
pursuit of global competitive developments in the international
regimes
in their
advantage. Current political economy,
industry
cases to provide
23 Number
more concrete
3/1992
examples
of
the trends discussed in the main body of this paper. It is important to emphasis that this paper is not an attempt to provide a regulationist explanation of current developments. Although the kinds of concrete regulatory policy discussed are certainly part of
notably the strengthening of regional economic intergration in Europe and North America and the
the mode of social regulation and TNC strategies part of the regime of accumulation, development
continuing GATT negotiations in the Uruguay Round, are transforming the geographical scale and nature of the ‘regulatory surface’ on which TNCs
regulation theory at the international scale is, so far, very limited [see, for example, PECK and TICKELL
are of
(1992)].
operate.
The result
is a dynamic
bargaining
process
in which
each party attempts to capture the greatest gains. The notion that the changing structure of the global economy is the outcome of a complex combination of processes involving both TNCs and states is increasingly widely accepted across the political spectrum. Thus, GORDON (1988, p. 64) argues that “TNCs are neither all-powerful nor fully equipped to shape a new world economy by themselves” whilst OSTRY (1990, p. 1) asserts that “the international environment of the coming decades will be shaped not by governments or international institutions but by the interaction of the two main actors, governments and global corporations-especially in the Triad: the United
States,
Europe
and Japan”.
The purpose of this paper is to explore some aspects of this interaction from the perspective of the influence of national regulatory policies on the spatial strategies of TNCs. The discussion is divided into three sections. In Section 2, a general overview of regulation in the global economy is provided with particular reference to major types of regulatory activity and to significant recent developments in the regulatory environment, notably the increasing convergence of separate regulatory strands within a ‘strategic’ policy framework and the growing trend towards regional integration in the global economy. Section 3 focuses upon the interaction between states and TNCs as each strives to enhance its own competitive position in a volatile and increasingly competitive environment. It also examines trends in the strategic behaviour of TNCs and the diversification of modes of international involvement as companies strive to reconcile the tension between globalising and localising forces. Section 4 consists of some very brief
2. Regulatory
Structures
in the Global Economy
The regulatory environment facing TNCs is exceptionally complex both in terms of the kinds of activities under regulatory control and in terms of the geographical scale at which such regulatory structures operate. In this paper, attention is focused on three types of regulation: those relating to trade, foreign investment and industry-specific policies [see DICKEN (1992a, Chap. 6) for a detailed discussion of these policy areas]. With the exception of trade, which is the one area of the three to operate within an international regulatory framework (the GATT) the primary scale of operation is the nation-state. However, the recent trend towards the strengthening of regional economic groupings is introducing a new meso-level of regulation of profound significance for TNC activity. It is widely accepted that the mode of international economic regulation, and especially the general stability of that mode, is driven primarily by the existence of a hegemonic power which has the political and economic clout both to initiate, and to ensure the maintenance of, the regulatory mechanisms. The role of the United Kingdom and, subsequently, of the U.S. as the global hegemon has been extensively documented. Today, however, the U.S. hegemonic role has been eroded (GILPIN, 1987; KENNEDY, 1987; MacEWAN and TABB, 1989). We appear to be in a phase of transition to a multipolar economy captured, at lcast crudely, by OHMAE’s (1985) concept of the global triad. For the TNC, the two most critical aspects of state regulatory policy are, first, nccess to markets and/or resources (including human resources) and, second.
Geoforum/Volume ruks ofoperation
23 Number
305
311992
for fn-ms operating
within particular
national (or supranational) jurisdictions. The primary regulatory mechanisms governing access to markets is, of course, trade policy. This is both the longest-standing mechanism of state regulation of international economic activity and also the only one which is set within an international institutional framework, the GATT. Currently, however, the entire GATT structure is itself in some confusion as the most comprehensive and ambitious GA?T negotiations
ever attempted-the
Uruguay
Round-are
meet
to filter out those investments national
of
access
to
markets
which do
whether
social or political. Foreign firms excluded entirely from particularly
economic,
may in fact be sensitive sectors
of the economy or the degree of foreign involvement may be restricted. The operations of those firms which have been allowed a physical presence may be regulated in a whole variety of ways including, in particular, the operation of local content requirements,
export
locally-derived regulation
objectives,
levels,
rules governing
the export
profits or capital and the levels and methods
in disarray. National
mechanisms not
via
imports-the traditional mode of entry before the deveIopment of direct presence by TNCs-is achieved through the use of either tariffs or nontariff barriers (NT&). Through the successive GATT rounds since the late 1940s the average tariff level has fallen dramatically, from an average of 40% in 1947 to around 5% today. This liberalisation of international trade, at least until the oil price shocks of the 197Os, coincided with, and contributed substantially towards, the remarkable growth of the world economy. In recent years, however, although tariff levels have continued to fall overall, NT3s have proliferated, both in the frequency with which they are being introduced and in their diversity of form. A plethora of import barriers ‘has been invented, the most important of which are the various forms of import quota (often euphemistically termed ‘voluntary’ export restraints). Governments have displayed considerable ingenuity in devising other more subtle, and often less transparent, trade restrictions. BHAGWATI (1988) divides such NTBs into two categories-‘high track’ and ‘low track’ restraintsaccording to their relationships with GATT rules. It has been estimated that NTBs now apply to more than a quarter of all industrialised country imports [see KOSTECKI (1987) for a detailed analysis covering the 1986-l 987 period]. In addition, there has been a surge in anti-dumping regulations by several states, notably Australia, the U.S., Canada and the European Community (EC). A second group of regulatory policies, those relating to inward foreign direct investment (FDI), are concerned with both access and rules of operation. In controlling access, that is regulating the entry of foreign firms, governments may operate screening
of
of taxing
profits.
