Carnegie-Rochester North- Holland
Conference Series on Public Policy 33 (19901
137-
168
LABOR SUPPLY WITH A MINIMUM HOURS THRESHOLD DAVID CARD Princeton University*
This paper considers the importance of minimum hours thresholds for An analysis of the interpretation of individual labor supply data. quarterly labor-supply outcomes for prime-age males in the Survey of Income and Program Participation suggests that such thresholds are an important A simple contracting model is presented aspect of weekly hours choices. that incorporates mobility costs and a nonconvexity in the relation between weekly hours and effective labor input. This nonconvexity gives rise to a two-part employment schedule. In periods of low demand, some individuals are temporarily laid off, while others work a minimum threshold level of In periods of higher demand all available workers are employed at hours. The model provides a simple hours in excess of the threshold level. interpretation for the role of demand-side variables in explaining annual It can also explain the weak correlations between labor-supply outcomes. annual hours and average hourly earnings that have emerged in earlier Under suitable assumptions on preferences, the intertemporal studies. labor-supply elasticity can be recovered from the relationship between earnings and hours per week. Estimation results for the SIPP panel yield elasticity estimates that are similar to those in the literature based on annual data. If the model is correct, however, annual labor supply is considerably more sensitive to changes in productivity than these estimates suggest.
Following the lead of Hansen (1985) and Rogerson (1988), real business cycle theorists have recently recognized the importance of distinguishing between changes in the intensity of work effort per period and changes in Although the importance of the partici-
the probability of employment.'
pation decision is widely acknowledged in studies of individual labor supply, most of the literature considers the question of participation at the
l
I also
am grateful
thank
Rochester
‘See
Robert
to
Kristin
Butcher
Miller,
Andrew
Conference
for
comments.
the
survey
recent
0167-2231/90/$03.50
by
01990
Plosser
-
for
Oswald,
assistance and
seminar
in
preparing
participants
the
data
at
Yale
for and
(1989).
Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. (North-Holland)
this the
paper. Carnegie-
I
annual of
level
annual
most
of
with
little
.L
the
or
in
of
12 months.
the
labor
based or
in
with
the
of
in of
with on the
worked,
not
expect
and
changes
data
sets
are
in
these
supply
of
fective
labor
input.
while
others
demand
all
in
mind
the
that
inquire
the
previous
Program
data
Partici-
sets,
the
The SIPP panel
composition
of
labor
the
SIPP
therefore
higher-frequen-
are
in
all
SIPP of
found
suggest
Over
of set.
worked,
be important
hours
that
work
data
weeks
to
90 percent
period
components
the
Although
hours
sample
the
number
supply.
weekly
most of
per
week
jobs
are
individuals
35 hours
contractual
Following
Rosen
between
or more per
workers
are
provides of
employment
is Heckman
a simple labor
wages. in
widely and
any
particular
analyzed
in
studies
for
the
with
the
model,
week
(1986).
excess
vary
to
of
laid
In periods
in
explanation supply
ef-
schedule.
temporarily
hours.
hours
According
Killingsworth
138
of at
labor model
and
hours
are
level
of the
worker
a two-part
employed
annual
for
per
some individuals
a minimum-threshold
model (1985),
hours
generates
demand
controlling
by
a simple
relation
nonconvexity
measures
participation
I present
the
The model
survey
of
men
in
week
threshold.
in
work
of
of
supply.
employed.
This
that
probability
other
adult
per
of
during
available
even
hours
range
employment
threshold.
Ham (1986)
for
individual
the
are
low
and
analysis
changes
threshold.
a nonconvexity
high
the
the
assumes
off,
analyze
a minimum-hours
facts
of
Unlike months.
a descriptive
a minimum-hours
In periods
Income
poorly
labor
per week during
of
four
in
questionnaires
hours
same job
they
See
one might
variation
on annual
Survey
employment,
number
variation
issue
weeks
hours
longitudinal
average
to
labor
and out
with
*The
are
released
begins
tabulations
particular.
in
if
supply.
quarterly
in
indicators,
then
decomposition
Nevertheless,
changes
annual
intra-year
opportunity
in
week whenever
the
sets
and usual
of
a unique
associated
of
components
exception.
of
on the
year.
hours, in
available
every
and changes
minimum
the
an important
of
With
weekly changes
administered
Movements
supply
average
of
recently
paper
observed
of
is
This variance
consists
is
cy changes
sources
data
The
(SIPP)
vary*
most
work
questionnaire provides
per
hours
between
research
and weeks
earnings.
these
weeks
pation
in
little
week
annual
no change
analyzing
Typically, about
per
correlation
hourly
to
surprisingly
hours
Unfortunately, suited
is
into
variation
a systematic average
There
hours
vary
female
of
of the
finding
demand-side changes
with
labor
in
employer-
supply
in
demand conditions. Until all available workers are employed, however, average hourly earnings are constant. Thus, changes in weeks worked are correlated with
demand
indicators, but may
be
independent of average
hourly
earnings. Under some restrictive (but standard) assumptions on preferences, the weekly-earnings elasticity model.
of
function
implied
hours per week
by
the
model
generates
as a conventional
the
same
wage
life-cycle labor supply
Thus, the intertemporal labor-supply elasticity can be estimated by
considering
the
relation of
average
hourly
earnings to hours per week,
although not necessarily to weeks worked. Labor-supply equations for hours per week, weeks worked, and hours per quarter are then estimated on the SIPP data. The estimation methods control for
measurement
generated
by
error
in average
conditioning
on
hourly
employment
earnings status.
and
selection
Perhaps
biases
surprisingly,
however, I obtain estimates of the intertemporal substitution elasticity in the same range as the previous literature.
I. PRELIMINARY DATA ANALYSIS To
investigate
the
characteristics
of
short-term
fluctuations
in
individual hours I have assembled a panel of observations for males age 2262 from the survey of
Income and Program Participation (SIPP).
has two important advantages over other longitudinal data sets. SIPP questionnaire annual
surveys
is administered every four months.3
in
the
Panel
Study
of
Income
The SIPP First, the
Thus, unlike the
Dynamics
(PSID)
and
the
National Longitudinal Survey (NLS), the SIPP interview schedule permits a detailed investigation of within-year variation in labor supply.
Second,
the SIPP is much larger than other longitudinal surveys: 20,000 households versus approximately 5000 in the PSID. the much
shorter
interviewed
8
or
time dimension 9
times
over
of a
These advantages are tempered by
the SIPP period
of
panel.
Each household
36 months.
Despite
is
this
limitation, the size of the panel and frequency of observation make SIPP an attractive data source for analyzing short-run hours determination. The Census Bureau does not yet make available a complete longitudinal
(1987)
?See U.S. Bureau of the Census “Survey of Income and Program Participation for complete details on the SIPP sampling frame and interview schedules.
139
Users’
Guide”
version of the SIPP panel
from
the
data.
available
I have therefore created my own longitudinal cross-sectional
The
samples.4
paper
information
is drawn
from
the
set of men with
for all waves of
the
1984 SIPP panel. To minimize
associated with
imputation errors,
complete
individuals with
of
the
The sample analyzed
merging procedure are described in the Data Appendix. in this
details
longitudinal problems
imputed responses for
earnings, usual hours per week, or weeks worked in any month of the sample have been excluded.5 with
and without
A comparison of the characteristics of individuals
data
imputations suggests
that the biases arising from
this exclusion are small.6 Finally, I have restricted the sample to individuals
who
worked
December 1985.
for pay
at
least one week
between October
1983 and
These combined exclusions generate a usable sample of 4814
men. Although weeks and earnings data are recorded on a monthly basis in the SIPP, hours per week are only recorded once for each employer over the previous four months. observations
It is therefore
on monthly
labor supply,
time
frame
is that each calendar
months
may
contain
independent
I have aggregated the monthly
An additional advantage of the quarterly
information into quarterly data. calendar
impossible to recover and
quarter
either
4
has exactly
or
13 weeks,
5 weeks.
The
whereas
staggering
of
interview dates for the four rotation groups in the SIPP panel implies that complete quarterly observations are only available from 1983-IV to 1985-IV. The
final data set therefore
contains
43,326 observations on the
labor-
supply outcomes of 4814 men in each of 9 quarters. Table
1 presents
information on the demographic
work histories of the sample.
characteristics
and
Data are presented for the sample as a whole
and for the subsample of individuals who were employed
in the first and
last quarter of the sample period and who report no change in their
4l 5
am grateful
L~llard,
“hotdeck” with
Smith
data
imputed
6The survey individuals
to
most
with
and
canmon to and
Butcher
Welch
imputation
earnings
decline
Kristin
for
(1986)
discuss
procedure.
leads
to
without
Their
significant
imputation provide
her
is
earnings imputations
for
assistance
the
limitations
findings
measurement
earnings. information. are
presented
140
with
suggest
this
task.
and
biases
that
in
inclusion
the
Census
of
Bureau
observations
error.
Roughly
15
percent
of
Comparisons
of
the
in
the
Data
Appendix.
individuals characteristics
in
each of
Table 1 Characteristics of SIPP Sample
Overall Sample
One-Employer Subsample
Demographic Characteristics 1.
Average Age
36.9
38.4
(start of panel) 2.
Percent Nonwhite
11.0
3.
Average Education
13.1
9.6 13.1
(start of panel) Employment Data for Main Job 4.
Average Weeks Worked per Quarter
11.2
12.8
5.
Average Hours per Week
41.1
42.6
6.
Average Hours Worked per Quarter
472.1
546.1
7.
Average Probability of Working
85.8
98.2
8.
Average Probability of Working
90.1
99.2
96.1
99.9
(in Quarters Worked)
in a Week (Over 117 Weeks) in a Quarter (Over 9 Quarters) 9.
Average Probability of Working in a Year (Over 2 Years)
10.
Average Hourly Earnings 1984
10.40
11.10
11.
Average Hourly Earnings 1985
10.65
11.32
12.
Sample Size
4814
2864
Note:
Sample consists of males age 22-59 as of Wave
I of the 1984 SIPP
Panel, with no imputations for earnings or hours in any wave and at least one week of paid work between October Appendix.
1983 and December 1985.
See Data
Individuals are followed for 9 quarters (1983-IV to 1985-W).
141
employer during the 9 waves of the SIPP panel.'
Approximately 60 percent
of individuals fall into the latter category. The
demographic
characteristics
of
the
sample
are
similar
very
to
those of a sample of similarly-aged men from the March Current Population Survey (CPS) who report working at some time in the previous year.8 4-11
of
the
table
contain
information
information reported for each
gleaned
from
earnings
individual's main job.
Rows
and
hours
Individuals report
working an average of 11.2 weeks per quarter, and just over 41 hours per week in those weeks in which they work.
Average hourly earnings, reported
in rows 10 and 11 of the table, are again similar to those of men in the same age group in the CPS.' The average employment rate varies
inversely with the length of the
interval used to define employment status.
Over the 27-month sample period
85.8 percent of the sample were employed in any given week, 90.1 percent in any given quarter, and 96.1 percent in either 1983 or 1984.l'
Movements in
and out of employment are clearly a more important source of variation in individual hours at higher frequencies of observation. The
contribution
of
changes
in
employment
var iation in quarterly hours of work is addressed
status
to
the
in Table 2.
total
The total
var iance in quarterly hours around individual-spec ifit means is presented in row 1.
This variance is defined as
&
v = where
Hit
(Hit - Hi)2,
&i~t
represents
the
hours worked
by
individual
i in period
t, Hi
represents the mean hours worked per quarter by i, N represents the number of individuals in the sample, and T (=9) represents the number of time
‘Inspection that
there
of
may
researchers
report
unemployment 8 the
For
(U.S.
example,
average
percent
age
is
the
sequences
both
false
scme
difficulty
Bureau
of
among
men
37.2
of
employer
transitions
and
with
the
Census
age
22-60
years,
the
the
identifiers
coding
(1989).
in
reported
unreported
pp.
the
average
of
changes employer
by in
the
identities
individuals data.
suggests Census
following
a
Bureau spell
of
16-18).
March
1985
years
of
CPS
who
completed
worked
in
the
education
is
previous
year,
13.0,
and
the
worked
in
1984
11.2.
hourly
earnings
in
the
March
1985
CPS
work
some
time
sample
of
men
age
22-60
who
$10.76.
“Recall order
is
nonwhite
‘Average are
be
to
appear
that in
individuals the
had
to
sample.
142
between
October
1983
and
December
1985
in
Table 2 Components of Variance of Quarterly Hours Around Individual-Specific Means (Standard Errors in Parentheses)
Overall Sample 1.
Unconditional Variance of Hours
16586.8 (369.9)
2.
3.
Conditional Variance of Hours
10655.5
Percent of Unconditional Variance
One-Employer Subsample
5766.9 (257.3) 4371.6
(254.1)
(194.7)
48.7
27.0
Due to Probability of Employment 4.
5.
6.
7.
Note:
14.67
Conditional Variance of Log
3.90
Hours (x100)
(-45)
(-27)
Conditional Variance of Log
4.06
1.45
Hours/Week (x100)
(-15)
(*IO)
Conditional Variance of Log
6.44
1.33
Weeks (x100)
(.2I)
(-II)
Conditional Covariance of Log
2.08
Hours/Week and Log Weeks (x100)
(-IO)
See text.
.56 (-06)
All data are deviated from individual-specific means.
143
periods per individual." the
one-employer
deviations
of
In the overall sample v = 15,587, while within
subsample
129 hours
v
and
= 76
5756.