In the case of foreign investment, there national body comparable to the GATT
is no interwhich pro-
vides a set of rules for international investment. The Uruguay Round negotiations do include attempts to establish a set of ‘trade-related investment measures’ (TRIMS). Major home countries of TNCs, notably the lJ .S., wish to prohibit or restrict such measures as local content rules and others which are believed to discriminate against foreign firms. The argument is that such measures distort or restrict trade. The opponents of TRIMS, particularly the developing countries, see such measures as essential elements of their economic development strategies. They, in turn, wish to see a tightening of the regulations against what they regard as the restrictive business practices of TNCs. Although few states operate a totally closed policy towards inward FDI, the actual degree of openness varies considerably. In general, developed market economies tend to be less restrictive in their policies towards foreign investment than developing market economies. One obvious reason is that the developed economies are the major sources of, as well as the dominant ~Iestin~~ti~~ns for, the world’s FDI. A third group of policies which directly or indirectly impinge upon the spatial strategies of TNCs are industry policies. Most governments have some kind of policy whose aim is to regulate and/or stimulate industrial activity within its jurisdiction and, therefore, to enhance its internationally competitive position. The tool box of industry policies is extremely diverse, ranging from the obvious one of financial and fiscal incentives, through state procurement policies, technology policies, policies to encourage industrial restructuring, to regulate mergers and influence
306
Geoforum/Volume
industrial structure, to regulate and so on. The list of possibilities
the labour market, is very long indeed.
Such policies (some of which are specifically designed to stimulate industrial activity, others explicitly to regulate such activity) may be applied either generally across the whole of a nation’s commonly,
applied
of firm or designated
selectively
geographical
The specific policy mix adopted
industry
or, more
by specific sector,
type
area.
by a number
of significant variables including: the nation’s political and cultural complexion and the strength of institutions and interest groups; the size of the national economy, especially that of the domestic market; the nation’s resource endowment, both physical and human; the nation’s relative position in the global economy. JOHNSON (1982, pp. 19-20) draws a distinction between two different ‘ideal type’ models of state policy stance: A regulatory, or market-rational, state concerns itself with the forms and procedures--the rules, if you willof economic competition, but it does not concern itself with substantive matters. For example, the United States government has many regulations concerning the antitrust implications of the size of firms, but it does not concern itself with what industries ought to exist and what industries are no longer needed. The dcvelopmental, or plan-rational, state, by contrast has as its dominant features precisely the setting of such substantive social and economic goals The government will give greatest precedence to industrial policy, that is. to a concern with the structure of domestic industry and with promoting the structure that enhances the nation’s intcrnational competitiveness. The very existence of an industrial policy implies a strategic, or goal-oriented. approach to the economy. On the other hand, the market-rational state usually will not even have an industrial policy (or, at any rate, will not recognise it as such). Instead, both its domestic and foreign economic policy, including its trade policy, will stress rules and reciprocal concessions (although perhaps influenced by some goals that are not industrially specific, goals such as price stability or full employment). to find examples of developmental states in today’s world than of pure regulatory states, although countries like the U.S. and the United Kingdom are more regulatory than developmental in their current policy stances. But, certainly, virtually all the newly industrialising countries (NICs), including those in East and South East Asia, and, u fortiori, Japan itself, are undoubtedly developmental states. Despite some prevailing views to the contrary, there It is far
easier
3/1992
that the role of the state in the NICs has
been a central driving force in their economic development, although not in a uniform manner. Even though it may be more valid to see the developmental state and the market-rational/regulatory state as two types
at the far ends
nevertheless,
ideal
not unreasonable
the current
by a state will tend to
vary over time and also to be influenced
is no doubt
23 Number
economy between
politico-economic
of a continuum to interpret tensions
it is. many of
in the global
as being as least partly a reflection of a clash these two different models of state behav-
iour. Of course,
these three areas of regulatory
trade, FDI and industry policies-are set in totally separate boxes. Indeed,
activity-
not, in reality, the fundamental
feature of the developmental state is its use of all three policy strands as part of a developmental strategy. However, one of the most significant developments of the past few years is the growing demand within such market-rational states as the U.S. for a strategic policy stance. Rather misleadingly, the term used to express this orientation is ‘strategic trade policy’ (STP). But, by definition, STP involves far more than just trade policy. In the U.S. case, for example, it encompasses issues of strategic industry policy and, by extension, FDI policy as well as trade policy. Comprehensive reviews of the literature on ‘STP’ are provided by STEGEMANN (1989), COHEN (1990), OSTRY (1990) and RICHARDSON (1990). The demand in the U.S. in particular is for a shift away from ‘free’ trade towards ‘fair’ trade-‘fairness’ being defined by the U.S.! An early sign of this shift in emphasis was apparent in the 1974 U.S. Trade Act. However, it became quite explicit in the 1988 Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act, especially in the so-called ‘super 301’ clause which aims to achieve reciprocal access to what the U.S. defines as unfairly restricted markets. The difference between the 1974 and 1988 acts is that the 301 clause is now applied to entire countries and not, as before, to specific industries. In relation to Japan, the U.S. has also negotiated a Structural Impediments Initiative whose aim is to remove what are seen by the U.S. as structural restrictions on access to the Japanese market. These shifts towards a more strategic policy are particularly evident in the high-technology sectors which are seen to be at the centre of a country’s future competitive position. The basic rationale is that, in imperfectly
Geoforum/Volume competitive
23 Number
markets
governments
307
3/1992 must intervene
in
favour of their domestic firms. As OSTRY (1990, p. 6) points out, the argument is based upon two issues: “the ‘first mover advantage’ that a country or firm captures by preempting foreign rivals . . . (which) . . . provides the opportunity for firms and countries to consolidate and extend their competitive advantage”, overs which
and the issue of externalities enhance the competitiveness
parts of the domestic Hence, one important regulatory environment
or spillof other
economy. change in the international is this increased emphasis on
competitive strategic policies. A second major development in the last 12 years or so has been the trend towards the deregulation of certain economic activities. As CERNY (1991, p. 173) observes, ‘deregulation’ emerged as a major phenomenon in many industriahsed countries during the 1980s: The concept of deregulation-as it has been used by most commentators, whether politicians, journalists or academics-is deceptively simple. It means the lifting or abolishing of government regulations on a range of economic activities in order to allow markets to work more freely, as in classical capitalist economic theory. Proponents of this image of deregulation believe that government regulations have come to distort the efficient working of markets. Deregulation of this sort has been intended, firstly, to reduce the costs of conforming with regulations these costs are thought to more than counterweigh the social, economic and political benefits of the particular regulations in question. In addition, even relatively ‘costless’ regulations are often seen as counterproductive in that they distort market actors’ calculations of allocative efficiency at the microeconomic level.
In the light of such arguments,
a variety of sectors in a number of countries-notably telecommunications and financial services-have been, or are being, deregulated. However, as Cerny points out, the issues are, in fact, extremely complex. In particular, deregulation at the national scale has to be seen in its wider, international, context. In fact, “deregulation cannot take place without the creation of new regulations to replace the old” (CERNY, 1991, p. 174). In effect, what is often termed deregulation is really ‘reregulation’. This interpretations is especially apparent in the context of the third major development in the international regulatory environment: the strengthening
of regional
economic
the 1980s witnessed opments complete
integration. two extremely
The final years of significant
devel-
in this regard. The first was the process to the Single European Market by the end of
1992. The second was the signing of the CanadaUnited States Free Trade Agreement and the initiation of negotiations to create a North American Free Trade Area involving, in the first instance, Mexico. Some observers see these developments as a kind of concerted move to restructure the global economy into three major regional economic blocs. OSTRY (1990, p. 12), however, argues that “the coincidence in timing is accidental, not planned” and points out that “the FTA and Europe 1992 are very different in both genesis and nature”. Nevertheless, the emergence of changed and strengthened regional blocs greatly alters the nature of the international regulatory surface on which TNCS operate. But it does so in complex, and often uncertain, ways. Both regional agreements will take several years to implement fully the enormous reforms needed to change existing regulatory structures. The move to the new, enlarged, scale of regulation is far from straightforward and, in the transitional period, the regulations regarding access and operations will become more difficult to cope with. Major conflicts have developed between the U.S. and the EC on the one hand over market access issues (WOOLCOCK, 1991), and, on the other, between the EC and Japan and some Asian countries over anti-dumping measures. In summary, the changing regulatory structures in the global economy in the areas of trade, foreign investment and industry policy are a reflection of the increasingly intensive competitive position in which nation-states now find themselves. In an increasingly integrated and interdependent global economy nation-states are engaged in fierce competitive rivalry. In CERNY’s (1991, p. 183) view, the nationstate is a ‘competition state’ whose problem is one of facing “major adjustments to shifts in competitive advantage in the global market place”. PORTER (1990, p. 19) argues strongly that “competitive advantage is created and sustained through a highly localised process. Differences in national economic structures, values, cultures, institutions and histories contribute profoundly to competitive success . . While globalisation of competition might appear to make the nation less important, instead it seems to
Geoforum/Volume
308 make it more so. With fewer impediments to trade to shelter uncompetitive domestic firms and industries, the home nation takes on growing significance hecause it is the source of the skills and technology that underpin competitive advantage.” Of course, a major component of the competitive struggle between states is their relationships with TNCs whose spatial strategies, regulatory
in turn, are strongly behaviour.