These
estimates
hours, respectively.
imply
The
standard
corresponding
coefficients of variation are -27 and -14. For a given individual, the variance of hours can be decomposed into a component due to the conditional variance of hours, given employment, and a component
due
to
represent
the
probability
changes
in
employment
that
i
is
status.
employed
in
Specifically,
let
pi
any
let
Ht
quarter,
represent the conditional mean of hours, given that i is employed, and let v$
represent
employed.
the
conditional
Finally,
quarterly hours. vi = p.1
let
variance
represent
Vi
of
i's
hours,
the unconditional
of
that
i
variance of
is i's
Then
vc + p.1 1
(1 - p.) (H")2 1
1
-
The first term can be interpreted as the part of variance
given
hours,
given
employment,
while
Vi
due to the conditional
the second component
can
be
interpreted as the part of Vi due to the variance of employment outcomes. For the entire sample:
V = ~
The
share
of
Ci
the
Vi
1
=
~
=
~
1
average
“i
(pi
Ci
pi
VF + pi
VF
+
variance
(1 - p-) 1
1
(HF) 2),
xi Pi(l - Pi)($)
1J
in hours
due
to the
2variability
of
employment outcomes is then
s _
A Ci
Pi(l - Pi)(HF)2 V
where
Si
over
time
=
variability
“The estimated by
II
pi
(1-pi)(HF)2 /
in
i's
of
hours for
degrees individual
of
Vi
employment
freedom means.
= 4 Ci
of
the
Si,
is the share of Vi status
individual i.
This
ai
estimated
adjustment
would
percent.
144
and
ai
attributable to changes
=
Vi/V
is
the
relative
The value of this share in the
sample reduce
variance the
are
estimated
not
adjusted
variances
for in
Table
the 2
overall sample is just under 50 percent. Thus, quarter-to-quarter movements in
and
out
of
variability
of
employment hours
employment.l*
contribute
as changes
about
in the
as
much
level of
to
hours,
the
average
conditional
on
In the one-employer subsample the share is lower, as could
be expected given the much higher employment probabilities for this group. The conditional variance of hours per quarter can itself be decomposed into a component due to the variation in weeks per quarter, a component due to
the
variation
decomposition
in hours per
is
presented
week, in
and
a covariance
Table
transformation of conditional hours.
2,
based
term.
on
a
One
such
logarithmic
Let nit represent the number of weeks
of employment for individual i in quarter t, let hit represent hours per week
reported
by
i in quarter
t, and observe that Hit = nit hit-
The
conditional variance of log hours for individual i can be written as: var (log HitlHit > 0) = var (log nitlHTt > 0) + var (log nitlHit > 0)
+ 2COV
(log
nit,
log
hit
1 Hit
0).
’
Sample averages of these 4 terms are presented in rows 7-11 of Table 2.13 In both the overall sample and the one-employer subsample the covariance of weeks
worked
attributed
and
hours
per
to
weeks
equally
conditional
variance
quarter
60
is
of
percent
week and
hours in
due
the
is
positive.
hours
per
to changes
overall
If
the
covariance
week,
the
share
in weeks
sample
and
worked
50
of
is the
within
percent
in
a
the
subsample. The data in Table 2 suggest that changes in quarterly labor supply for a
given
individual
arise
from
three
sources:
movements
in and
out
of
employment for an entire quarter; changes in the numbers of weeks worked, conditional
on employment
hours per week.
in the quarter; and changes
in the number of
For individuals who worked at the same job during the
sample period, the contributions of these three components are about equal. For others, the largest share of the unconditional variance is attributable to movements in and out of employment, and the smallest share to changes in
12This attributable
13Again
share
is
to
changes
the
data
roughly in
on
similar
to
employment:
weeks
and
hours
the see
share Hansen
per
week
145
of
the
(1985,
are
variance p.
adjusted
of
311)
and
for
aggregate Coleman
quarterly
hours
(1984).
individual-specific
means.
hours per week.14 Further insight into the nature of hours variation is provided by the cross-tabulations
in Table 3.
Each row of the table gives the percentage
of individuals with a particular range of hours per week during the sample period.
The first 4 rows give the percentages of individuals who report
the same hours per week in all 9 quarters, while the next rows give the percentages
of
individuals with
some variation in weekly hours.
In
the
overall sample 30 percent of individuals report constant weekly hours: the vast majority of these report exactly 40 hours per week.
Among individuals
with some variation in hours per week, two cases are prominent. percent report a minimum of exactly 40 hours.
About 40
Another 40 percent report a
range of hours with a minimum below 35 hours. The distribution of the range of weekly hours is slightly different in the one-employer is the
fact
subsample.
that
An interesting aspect of the table, however,
the distributions
in the overall
sample and the one-
employer subsample are very similar, conditional on the presence or absence of
weeks
of
nonemployment.
Thus
the distribution
in column
4
is very
similar to that in column 1, while the distribution in column 5 is similar to
that
in column
2.
The one-employer
group differs
from the overall
sample mainly in the likelihood of lost weeks. These tabulations suggest that some notion of a minimum threshold in the weekly hours of prime-age males is probably useful.
Three-quarters of
the overall sample and almost 90 percent of the one-employer subsample work at
least
35 hours
per week
whenever
they
Despite
are employed.
these
tendencies, a significant fraction of individuals fall below 35 hours per week
at
some
particularly
point
during
likely among
the
sample
Low
period.
one-half of these fall below 35 hours at some point. weekly-hours
threshold
weekly
hours
are
individuals who suffer weeks of nonemployment:
is
overly
restrictive,
it
Thus although a rigid is
a
useful
first
approximation, at least within jobs.
14These errors
in
calculations
weeks
worked
should and
hours
be per
interpreted week
can
since
carefully, lead
contributions.
146
to
over-
or
differential
understatement
measurement of
the
relative
Table
Individual-Specific
Range in Hours Per Week
Overall
Percent I.
2.
3.
Sample
One-Employer
Subsample
No
Some
No
Some
Weeks
Weeks
Weeks
Weeks
Lost
Lost
Al I
Lost
Lost
All
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
with:
Constant
Hours Per Week
(a)
40 hours per week
(b)
35-39
(C)
~35 hours per week
.2
Cd)
~40 hours per week
1.4
Variable
35.3
hours per week
14.5
1.2
.5
3.4
.9
26.3
36.520.2
34.4
I .2
.9
1.3.6
1.6
.2
0
.l
1.5
0
1.3
1.1
Hours Per Week
(a)
Minimum 40 hours per week
(b)
Minimum 35-39
(C)
Minimum x35 hours
per
Cd)
Minimum
per
Number
3
of
>40
Individuals
34.2
15.7
26.2
7.8
6.3
7.2
week
5.8
53.6
26.6
week
14.2
5.2
10.3
14.03.6
2719
2095
4014
2502
hours per week
hours
147
33.816.0
7.65.2
5.254.4
31.6
7.3
11.4
12.6
362
2664
II. A SIMPLE CONTRACTING MODEL WITH MINIMUM HOURS This
section
presents
a
simple
contracting
model
of
intertemporal
labor supply that captures some of the features highlighted in the previous section, while
at the same time addressing an important issue raised by Ham's findings, and
Ham's (1986) analysis of intertemporal labor supply. the
results
demand even
presented
below,
suggest
variables
are
important
controlling
for
wages.
that
industry-specific
determinants Ham
of
interprets
individual labor this
against the strict life-cycle labor-supply model. l5 here this
finding
relation between
is
interpreted
as
evidence
of
individual hours and output.
employment-
finding
as
supply, evidence
In the model presented a
nonconvexity
As noted by Rosen (1985),
this nonconvexity gives rise to a two-part employment contract. demand
states,
some
employees
temporarily laid off.