influenced
by state
23 Number
30992
structures in the global economy we need to keep in mind the fundamental nature of the relationships between TNCs and states. In the specific case of regulation, the most obvious assumption would be that TNCs will invariably seek the removal of all regulatory barriers which act as constraints and impede their ability to locate wherever, and to behave however, they wish. Removal of all barriers to entry, whether to imports or to direct presence; freedom to export capital and profits from
3. Regulatory
Structures
Oppo~unities: Nation-states
interactions
as Constraints between
and
TNCs and
While states are engaged in competition with other states to enhance their position they are also locked into compiex interactions with TNCs. This relationship cannot be reduced to the simple universal generalisation that, in such interaction, the power invariably lies with the TNC. It is, however, given the fundamental differences between their specific goals, inevitably an uneasy relationship which tends to Auctuate between conflict and cooperation and may be extremely variable between different sectors of the economy. As GORDON (1988, p. 61) observes, “it is perhaps most useful . to view the relationship between multinationals and governments as both cooperative and competing, both supportive and conflictual. They operate in a fully dialectical relationship, locked into unified but contradictory roles and position, neither the one nor the other partner clearly or completely able to dominate.” PITELTS (1991, p, 142) proposes that the relationship between TNCs and nation-states should be analysed within a rivalry and collusion framework, arguing that “the degree of rivalry and collusion will depend heavily on whether the relationship refers to TNCs’ own states or ‘host’ states, as well as whether the states in question are ‘strong’ or ‘weak’, DCs or LDCs”. Whether or not a particular situation is one of rivalry or collusion the essence of the TNC-state relationship is one of overt or covert bargaining. As NIXSON (198S, p. 378) points out, “it is this process that in large part determines the extent, nature and distribution between the participating agents of the costs and benefits that arise as a result of direct foreign investment”. Thus, in considering TNC attitudes and responses towards different regulatory
local operations; freedom to import materials, components and corporate services; freedom to operate unhindered in local labour markets-these would all seem to be the ultimate preference for TNCs. Certainly, given the existence of differential regulatory structures in the global economy, TNCs will seek to overcome, circumvent or subvert them. Regulatory mechanisms are, indeed, constraints to a TNCs’ strategic and operational behaviour. Yet it is not quite as simple as this. The very existence of regulatory structures can be perceived as an oppor~~~jr~ available to TNCs to take advantage of regulatory differences between states by shifting activities between locations according to differentials in the regulatory surface. Clearly, this is not an option which is available to purely domestic firms. AS we shall see later, TNCs do indeed engage in regulatory avoidance. Other things being equal, therefore, TNCs will be attracted to countries where the treatment of foreign firms is liberal rather than restrictive. Where regulatory differences do exist, TNCS may well use them in their n~g~?tiations with g~~vernments, particularly where the latter are anxious to attract specific TNC investments. Such competitive bidding between states (and between regions and communities within states) to attract TNC investment has undoubtedly intensi~ed in recent years (DICKEN, 19911). Several writers have pointed to the fact that TNCS have a somewhat ambivalent attitude to state regulatory policies. For example, PICCIOTTO (1991, pp. 43,46) points out that: TNCs have
favoured minimal international coordination while strongly supporting the national state, since they can take advantage of regulatory differences and loopholes. . While TNCs have pressed for an adequate
GeoforumNolume
23 Number
309
30992
coordination of national regulation, they have generally resisted any strengthening of international state structures. Indeed, the emergence of internationalised ownership of capital through such international corporate groups resulted from the existence of national protectionist regulation: not only tariffs, but national procurement and national protection of scientific innovation. Having secured the minimalist principles of national treatment for foreign-owned capital, TNCs have been the staunchest defenders of the national state. It is their ability to exploit national differences, both politically and economically, that gives them their competitive advantage.
More specifically, present a detailed will tend
YOFFIE argument
increasingly
and MTLNER (1989) to the effect that TNCs
to support
a strategic
trade
policy in their home country with the expectation that this will open up market access in foreign countries and enable them to benefit from large-scale economies and learning curve effects. Such general comments should not create an impression of a uniform response among TNCs to regulatory differentials although there are some kinds of regulation which will tend to produce a fairly general reaction. For example, all TNCs will engage in transfer pricing in order to take advantage of inter-nation differences in taxation levels and regulations (LALL, 1973; MURRAY, 1981; UNCTC, 1988). But, for the most part, responses to regulatory differences are contingent upon specific circumstances in which particular TNC strategies are especially significant. Some of the most influential ideas on a firm’s competitive strategy have been developed by PORTER (1985, 1986). According to Porter, business firms will seek to achieve a competitive advantage in their particular industry through the pursuit of one of three ‘generic strategies’: cost leadership, differentiation or focus (niche). At an international scale, both Porter and DOZ (1986) argue that industries exist along a competitive-scope spectrum ranging from multidomestic at one end of the spectrum to global at the other. Prior to the 196Os, most TNCs invariably pursued a multidomestic (or nationallyresponsive) strategy in their international operations whereby autonomous national subsidiaries served individual national markets. TNCs capitalised on their ownership-specific advantages and transferred intangible assets (through the internalisation of markets for intermediate goods) to their overseas subsidiaries. This could be done very cheaply-
effectively
at marginal
seas plants
cost-once
was established
a network
(DOZ,
1986).
of overConse-
quently, these affiliates possessed a number of competitive advantages compared with purely domestic firms, enabling them to compete very effectively in specific national markets. The domestic or nationally-responsive
essence of a multistrategy is an inter-
national network of commonly owned, but quasiindependent, operations, each of which is responsive to the characteristics of individual national markets. This kind of international extremely investment gionally
competitive
strategy
is still
common among TNCs. Most foreign direct remains oriented towards national or recompact
markets
(THOMSEN,
1992). But a
growing number of TNCS, most notably (although not exclusively) the larger ones, have been developing globally integrated competitive strategies in pursuit either of economies of scale or economies of scope and coordination. Categorising industries (or firms) into these two polar opposites is clearly a severe distortion of reality. It suggests two mutually exclusive strategic orientations whereas, in fact, each must contain elements of the other. Firms operating in so-called multidomestic industries must take account of global forces while, conversely, firms operating in global industries must be responsive to national and local differences. The intensification of global competition in a world which still retains a high degree of local differentiation creates, for all TNCs, an internal tension between globalisation forces on the one hand and localisation forces on the other (BARTLETT and GHOSHAL, 1987). These pressures greatly complicate the nature of the responses of TNCs to regulatory differences between states. Such complications are intensified by the fact that the global-local tension applies at each stage of the firm’s production (or value-added) chain. Spatial variations in regulatory structures will surely influence (though are unlikely to determine) the extent to which the production chain is integrated or disintegrated geographically. As Porter has shown, international competitive strategies involve both the organisational coordination of a firm’s activities within the production chain and also their geographical configuration. Different regulatory structures, therefore, will have different implications according to a firm’s position in this two-dimensional space.
310
Geoforum/Volume
Whether
or not a specific regulatory
mechanism
is a
even to dismantle,
23 Number
the MNC integrated
311992
manufactur-
constraint or an opportunity will depend, at least in part, on whether the firm is pursuing a nationally-
ing and trade networks restrictions on foreign
responsive or a globally-integrated strategy. For example, the primary requirement for a firm pursuing a nationally-responsive marketing strategy is unhin-
access”. In such circumstances, what matters is the relative bargaining power of the state on the one hand and the TNC on the other. The relative bargaining power of TNCs and host countries is a function of
dered
access to its target
markets.
Regulatory
bar-
riers, such as tariffs or NTBs, will usually stimulate
a
response by which the firm sets up operations within the regulated market. The picture is complicated in regional
economic
groupings,
such as the EC prior to
the completion of the Single Market, where there are differential regulatory barriers affecting a firm’s spatial strategy regional market
but in which access to the larger may be achieved. In these circum-
stances, firms may well member country against regulatory differences.
be able another
to play off one on the basis of
A more complex situation arises in the case of TNCs attempting to pursue a globally-integrated strategy. The essence of such a strategy is the ability to locate each part of the production chain in optimal conditions (for example, to use cheap labour for basic assembly operations). The integrated structure, therefore, consists of a complex network of managerial, research, production, marketing, distribution and service nodes linked together by intricate crossborder flows. On the one hand, such global networks provide TNCs with the potential ability to minimise regulatory constraints and maximise regulatory opportunities because they may be able to switch and reswitch their operations between alternative locations. In this sense, global firms may be able to engage in ‘regulatory arbitrage’, that is, to benefit from the differences in regulatory structures between states at a global scale. Most obviously this is the case with transfer pricing. More generally, however. the ability to engage in regulatory arbitrage is limited by the existence of fixed capital investments. The TNC’s ability to switch and reswitch activities between alternative locations is often exaggerated. Much will depend upon the extent to which TNCs set up dual or multiple sourcing arrangements on either an internalised or an externaliscd (subcontracting) basis. On the other hand, states may well have the ability to inhibit the achievements of globally-integrated strategies. As DOZ (1986, p. 39) has observed. “host governments wield the power to limit the extent of, or
three demand
related
elements
with more regulations and investments and market
(Figure
1): (1) the relative
by each of the parties for the resources
which
the other controls, (2) the constraints on each which reflect the translation of bargaining power into control over outcomes, participants.
(3) the negotiating
status of the
Conventionally, the activities of TNCs have been equated with the actual ownership of assets in more than one country. Indeed, this is the only criterion on which comparative statistical data are available at an international scale. However, as Figure 2 demonstrates, FDI. whether by greenfield investment or by acquisition and merger, is only one possible mode of foreign involvement which firms might adopt. Recognition of a diversity of modes implies a broader definition of the TNC; one which is not confined to direct equity ownership. This, indeed, has been the position of the UN Centre on Transnational Corporations whose definition has broadened substantially during the past 15 years. COWLING and SUGDEN (1987, p. 60) suggest a far more flexible definition of the TNC: “A transnational is the means ofcoordinating production from one centre of strategic decision making when this coordination takes a firm across national boundaries.”
Thus, a firm’s international involvement may well take the form not only of FDI of the conventional variety but also (and increasingly) various forms of strategic alliance (JAMES, 1985; BUSINESS INTERNATIONAL, 1987; CONTRACTOR and LORANGE, 1987; MORRIS and HERGERT, 1987; WELLS and COOKE, 1991), international subcontracting (GERMIDTS, 1980; HOLMES, 1986; UNCTC, 1988) and various forms of networking (BARTLETT. 1986). At least in part, although to varying degrees, these various modes are a response to regulatory differences in the global economy. Strategic alliances, for example, are very often a means for firms to get a foothold in tightly regulated markets by joining up with domestic firms.
Geoforum/Volume
23 Number
TRANSNATIONAL
311
3/1992 HOST
CORPORATION
Constraints
Power
resources
Power
-1 Degree of competition ant concentration in the industry
Extent to which host country government is important
resources
Negotiating -ability -_* of TNC
Capital
m countries for the investment
1
Negotiating -ability -
-1
Dependence the economv
of tic
customer or distributor
1-1
-
Political
Employment
Change
q
Constraints
-1
VI -I
COUNTRY
of
climate
1
over
time
in relative
bargaining
strength
c Relative power 01 host country vis-kvis TNC increases
Relative power of TNC vls-a-vis host country increases
Figure 1. Elements in the countries. Source: DICKEN
bargaining relationship between TNCs and host (1992a, Figure 12.5). Based upon material in KOBRIN (1987).
Mode6
of forelgn
Involvement
I
Greenfield Investment Confnbutory IllfllJf?llCeS
(Producer ser&e~ Polltlcsl Tarrfls. NT& Relative exchange rates
I-t
rl
Consumer
1
I
‘I
servrces
PolItical
Investment mxntres (ltscarllwlanclal)
Property
EPZs Labour forcC2Controls Relatrve exchange rate! Offshore assemb(y tarrfl provisrons Quota circumventron rn third counlry markets
__----------
Figure
I
2. Modes
of foreign
involvement.
Source:
DICKEN
(1992a, Figure 7.16).