"standard
work
in the
hours,"
while
In low-
others
are
In high-demand states, all available employees work
"overtime hours," at a premium that depends on the intertemporal elasticity of
labor
prominent
supply.
Such
a
two-part
contract
is useful
spike in the distribution of weekly
to
explain
the
hours at 35-40 hours.
It
also gives a straightforward interpretation of demand-side variables in the labor-supply equation.
These appear as determinants of the probability of
employment in any particular week.
Finally, to the extent that changes in
annual
changes
hours
take
place
through
in
the
number
of
weeks
of
employment at standard hours, the two-part employment contract explains the rather weak correlations between annual hours and average hourly earnings that have emerged in previous studies-l6 The
model
is
a
straightforward
presented by Rosen (1985, Section V). firm-specific
demand
or
re-interpretation
productivity
themselves permanently to firms.
of
the
model
Consider a multi-period economy with shocks
in
which
workers
attach
In each period a firm selects the number
of employed workers, nt, and hours per employed worker, ht.
Revenues of a
particular firm are
15See and
some 16
Card of
See
nonconvexities with
relatively
(1987)
the
and
objections
Altonji
Heckman that
(1986),
can weak
explain
for the
correlations
and
have
MaCurdy
been
example. co-existence between
(1988)
raised
to
Hansen of hours
for their
further
(1985)
and
arbitrarily of
148
work
discussion
of
these
findings
interpretation.
Rogerson
elastic and
average
(1988)
point
intertemporal hourly
earnings.
labor
out
that supply
where ntf(ht) represents effective labor input in t, and et represents a demand or productivity shock.
The correct time period in this context is
the minimum
employment
period over which
naturally to a week.
Assume
decreasing returns to hours.
is fixed, and corresponds most
that f exhibits first
increasing and then
A convenient example of such a function
is
one with "start-up" costs:
f0-Q = 0, =
(ht -
hoI
0<6
ht 2 ho,
Start-up costs, or similar nonconvexities in the relation between hours per worker and effective (see below).
labor input, give rise to a minimum-hours threshold
Fixed costs of travelling to work or nonconvexities in tastes
for leisure could generate the same phenomenon. an
important
component
of
threshold-like
I suspect, however, that
behavior
is
attributable
to
technology. Assume that workers' preferences between hours of work and consumption are additively separable over time.
In addition, assume that the within-
period utility function U is additively separable in consumption, ct. and hours of work:
wt’ where
$1 = u(ct) - +(h&
u and 0 are strictly
+(O)=O.
and
Assume that a pool of workers of size no is initially attached to
the firm. employed
increasing, u is concave, o is convex,
In (nt 5
each period, a random selection nt of these are actually no),
and
the
remainder
are
temporarily
laid off.
The
expected utility earned by a representative worker is therefore
q/no U(ct.
$1 + (1 - nt/nO) U(Q, 01,
where ct denotes consumption in period t if employed, ht represents hours per employed worker in t, and Et represents the consumption of unemployed workers. Suppose that training and recruiting costs per worker are T, and that workers and the firm share a comn
discount rate 6. 149
An optimal contract
is a set of contingent functions ct(et), ct(et), nt(et), and ht(et), and an initial firm size n0 that maximizes
E Et 8t Mntf(ht),
et) - ntct - (“0 - n&l
-
TnO,
subject to
E Et 8t IntU(q,
ht) + (“0 - ntYWt,
011 2 ngV*,
and nt 5 no for all t.
Here, E denotes expectations over the joint distribution of {et, t=O,...m), taken
with
respect
to
information
available
period, and V* represents the equilibrium
in
an
initial
recruiting
value of alternative contracts
available to each worker. Let J, represent the per-worker value of the multiplier associated with the
expected
utility
constraint,
and
let
etu(et)
represent
the
present
value of the multiplier associated with the maximum employment constraint in period
t when
the demand/productivity
shock
is et.
The first-order
conditions for an optimal contract imply that consumption is constant over time and states and independent of employment or unemployment status:
ct(et)
= Q(et)
=
[u’lel (e-l).
The first-order conditions for employment and hours are
f(ht)
f’($)
Rl(ntf(ht).
Rl(ntf(ht),
et) = e+(ht)
+ ut(et),
et) = $-+‘($I.
In periods when nt < no, ut = 0 and these equations can be rewritten as
150
(1)
(2)
f’ ($1
b’(hJ
-f(ht)=xqI’ implying
that
ht
=
h*,
function
is monotonic
independent of
in 9, then
et.
17
If the marginal
there exists a critical
revenue
level of
the
demand/productivity shock, say e*, such that if et < e* then ht = h* and nt < no. while if et > e* then nt = no and ht > hf.
In low-demand states,
hours per worker are fixed and marginal adjustments to the effective labor force are met by changing the level of employment.
In high-demand states,
on the other hand, employment is constrained by the size of the available pool, and marginal changes in the effective labor force are accomplished by varying hours per worker. An
important aspect of this contract is its decentralizability.
On
the demand side, if the firm acts unilaterally to maximize profits, subject to an earnings schedule g(ht) for each employed worker, then the firm will make the jointly optimal employment and hours choices provided that g(ht) = $-+(ht),
where
1,
optimization. '*
is
the
multiplier
from
the
associated
joint
On the supply side, if workers have access to risk-neutral
savings/insurance markets, and face a contractual earnings function g(ht) = then there exists a once-for-all transfer payment from the firm
W(h&
that causes workers to supply the jointly optimal hours choice ht if they are
offered
employment
in period
t,
and
jointly optimal consumption choices."
to unilaterally
implement the
To see this, consider the problem
of choosing consumption if employed ct. hours if offered employment ht, and consumption if unemployed St to maximize
E
“The exhibit and
existence first
of
h”,
‘*This
an
increasing
+(h)=l/E
revenues
6t (nt/nO U(ct,
It
is less
with
E>1>6,
readily wage
hours
and
seen
costs,
ht) + (1 - nt/nO) U(tt,
choice
hl
then
decreasing
then
hf
by
satisfying
= E/(E-6)
the
to
earnings
the
to
and
(2)
scale.
when For
p+
= 0
requires
example,
if
that
f
f(h)=(h-ho)’
ho.
considering
subject
(1)
returns
0))
maximization function
of
the
g(ht)
discounted =
$-+(ht)
present and
value
the
of
constraint
nt
In
some
states
of
randomization
less
than
device)
full to
employment. choose
which
individual workers
151
workers are
employed
must and
still
rely
which
are
on not.
the
firm
subject to E zt at Cnt/ng ct + (1 - nt/ng) St - nt/ng g(ht)l = B,
where 6 is an initial transfer payment from the firm to each worker, and expectations
are
taken
with
respect
to
the
distribution
of
employment
levels induced by the jointly optimal contract.*' Let
x
denote
constraint.
the
multiplier
associated
with
the
lifetime
wealth
The first-order conditions for this problem include
u’(ct)
= u’(Q)
=
A
and +'(ht) = 1 g'(h+
If B is selected to allow the same consumption stream as in the jointly -1 optimal contract, then A=* , the inverse of the multiplier associated with the per-worker utility constraint the
contractual
earnings
in the optimal contract.