312
Geoforum/Volume
4. Some fndustry Cases In this
final
developed because,
section,
some
above are applied
of the
in the final analysis,
contingency
in TNC
there
responses
cases
is a high level of
to regulatory
3/1992
example, Hong Kong firms began to shift clothing production to other Asian countries as early as the mid-1960s.
generalisations
to specific industry
23 Number
differ-
With the tightening
grip of the MFA
Hong Kong manufacturers
in the 1970s,
set up plants in the Philli-
ences. Each case illustrates, in the briefest of terms, rather different aspects of the TNC-state regulatory
pines, Thailand, Malaysia and Mauritius and, subsequently, in Indonesia and Sri Lanka to get around
interface.
quota ments
industries
manufacturing
are unique industries
In the past decade, huge investmade in China. East Asian firms
have also begun to establish plants in Europe and North America (including the Caribbean) to serve
4. I. Textiles nnd ctuthirzg These
restrictions. have been
in that they are the only
which
exist
within
an
industry-specific international regulatory framework: the Multi Fibre Arrangement (MFA). Most world trade in textiles and clothing is covered by this arrangement whose origins go back to the 1962 Long Term Arrangement initiated by the U.S. to counteract Asian imports but which was broadened into the MFA in 1974. Since then the MFA has been renegotiated several times and the intention was to incorporate it into the Uruquay Round of the GATT. The basis of the MFA is a highly complex, productspecific set of individual quotas which set precise limits on the quantity of textile and clothing which can be exported from one country to another. For every single product, a quota is specified; when exports reach that level no further trade is permitted. The MFA is the single most important measure shaping the global geography of international trade in textiles and clothing. It has had especially serious effects on the industry in developing countries. But it has also had a major influence on the locational and organisational strategies of textile and clothing firms. An inevitable consequence of the increased restrictiveness on developing country exports of textiles and clothing has been a parallel increase in efforts to circumvent the restrictions by both developed and developing country firms. Such evasive action may take a variety of forms. One method is for firms in a producing country which has reached its quota ceiling in one product to switch to another. Anotherillegal-method is the use of false labelling to change the apparent country of origin. Yet another is for firms to relocate some of their production to countries which either are not signatories to the MFA or whose quota is not fully used by indigenous producers. FOJ
developed country markets directly. country producers and retailers, likewise,
Developed have devel-
oped spatial and organisational strategies to circumvent the constraints of the MFA. The MFA, therefore, has had a major influence on both the production strategies and the sourcing strategies of firms within these industries, both manufacturers and retailers. There can be little doubt that the global shape of these industries would have been very different in the absence of this particular regulatory framework.
4.2. Automobiles Historically, the global geography of automobile production owed a great deal to its early national regulatory structures, especiaIly import tariffs. The existence of high tariffs on imported vehicles from the early days of the industry’s development led directly to major investment decisions by the leading producers. notably the U.S. companies, to build or acquire assembly and manufacturing plants in each major national market. Such nationally-responsive decisions were reinforced by technical regulations which were highly differentiated between countries. The inheritance of this regulation-driver1 pattern has been a subsequent lengthy rationalisation and restructuring of national operations to t-c-position firms in regional and global markets. Since the 197Os, however, largely because ofthe increasingly intensive cotnpetition from Japanese producers, the regulatory emphasis has shifted from tariffs to NTBs. Voluntary export restraints have been applied by the U.S. and by several European countries against Japanese automobile imports. These have, inevitably, helped to force Japanese automobile manufacturers to cstah-
Geoforum/Volume
23 Number
313
311992
lish ‘transplant’ operations there. In the European case, the regulatory environment is, of course, changing dramatically as part of the programme to complete the Single Market (DICKEN, 1992b). Physical, technical and fiscal regulatory barriers to internal trade and investment are being removed certainly benefit those major automobile
and this will firms which
currently have the most highly integrated European operations. This is simply because their ability to optimise their in-house and externalised component and vehicle sourcing strategies will be greatly enhanced by the removal of internal physical and technical
barriers.
An important
additional
regulat-
ory mechanism focuses specifically on Japanese companies. The existing bilateral ‘voluntary’ agreements to restrict Japanese automobile imports operated by five EC member states are to be replaced by a very complex (and contentious) transitional arrangement to 1999 which freezes Japanese imports but allows growth of Japanese transplant production within the EC. At the Same time. the emphasis on local content levels has been enhanced, even though there is no specific quantitative level embodied in the Treaty of Rome. In the U.S., pressure to increase local content has helped to stimulate the arrival of more than 300 Japanese component manufacturers but, so far, the same trend has not occurred in Europe.
4.3.
Semiconductors
The semiconductor industry was the first major industry in which a clear international spatial division of labour developed. Starting with the early decisions of U.S. manufacturers to move assembly operations offshore in the 1960s a global system of production has become the norm, with a clear spatial segmentation of various stages in the semiconductor production chain. The semiconductor industry became one to which the term ‘global factory’ could fairly be applied (GRUNWALD and FLAMM, 1985; HENDERSON, 1989; SCOTT and ANGEL, 1988).
government regulatory involvement. In some cases, such as Singapore, this control was exercised mainly though government influence depoliticisation of the labour state
policy
(CASTELLS
er al.,
1991). In
others, like South Korea, control of the labour market was more overtly repressive. Second, the particular nature
of U.S.
customs
regulations,
specifically
those related to the Offshore Assembly Provision, greatly facilitated the offshore movement of assembly activities
by U.S. semiconductor
companies.
During the 198Os, regulatory issues in this industry have focused more explicitly on trading relationships between
Japan
on the one hand
and the U.S.
and
Europe on the other. Two key issues have been the alleged restriction of access to the Japanese market for semiconductors and the claims that Japanese chips have been dumped in overseas markets at excessively low prices. The U.S. response, under pressure from domestic semiconductor firms, has been to negotiate a semiconductor pact with Japan, one of whose aims is to increase the U.S. share of the Japanese semiconductor market to 20%. In Europe, particular emphasis is being placed on regulating market access and on persuading both U.S. and Asian semiconduct~)r firms to locate more of their design and fabrication functions within Europe. Antidumping measures and efforts to enforce price levels (related to those of the U.S.-Japanese semiconductor pact) are clear attempts to influence the spatial strategiesof semiconductor producers. Of course, the semiconductor industry in both the U.S. and Europe is made up of both domestic and foreign companies. In both cases, ‘foreign’ companies have been prevented from participating in domestically-organised consortia such as Sematech in the U.S. and JESSI in the EC. In the latter case, for example, the British computer company, ICL, was expelled from the consortium after its takeover by the Japanese company Fujitsu.