function
is
g(ht)=#.$(ht),
condition for hours is satisfied trivially for any ht.*' optimal
contract
is
supported
by
a
simple
Assuming that
the
first-order
Thus the jointly
earnings
function
that
is
proportional to the disutility of hours function b(h). It is interesting to compare this contractual-earnings function to the earnings
function
generated
by
a
conventional
life-cycle
problem, under a similar specification of preferences. cycle
problem,
earnings
represent
the
product
of
labor
supply
In the usual life-
hours
of
work
and
a
The first-order condition for the optimal choice
parametric wage rate wt. of hours in period t is
“This
formulation
unemployed the
21
The
Unemployed level is
A
foregone
unemployment benefits
benefits
can
be
added
or with
other no
income
change
in
Sources
the
in
the
implications
of
.
model
cho i ces
ignores Unemployment
states.
contract
in
the
leaves sense
individuals
but
more
per
unit.
leisure. Since
individuals
that are
any in
one
However, Xg(h+)
=
who level
of
sense
employed
hours
“better
employed a(h+),
are
the
wi Ii off,”
individuals shadow
leisure.
152
indifferent
because are
value
between
satisfy
of
the they
earning earnings
alternative
first-order have income, just
the
hours
conditions. same
whose offsets
consumption shadow the
value
value
of
+‘($I where
=
A~
wt,
is the marginal utility of wealth
A,
1% is set to give the same consumption stream as the jointly
If
problem.
in the life-cycle allocation
optimal contract, then 0, = JI-~.
Under this assumption the conventional
life-cycle earnings function g,(ht) satisfies
g,($)
since
+(h)
= J, ht +‘(ht)
is convex.
’
a4qJ = g0-Q.
I
However,
if $
exhibits
a
constant
elasticity,
implying that the intertemporal substitution elasticity is constant, then the contractual-earnings function is proportional to the earnings function implied by the usual life-cycle labor-supply model. Specifically, suppose that +(h) = l/~ h", where E = (l+n)/n. and @O. Then the contractual earnings function satisfies log ht= n log (gt/ht) + Constant,
where n is the conventional intertemporal substitution elasticity. the usual
life-cycle model,
however, this equation only
worked in excess of standard hours h*. week,
then
related
changes
to
weekly
labor-supply
in weekly
hours
average hourly
equation.
Monthly
If over
the firm's decision period is a and
earnings or
by
annual
relation to average hourly earnings.
Unlike
holds for hours
above
standard
a conventional
hours
bear
no
hours
are
life-cycle such
For example, if changes
simple
in annual
hours consist of changes in weeks worked at standard hours, then hours will appear to vary at fixed wage rates.
Research by Abowd and Card
(1989)
suggests that much of the measured variation in annual hours for prime-age males actually occurs at constant wages. This model can also explain the role of demand-side variables employment
growth
rates
for
an
annual labor-supply equation.
individual's
industry or
region)
(like in an
According to the model, variation in weeks
worked depends on the realization of demand shocks and is only indirectly related to average hourly earnings while employed. therefore
appear
in an annual
Demand-side variables
labor-supply equation as proxies
determinants of the number of weeks worked. 153
for the
With mobility costs and a non-
convex production technology, it is impossible to specify the labor-supply 22 equation independently of demand-side information. To model
summarize,
with
this
section
a nonconvexity
presents
a
simple
long-term contracting
in the relation between output
and hours
per
worker. This feature gives rise to a two-part contractual-hours function.
In periods of low employment demand, some individuals are temporarily laid off, while the remainder work standard hours. shift
between
earnings. employed
employment periods
In
and
of
at hours greater
unemployment
high
employment
preferences
(including
leisure within periods),
at
constant
demand,
average
all
than standard hours, with
between earnings and hours worked. on
In these states, individuals hours
individuals
a positive
are
relation
Under a set of restrictive assumptions
additive
separability
between
the contractual-earnings
consumption
and
function generates
the
same elasticity between hours and average hourly earnings as a conventional life-cycle
labor-supply
This
model.
relation
only
holds
for
hours
in
excess of standard hours and need not hold for aggregates of hours (such as annual or quarterly totals). It
is worth
preferences
noting
are
that
assumed
to
the model be
is highly
additively
restrictive.
separable
within
First,
and
across
periods, with no allowance for heterogeneity across people or over time. Second, jobs are assumed contractual-earnings
to
schedule
compulsory overtime
Third, the form of the
last indefinitely. ignores
legislation.
institutional
restrictions
I hope to be able to address
such
as
some of
these issues in future work.
III.
MODEL ESTIMATION
This section applies the model of the previous section to quarterly changes
in
According
individual
level employment earnings
labor
to the model, by
a
supply
changes
for
22
A
correlated
similar with
males
the
SIPP.
in which
in
firm-
is fixed should be related to changes in average hourly conventional
intertemporal
interpret this period of fixity as a week. longer periods
prime-age
in hours between periods substitution
elasticity.
I
Changes in labor supply between
(quarters or years) consist of changes in hours per week,
argument reported
shows
annual
how
reported
hours.
154
weeks
of
unemployment
may
be
negatively
which are necessarily correlated with average hourly earnings, and changes Therefore, if the model is correct, one
in weeks worked, which are not.
should expect larger elasticities between average hourly earnings and hours per week than between average hourly earnings and weeks worked. Before proceeding to analyze quarterly data from the SIPP panel, it is worth checking whether annual labor-supply data from the SIPP sample show similar patterns to data from the PSID and NLS. analysis
of
intertemporal
labor
supply
Since much of the previous
has
been
conducted
on
first-
differenced data, I aggregated quarterly information for the SIPP sample into
annual
data
for
1983
and
1984,
and
computed
the
variances
and
covariances of changes in annual hours, annual earnings, and average hourly earnings.
In
the
strongly
SIPP
sample,
changes
in the
logarithm of
negatively correlated with changes
in the
annual
hours
logarithm of
are
average
hourly earnings: the regression coefficient of the change in log hours on the change in log average hourly earnings is -.41, with a standard error of When potential labor market experience
.03.
is used as an instrumental
variable for the change in wages, the estimated elasticity of annual hours with respect to average hourly earnings is .87, with a standard error of -38. These elasticities are not much different from those reported by Abowd and Card (1989) for samples of men drawn from the PSID and NLS. Estimation of the simple model of the previous section is complicated by
three
issues
--
aggregation bias. properties
of
measurement
errors,
sample
selection
bias,
and
The importance of measurement error in the covariance
hours
strong
and
average
negative
hourly
correlations
earnings between
is
well-documented.23
Indeed,
the
changes
in average hourly earnings that appear in virtually every panel
changes
data study are generally attributed to measurement error. agreement on how to handle the problem.
MaCurdy (1981)
in
hours
and
There is less
proposed the use of
polynomials of age and education as instrumental variables for the change in
average
hourly
uncorrelated Even under
with this
earnings. age
and
Provided
education,
assumption,
that
these
the explanatory
are
tastes
for
legitimate
power of
leisure
such variables
extremely weak, often leading to imprecise estimates of the elasticity
23See
Altonji
(1986).
for
examPfe.
155
are
instruments. is
between hours and average hourly earnings.24 The
use
of
quarterly
alternative instrument. characterized changes
in
changes
that
future).
observations
hourly
occurred
an
opportunity
for
an
Suppose that individual employment situations are
by a match-specific
average
provides
4
seasonal productivity
earnings
quarters
will
ago
be
component.
positively
(or that occur
Then
correlated
4 quarters
with
in the
Among men in the one-employer subsample this individual-specific
seasonal
correlation
is small, but highly statistically
significant.
A
regression of the change in log average hourly earnings on the change 4 quarters yields
in the past and a set of unrestricted quarterly dummy variables
a
coefficient
important
limitation
of
-035, with
of
this
a
standard
instrument
error
is that
it
of
.007.25
An
is unavailable
individuals who did not work 4 and 5 quarters in the past.
for
In the one-
employer subsample the fraction of quarterly observations affected by this problem is small (1.4 percent). Compared to the
issue of measurement
bias has received relatively labor
s~pply.~~
With
error, the issue of selection
little attention
quarterly
data,
in the literature on male
however,
selection
bias
is
a
potentially serious problem, since many more individuals spend at least a full quarter unemployed than spend a whole year unemployed.
To see the
likely nature of the biases, consider the following equation for log hours per week of individual i in quarter t:
log hit = oi + rl log Wit + Vit'
Here, ai
refers
to
a person-
and
(3)
job-specific
constant,
Wit
refers
to
average hourly earnings in the quarter, rl is the intertemporal substitution and vit is a stochastic disturbance
elasticity,
24This variables average 25
is
hourly
26 Heckman
Note
Sample and
of
by the
the
rather
elasticity
large of
standard
changes
in
error annual
associated hours
with
with
the
respect
instrumental to
changes
in
earnings.
that
since
leisure,
evidenced
estimates
incorporating measurement
this
selection Killingsworth
correlation
seasonal
unrestricted
quarterly
is
routinely (1986)
dummies
addressed for
a recent
does are
not
in survey.
156
simply
reflect
seasonal
tastes
for
included.
the
literature
on
female
labor
supply.
See
error.
According
to the model
in Section II,
the probability that i is
employed in t, and therefore observed in the sample, depends only on the
If i is employed, hours and earnings are
state of demand at i's employer.
related by a deterministic earnings function. On this strict interpretation Uit consists solely of measurement error, and there is no selection bias (i.e., E(uitlHit>O) does not depend on
If
Wit).
hours per week and the
probability of employment share any discretionary components, however, one would expect vit to be positively correlated with the likelihood that i is In this case, the sample-selection process
employed in t.27
leads to a
negative bias in estimates of rl. Suppose that i is employed in period t if a latent random variable yit is positive, where
Yit
=
Yi
+ ZitH
-
(4)
Sit_
Here ri has the interpretation of a person- and job-specific fixed effect, Zit consists of measured covariates, and Sit is a transitory component. According to the model developed above, Zit should contain proxies for the strength
of
employment
demand
in
i's
industry
in
period
t.
In
the
application below, Zit consists of the level of employment in quarter t in i's l-digit industry. To the best of my knowledge there is no completely satisfactory method for handling the selection biases implied by (4) in the estimation of (3). The following strategy is based on a suggestion of Olsen (1980). that Sit is uniformly distributed on the interval [O,l].
Suppose
Then pit' the
probability that i is employed in t, is given by
Pit = Yi
The
parameter(s)
l
Zit”
II can
be
estimated
by
a
first-differenced
linear-
probability model applied to the actual sequence of employment indicators
*‘For individuals
example, to
reduce
sickness their
or hours
other when
soucces employed
of
taste and
157
to
variation reduce
ignored the
probability
in
the of
model
may
employment.
lead
for individual i.
Suppose in addition that
i.e., that the conditional expectation of the error component vit is linear in Sit*
Then
E(lOg hitIHit’0)
=
ai
+
n
log
=
“i
+
II
log Wit
=
where c2 = cI/2. consistently
Wit
+
CO
+
CO + Cl
(Co + ai + C2.Yi) +
+
rl
Cl
E(Fitltit
-
5
Yi
+
(Yi + ZitH)/Z
log Wit
+ c2
(Zit*)9
Given an estimate of II, say a, the parameter
estimated
by
taking
Zit”)
first-differences
of
n can be
observed
hours
choices (conditional on positive hours in t and t-l):
AIOg
hit = n AlOg Wit + C2 (AZiti)
The assumptions underlying this procedure very
least,
however,
estimates
of
c2
(5)
+ eit-
are quite restrictive.
provide
simple
evidence
At the on
the
importance of sample-selection biases in the estimation of quarterly hours equations. The
final
issue
in
estimation
of
the
model
is
the
fact
that
observations on the critical "hours per week" variable are only available quarterly.
If
hours
per week are constant within a quarter, then the model
applies directly and there is no aggregation bias. within a quarter, however, two problems arise.
If
hours
per week vary
First, recall biases and
the wording of the SIPP question on hours per week make it conceivable that some individuals report an answer like "40 hours per week" rather than a
158
Second, even if individuals correctly
precise average of weekly hours.**
an average of weekly hours, the convexity of the weekly earnings
report
function
implies
that
averages
of
hours
per
week
related to average hourly earnings by (3).*' reporting
biases
in
the
SIPP,
not
necessarily
Whatever the magnitude
these problems is more important than the second. of
are
I suspect that the first of
however,
they
are
presumably
less
troublesome than the biases in an annual survey. Estimation
results
various
for
first-differenced
labor-supply
equations fit to observations for the one-employer subsample of the SIPP data set are presented in Table 4.
Each column of the table corresponds to
a particular choice of estimation method, sample, and instrumental variable For each choice, estimation
for the change in average hourly earnings.
results are presented for three measures of labor supply: the logarithm of total quarterly hours, the logarithm of hours per week, and the logarithm Because the logarithm of quarterly hours is the sum of
of weeks worked.
the logarithms of hours per week and weeks worked, the coefficients in rows 4(i) and 5(i) sum to the coefficients in row 3(i). Two samples are constructed from the quarterly
labor-supply data of
the one-employer SIPP sample: the set of all available quarterly changes in labor supply (denoted by the column heading "All"); and the subsample of changes
for
which
in
quarters
the
a
corresponding
future
is
change
available
4 quarters
(denoted
in the
by
the
past
column
or
4
heading
Use of Alog Wit-4 or AlOg Wit+4 as an instrumental variable
"Subsample").
for Alog Wit is restricted to the subsample. Ordinary
least
squares
columns (1) and (2).
(OLS)
estimation
results
are
presented
in
The estimates are very similar in the two samples,
and suggest that changes in hours per week and changes in weeks worked are both
strongly
earnings. to
negatively
correlated
average
20In than
an
hourly
parameters
the
fact, with
average
2gThis suPPlY
is
changes
in
average
hourly
The estimated elasticity of total quarterly hours with respect is -.39,
earnings
literature based on annual data.
individuals
with
of
interviewer hours
hours
problem shorter will
SIPP
varying
arises than
differ
per
per
week
quite the
from
manual week
over
the
the
to
(U.S. report
true
similar
If of
Bureau their
preceding
generally.
periodicity
very
to
estimates
in the
It is interesting to note that the
the
parameters.