4.4. In one sense, the spatial strategy of offshore assembly was not obviously motivated by regulatory considerations; rather it was an overt search for cheap labour. However, two important regulatory mechanisms were undoubtedly significant. First, the basis of low labour costs in most of the NICs was a high level of
housing
on wage levels, the unions, and through
PharmnceuticcrEs
The final example in this brief review of specific industry cases is the most closely regulated of all. Whereas in the other industries discussed differentials on the regulatory surface are important they are rarely overwhelmingly so. In pharmaceuticals, the
314
Geoforum/Volume
regulatory framework tal to their competitive same
time,
facing producers is fundamenand spatial strategies, At the
pharmaceuticals
is an industry
which,
rather like semiconductors, can be separated into a series of discrete stages of production whose individual spatial orientations differ. It is also one of the most highly R and D intensive industries, driven by the uncertainty producing
and very long lead times involved
and marketing
cessful drug (BRECH
a new, commercially
and SHARP,
in suc-
1984).
ensure
a financial
countries,
states-has played, and continues to play, a critical role in the industry’s spatial organisation at a global scale. Pharmaceuticals production exists within a very stringent and complex political and regulatory environment. Before a drug can be put on the market it has to be subjected to very thorough, expensive and time-consuming pre-clinical trials. The time taken for this process varies widely from one country to another but can be up to 10 years. In addition, in most countries the major customer for drugs, in the sense of who picks up the bill, is either the state or a stateregulated private agency. Differentials in health care policies between countries are, therefore, extremely important to the strategies of pharmaceutical companies. These regulatory devices act as NTBs to trade in pharmaceuticals, creating quite distinctive national markets.
especially
between
and devel-
oping countries. Similarly, there are national variations in the time involved
wide interin the drug
approval process. It has been estimated, for example, that the process in the U.S. takes roughly twice as long as in Europe. One result of this regulatory has been to encourage
countries
and
U.S. pharmaceuti-
to invest in R and D in certain to perform
clinical trials and drug differences in government
the complex approval policies
overseas process
of
abroad. Finally, towards the intro-
duction and marketing of generic drugs poses a further regulatory factor in the strategic decisionmaking processes of pharmaceutical firms. Again, as in other industries, the planned completion of the Single European Market will drastically change the regulatory surface on which pharmaceutical companies operate. When a single drug approval process is eventually implemented across the entire EC then, at least potentially, the spatial strategies of pharmaceutical companies may well change and the close physical tie with individual national markets may be broken. However, there is a long way to go before that stage is reached.
5. Conclusion
The stage of pharmaceuticals production which has been most responsive to regulatory differentials is the final stage of drug formulation and packaging. Pharmaceutical companies have invariably located this stage in accordance with state regulatory pressures. In many cases, a drug needs to be ‘produced’ in a specific country in order to be acceptable to the regulatory authorities and, therefore, to be marketable there. Many countries place restrictions on the import of made-up drugs. A common practice, therefore, is for the R and D and bulk production of drug components to be concentrated either in the firm’s home country or in a small number of other technologically advanced countries, and for the final stages to be spatially distributed in response to marketaccess regulations.
Drug companies
invest-
developed
difference
structure of the pharmaceutiis highly variable between
on the enormous
311992
ments made in R and D. However, the level and duration of patent protection varies widely between
cal companies The specific regulatory cal industry-which
return
23 Number
rely heavily
on patent
protection
to
This paper has endeavoured to explore the influence of national regulatory policies on the spatial strategies of transnational corporations. As shown this is, in fact, a two-way process. On the one hand, TNCs respond to differentials in the regulatory surface: on the other hand, the changing nature of the regulatory surface itself is, at least partly, a state response to the strategies of TNCs. The scope of this paper has been limited to just three aspects of state regulation: trade, foreign investment and industry policy. But these, of course, need to be set within the broader regulatory framework at the macro-scale. The issues discussed in this paper are merely a part of the whole set of interrelationships which exist between states and TNCs. Unfortunately, the geographical literature has tended to pay scant attention to these complex. but highly significant, politico-economic interactions. Indeed, much of the literature on the new international
Geoforum/Volume
23 Number
315
30992
division of labour gives very little emphasis to the role of the state as a significant actor in shaping the contemporary global economy. There is a real need for geographers to engage in research into the interactions between states and TNCs, into the dynamic impact of changing regulatory environments, into the bargaining processes involved.