159
of “most
the
Census
frequent”
(1989)) weekly
instructs hours
rather
months.
the available
correct
“period” data,
the
for estimated
analyzing
labor
labor-supply
Table
Estimated
Hours
Equations: Fit
to
4
First
Differenced
One-Employer
(Standard
Errors
Specifications
Subsample in
Parentheses)
Estimation
Method
and
Sample
OLS
IV Sub-
I
Al
Sample:
(1)
I.
Instrumental for
Sub-
sample
Al I
Al I
(2)
(3)
(4)
EXP
EXP
--
Variable
Correction
3.
Log
Equation
Hours
Wage
(i)
(ii)
Coefficient
Selection
No
No
No
.oo
-.39
-.X3
(.Ol)
C.01)
C.50)
--
Co-
efficient
Log
Hours/Week
(i)
Wage
(ii)
Coefficient
Selection
Weeks
(ii)
.I8
-.29
-.28
C.01)
C.01)
C.36)
--
Co-
Coefficient
(7)
(8)
EWP
EWP
Awt_4 9
Selection
:
All
which Selection
log
earnings
A?+4
Yes
No
Yes
-.Ol
-.Ol
-.02
.16
.I4
(.50)
C.52)
C.52)
C.22)
C.22)
7.26
6.37
--
(1.45)
(1.58)
No
Yes
6.02 (1.27)
.I8
.22
.21
.10
.lO
t.36)
C.38)
C.38)
C.14)
C.14)
2.78
2.55
--
2.80
(1.02)
(1.16)
(.79)
-.09
-.I8
-.19
-.23
-.24
.05
.05
C.01)
C.32)
C.32)
C-33)
C.33)
(.13)
C.13)
--
-_
4.48
3.03
--
3.21
( .91)
contains in
row
average four
I,
19842
average
correction In
t-4,
C.01) Co-
sample
change
text.
tt4
AW
-.I0
efficient
in
(6)
Equation
Wage
(i)
Notes
(5)
Education
efficient
Log
Subsample
AW
Selection
5.
Subsample
Awt
2.
4.
Subsample
samp I e
is Exp hourly
quarters
observations.
hourly based
refers
earnings
on to
earnings, in
estimated
potential and
(I .02)
Subsample four
contains
quarters
in
first-differenced labor-market
Aw~_~/Aw~+~ refer
past/future.
160
19566
observations
past/future linear
experience, to
C.76)
changes
is
probability Awt
refers in
log
model: to
for
available.
the
average
see change hourly
elasticity
of
hours
per
week
is more
negative
than
the
elasticity
of
One simple explanation for this finding is that measurement errors
weeks.
are proportionally
smaller in the weeks measure
hours per week.30
Given the nature of the SIPP
than
in the measure
of
questionnaire, this seems
plausible. Instrumental variables
estimates that potentially eliminate the
(IV)
biases caused by measurement errors in hours are presented in columns (3) The estimates in columns (3)-(6) use potential labor-market
through (8).
experience (age minus education minus 5) as an instrument for the change in average hourly earnings.
The use of this instrumental variable leads to
similar results on the total sample and subsample.
In both cases the IV
estimate of the elasticity of hours per week with respect to average hourly earnings
is positive but relatively imprecise.
The
IV estimates of the
elasticity of weeks with respect to average hourly earnings are negative, but again relatively imprecise.
The elasticities of hours per week and
weeks tend to offset each other,
leading to a wage elasticity of total
quarterly hours that is close to zero. Columns
(4) and (6) combine
IV estimation with the linear selection
correction proposed in equation (3).
The first-stage equation uses changes
in the log of aggregate employment in the individual's one-digit industry as well as an unrestricted set of quarterly dummy variables to predict the change in the probability of employment. are
reasonably
strong
predictors
of
Industry-level employment changes
the
change
in
the
probability
of
employment: the t-statistic associated with the measured change in industry employment is 2.7.
Again, estimation results are similar in the complete
sample and the subsample: in all cases the estimated coefficient associated with the selection term is positive and statistically significant, although the addition of the selection term has little impact on the estimated wage elasticities.
As expected, the selection term has a larger coefficient in
the equation for the number of weeks worked than the number of hours per week, although one can reject the hypothesis that the number of hours per week
is
independent
of
average hourly earnings.
30Any error the hourly
in more
measurement log
average
negative
is
error hourly the
OLS
in
industry
demand,
controlling
for
the
level
of
The large and statistically significant estimates
log
hours
earnings. estimate
or The
of
the
weeks greater elasticity
earnings.
161
induces the
a perfectly
variance between
in the
negatively such hours
correlated
measurement
errors,
measure
average
and
of
the
selection
changes
coefficients
in demand-side
confirm
variables
the
influence
finding
of
Ham
(1986)
that
individual labor supply, even
controlling for individual wages. The earnings
last two 4
columns
quarters
in
of
table
the
past
4 use
or
instrumental variable for the change
4
the change
quarters
leading
to
a
substantial
in
the
hourly
future as an 31 This
in average hourly earnings.
instrument is more strongly correlated with earnings,
in average
the change in average hourly
reduction
in the
estimated
standard
errors associated with the wage elasticities, although little change in the point estimates.
Again, the estimated coefficients of the selection terms
are positive and statistically significant,
but their inclusion
leads to
little change in the estimated wage elasticities. Irrespective of the choice of instrumental variable, the estimates of the wage elasticity of hours per week, which can
be
interpreted
as
estimates
of
in the context of the model
the
intertemporal
substitution
elasticity, are in the same range as those obtained by MaCurdy (1981) and Altonji (1986) using annual hours data from the PSID.
There is no evidence
to suggest that analysis of quarterly observations on hours per week will lead to a new assessment elasticity.
of the
size of
the
intertemporal
substitution
Either the intertemporal labor-supply elasticity is relatively
small (on the order of estimates already in the literature), or, contrary to
the model
curvature
in Section
of
weekly
II, one cannot
earnings
recover
schedules.
its magnitude
Since
there
is
from
the
considerable
variation in weekly earnings and hours in the SIPP sample, it remains an interesting
question
how
this
variation
is
determined,
if
not
by
preferences over intertemporal labor supply.
IV. SUMMARY This
paper
begins with
a descriptive
analysis
of
short-term
hours
variation among males in the Survey of Income and Program Participation. unique
feature
of
the
SIPP
is
its
4-month
interview
schedule.
A
This
schedule permits a detailed investigation of the components of variance in individual labor supply over time.
31 the
past
I
tested or
whether
4 quarters
changes in
the
in future
wages but
are found
A simple decomposition
correlated no
162
significant
differently
with
difference.
suggests that
changes
4
quarters
in
quarter-to-quarter movements number
variation
in hours worked
arises
from three
sources:
in and out of employment for an entire quarter; changes in the
of
weeks
conditional
worked,
on
employment;
and
changes
in the
For individuals with the same employer over the
number of hours per week.
sample period, these three components contribute about equal shares to the overall variation in hours around individual-specific means. movements
For others,
in and out of employment for the entire quarter contribute the
largest share of variance, whereas changes in hours per week contribute the smallest share. Motivated
by the observation that weekly
labor supply exhibits some
minimum hours threshold, the second part of the paper constructs a simple contracting model with mobility costs and a nonconvexity in the relation between hours per worker and output.