and
References BARTLETT, C. A. (1986) Building and managing the transnational, In: Competition in Global Industries, Chap. 12, M. E. Porter (Ed.). Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA. BARTLETT, C. A. and GHOSHAL, S. (1987) Managing across borders: new strategic requirements, Sloan Mgmt Rev., 7, Summer, 7-17. BHAGWATI, J. N. (1988) Protectionism. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. BINA, C. and YAGHMAIAN, B. (1991) Post war global accumulation and the transnationalisation of capital, Capital and Class, 43, 107-130. BRECH, M. and SHARP, M. (1984) Znward Investment Policy Options for the United Kingdom. Routledge, London. BUSINESS INTERNATIONAL (1987) Competitive Alliances: how to Succeed ut Cross-regional Colluborution. Business International, New York. CASTELLS, M., GOH, L. and KWOK, R. Y-W. (1991) The Shek Kip Mci Syndrome: Economic Development und Public Housing in Hong Kong and Singapore. Pion, London. CERNY. P. G. (1091) The limits of deregulation: transnational interpenetration and policy change, Eur. J. political Res., 19, 173-IY6. COHEN. B. J. (lY90) The political economy of international trade, Int. Org., 44. 261-281. CONTRACTOR F. and LORANGE, P. (1987) Cooperative Strategies in Internutionul Business. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA. COWLING, K. and SUGDEN, R. (1987) Market exchange and th’c concept of a transnational corporation. Br. Rev. ec’on. Issues, 9, 57-68. DICKEN, P. (1990) Seducing foreign investors-the competitive bidding strategies of local and regional agencies in the United Kingdom, In: Unfamiliar Territory: the Reshuping of Europeun Geography, Chap. 12, M. Hebbert and J.-C. Hansen (Eds). Avebury, Aldershot. DICKEN, P. (1992a) Global Shift: the Internationalization of Economic Activity, 2nd Edn. Paul Chapman, London. Guilford Publications, New York. DICKEN, P. (1992b) Europe 1992 and strategic change in the international automobile industry, Envir. Plunn. A, 24. 11-31. DOZ. Y. (1986) Strategic Management in Multinational Companies. Pergamon Press, Oxford. GERMIDIS, D. (Ed.) (1980) International Subcontracting: a New Form of Investment. OECD, Paris. GILPIN, R. (1987) The Political Economy of International Relations. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
GORDON, D. M. (1988) The global economy: new edifice or crumbling foundations?, New Left Rev., 168,24-64. GRUNWALD, J. and FLAMM, K. (1985) The Global Factory. Brookings Institution, Washington, DC. HENDERSON, J. (1989) The Globulisation of High Technology Production. Routledge, London. HOLMES, J. (1986) The organisation and locational structure of production subcontracting, In: Production, Work and Territory: the Geographical Anatomy of Industrial Capitalism, Chap. 5, A. J. Scott and M. Storper (Eds). Allen & Unwin, London. JAMES, B. G. (1985) Alliance: the new strategic focus, Long Range Plunn., l&76-81. JOHNSON, C. (1982) MITI and the Japanese Economic Miracle: the Growth of Industry Policy, 1925-1975. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA. KENNEDY, P. (1987) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. Random House, New York. KOBRIN, S. J. (1987) Testing the bargaining hypothesis in the manufacturing sector in developing countries, Int. Org. , 41, 609-638. KOSTECKI, M. (1987) Export-restraint arrangements and trade liberalisation, Wld Econ., 10, 425-453. LALL, S. (1973) Transfer pricing by multinational manufacturing firms. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Statist., 35. 173-195. MacEWAN, A. and TABB, W. K. (1989) The economy in crisis: national power and international instability, Socialist Rev., 19, 67-Y 1. MORRIS, D. and HERGERT, M. (1987) Trends in international collaborative agreements, Columbia J. Wld Business, 22(2), 15-21. MURRAY, R. (1981) Multinutionals beyond the Market. Harvester Press, Brighton. NIXSON, F. (1988) The political economy of bargaining with transnational corporations: some preliminary observations, Munch. Pup. Dev., 4, 377-390. OHMAE, K. (1985) Triad Power: the Coming Shape of Global Competition. Free Press, New York. OSTRY, S. (1990) Governments and Corporations in a Shrinking World. Council on Foreign Relations Press, New York. PECK, J. A. and TICKELL, A. T. (1992) Regulation theory and the geographies of flexible accumulation: transitions in capital, transitions in theory, Prog. hum. Geogr., 16, lYc218. PICCIOTTO, S. (1991) The internationalisation of the state, Capital und Class, 43, 43-63. PITELIS. C. (1991) Beyond the nation-state? The transnational firm and the nation-state. Capitaland Class, 43, 131-152. POOLEY. S. (1991) The state rules, OK‘? The continuing political economy of nation-states, Capital und Class. 43,65-82. PORTER, M. E. (1985) Competitive Advantage: Creating und Sustaining Superior Performance. Free Press, New York. PORTER, M. E. (Ed.) (1986) Competition in Global lndustries. Harvard Business School Press, Boston. MA. PORTER, M. E. (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations. Macmillan, London. RICHARDSON, J. D. (1990) The political economy of strategic trade policy, Int. Org., 44, 107-135. SCO1TT, A. J. and ANGEL, D. P. (1988) The global assembly operations of US semiconductor firms: a geographical analysis, Envir. Plann. A, 20, 1047-1067.
316 STEGEMANN, K. (1989) Policy rivalry among industrial states: what can we learn from models of strategic trade policy?, ht. Org., 43, 73-100. THOMSEN, S. (1992) Integration through globalisation, Natn. Westminster Bank Q. Rev., February, 73-83. UNCTC (1988) Tramnational Corporations in World Development: Trends and Prospects. United Nations, New York. WELLS, P. E. and COOKE, P. N. (1991) The geography
Geoforum/Volume
23 Number
30992
of international strategic alliances in the telecommunications industry: the cases of Cable and Wireless, Ericsson and Fujitsu, Envir. P/am. A, 23, 87-106. WOOLCOCK, S. (1991) Market Access Issues in EC-US Relations: Trading Partners or Trading Blows? Royal Institute of International Affairs, London. YOFFIE, D. B. and MILNER, H. V. (1989) Analternative to free trade or protectionism: why corporations seek strategic trade policy, Califi Mgrnt Rev., 31, 111-131.