In states
schedule.
This model generates a two-part hours
of low demand, some individuals are temporarily laid
off, while others are employed at a minimum weekly hours level. of
high
demand
all
individuals
work
hours
in
excess
of
In states
the
minimum
threshold. The contract is supported by a simple schedule relating earnings per worker to
hours per worker.
separability
additive
between
Under the assumption of within-period leisure
and
consumption,
elasticity between hours and average hourly earnings
the
implied
is the conventional
intertemporal labor supply. The model
offers
a simple
explanation
for the role of demand-side
variables in an individual labor-supply function.
According to the model,
changes in weeks worked occur at fixed average hourly earnings, reflecting the realization of employment demand.
Changes in annual measures of labor
supply, which consist in part of changes in weeks worked, will therefore be correlated
with
measures
of
employment
demand
faced
by
an
individual's
employer, even after controlling for average hourly earnings. The model
implies that estimates
of
the
intertemporal
labor-supply
elasticity can be obtained from estimates of the wage elasticity of hours per
week
for
individuals
observed
in
the
same
contract
over
time.
Estimates are constructed from quarter-to-quarter changes in labor supply for
men
with
the
same
employer
during
the
SIPP
sample
period.
The
estimation procedures take account of measurement error in average hourly earnings and possible selection biases associated with movements in and out of
employment
for an entire quarter.
Even with
these adjustments,
the
estimates of the wage elasticity of hours per week are relatively small, ranging from -10 to -22.
If the basic point of the model is correct, however, it is important 163
to realize that variation changes
in productivity
in labor supply may be much more sensitive to
than
these
estimates
suggest.
This
is because
changes in productivity have a direct effect on the fraction of individuals employed
at a given firm and on the number of weeks worked
individual.
by a given
The evidence in this paper shows that changes in weeks are a
major source of variation in individual labor supply and that these changes are highly correlated with industry-demand conditions. little
indication
that
these
changes
supply schedule.
164
occur
along
However, there is
a conventional
labor-
DATA APPENDIX The
data
from
cross-sectional
consecutive
data
sets.
A
interviews of panel
can
information from the 9 interview "waves."
be
the SIPP
are
constructed
released
by merging
as the
Individuals are identified in
each wave by a combination of three variables: the sample unit identifier, the entry address identifier, and the person number.
I merged information
for men whose age is between 22 and 62 in all waves of the 1984 panel by these
three
Department
identifiers.
of
Commerce
As
(1987),
noted
individuals
are
occasionally
assign the same series of
incorrectly
in
chapter merged,
the 6),
SIPP it
since
is the
User's
Guide
possible SIPP
(U.S.
that
interviewers
identifiers to different
people.
This is most likely to happen in the event of a marital dissolution. the other hand,
individuals who move cannot
be merged
sampling frame is based on residential location. members
to the sample as they move
some
On
because the SIPP
The SIPP also adds new
into existing sample households.
I
found 8280 individuals who reported information in 8 consecutive interviews in the 1984 SIPP panel and another 8458 individuals for whom information was missing in at least one interview.
The following table compares the
characteristics of those with complete longitudinal data and those without:
165
Comparisons of Individuals with Complete and Incomplete Data
Characteristic (at first interview)
Mean In Sample With: Complete Data
Incomplete Data
1.
Age (years)
2.
Education (years)
16.9
16.2
3.
Percent worked 4 weeks
83.9
75.5
1388.3
1208.9
8.4
10.8
38.1
40.1
in previous month 4.
Monthly earnings ($) (including zeros)
5.
Percent Black
A second significant reduction in the size of the sample occurs when individuals with imputed data on earnings, weeks worked, and hours per week Of the 8280 individuals in the sample with complete are excluded. longitudinal data, 1965 have an imputed value for one of these variables at some point in the sample. The following table compares the characteristics of those with imputed data and those without:
Comparisons of Individuals With and Without Imputed Data
Mean In Sample With: Characteristic
Imputed Data
No Imputations
40.4
40.3
1.
Age in 1986 (years)
2.
Monthly earnings (lb)excluding nonworkers:
3.
5.
September 1983
1758.8
1791.4
December 1986
1955.3
1983.6
Usual hours per week excluding nonworkers: September 1983
42.8
42.4
December 1986
43.0
42.4
Percent Black
9.7
8.1
166
REFERENCES Abowd, J. and Card, 0. (1989)
On the Covariance Structure of Earnings and Hours Changes. Econometrica,
57: 411-45.
Altonji, J. (1986)
Intertemporal Micro Data.
Substitution
in
of Political
Journal
Labor
Supply:
Economy,
Evidence
from
S176-S215.
94:
Card, 0. (1987)
Supply and Demand in the Labor Market. Princeton University Industrial Relations Section Working Paper 228.
Coleman, 1. (1984)
Essays on Aggregate Labor Market Business Cycle Fluctuations. Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, University of Chicago.
Ham, J. (1986)
Testing Whether Unemployment Represents Inter-temporal Labour Supply Behavior.
Review of Economic Studies,
53: 559-78.
Hansen, 6. (1985)
Indivisible Labor and the Business Cycle. Economics,
Journal of Monetary
16: 309-327.
Heckman, J. and MaCurdy, T. (1988)
Empirical Tests Carne-gieRochester
of Labor-Market Equilibrium: An Evaluation. Conference
Series on Public Policy,
28: 231-5.
Heckman, J. and Killingsworth, M. (1986)
Female Labor Supply: A Survey.
Orley Ashenfelter and Richard
Layard, (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics.
New York: North
Holland. Lillard, L, Smith, J., and Welch, F. (1986)
What
Do
We
Nonreporting Economy,
Really and
Know
Census
94: 489-506.
167
About
Wages?
Imputation.
The Journal
Importance of
of
Political
MaCurdy, T. (1981)
An Empirical Model of Labor Supply in a Life-Cycle Setting. Journal of Political Economy,
1059-85.
89:
Olsen, R. (1980)
A
Least
Squares
Econometrica,
Correction
for
Selectivity
Bias.
48: 1815-20.
Plosser, C. (1989)
Understanding
Real
Business
Perspectives,
3: 51-77.
Indivisible
Labor,
Cycles.
Journal of
Economic
Rogerson, R (1988)
Monetary Economics,
Lotteries,
and
Equilibrium.
Journal of
21: 3-16.
Rosen, S. (1985)
Implicit Contracts: A Survey.
Jownal of Economic
Literature,
23: 1144-75. United States Oepartment of Commerce Bureau of the Census (1987)
Survey
of
Income
and
Program
Participation
Users'
Guide.
Washington, D.C.
(19@4
SIPP 5010 Interviewer's Manual.
(1989)
The 1984 SIPP Full-Panel Research File.
168
Washington, O.C.
Washington, D.C.