On the interaction between efficiency wages and union-firm bargaining models

On the interaction between efficiency wages and union-firm bargaining models

Economics Letters 01651765/93/$06.00 41 (1993) 319-324 0 1993 Elsevier 319 Science Publishers B.V. All rights reserved On the interaction betwee...

326KB Sizes 10 Downloads 28 Views

Economics Letters 01651765/93/$06.00

41 (1993) 319-324 0 1993 Elsevier

319 Science

Publishers

B.V. All rights

reserved

On the interaction between efficiency wages and union-firm bargaining models Peter J. Sanfey* KeynesCollege, University Received Accepted

of Kent at Canterbury,

Canterbury

CT2 7NP, UK

4 March 1993 17 March 1993

Abstract Even when efficiency wage considerations are taken into account, firms may have no incentive to pay wages above the competitive minimum. The total value of output therefore may be increased if workers in the efficiency wage sector also possess bargaining power. Efficiency wage and insider-outsider models may also reinforce each other.

1. Introduction Models of efficiency wages and union-firm bargaining have achieved considerable popularity in the labour economics literature in recent years. In this paper, I outline a simple model with elements of both, and examine the following questions. First, suppose that even if workers’ effort responds positively to wage increases, firms still have no incentive to pay above the competitive, or ‘going’ rate; does the competitive solution necessarily maximize the total value of output? Second, what is the optimal level of bargaining power for workers in the efficiency wage sector? Third, do efficiency wage and insider-outsider models reinforce each other, contrary to the conclusion of Lindbeck and Snower (1991)? The model is outlined in section 2, some analytical results are derived in section 3, while section 4 concludes with a brief discussion of the implications for the current debate over ‘performance-related pay’.

2. The model There are two sectors in the economy, A and B, each with one firm. Sector A is subject to exogenous productivity shocks, and output is also a function of workers’ effort, which is variable, due perhaps to imperfect monitoring of effort, or greater morale from higher wages. Sector B, on the other hand, has no productivity shocks and constant effort level (perfect monitoring). ’ Output in both sectors is a function of labour only. Employment in both sectors lies along the * I wish to thank Alan Carruth, Andy Henley, Andrew Oswald and Jim Robinson ’ Both productivity and effort in this sector are normalized to 1.

for helpful

discussions.

320

P.J. Sanfey I Economics

Letters 41 (1993) 319-324

respective labour demand curves (the ‘right-to-manage’ assumption). Wages in sector B always adjust to clear the labour market; thus there is no unemployment. All workers are identical ex ante and, aside from the efficiency wage aspect of jobs in sector A, all jobs are identical. In sector A, the workers are unionized and wages are determined prior to employment according to a Nash-bargaining model. The specific functional forms are as follows:

QA = (eda

where

Q is output,

(1)

)

II is employment

and e is effort.

’ e is given

by

720,

e=(wlb)‘,

(3)

where w and b are the wages in sectors A and B, respectively. The interpretation of this is straightforward: workers expend effort in excess of unity (the fixed level required in sector B) if their wage exceeds the wage in sector B. ’ Clearly, T measures the elasticity of effort with respect to wages. The utility of an individual worker in either sector is given by the constant relative risk aversion form: 4 u(w) = The union

wvp.

in sector

(4)

A is utilitarian

U(w, n) = nu(w) =

and therefore

wishes

to maximize

n(wVP)

(5)

(Henceforth, II without the subscript refers to flA.) In their bargaining takes the ‘alternative’ wage, b, as given, and hence its fall-back utility

with the firm, is

the union

U* = n(b”lP) The firm in sector

(6)

A maximizes

7r = P(en)”

profits:

- wn ,

(7)

fall-back where P is the exogenous productivity shock. 5 In the event of disagreement, equal to zero. Hence, wages, employment and effort in sector A are the solution to M,“x /_Llog{n(wPIP s.t. 7rn =o,

- b’lp)}

+ (1 - /.L)( log{P(n”(wlb)“‘)

- wn}

profits

are

(8)

OS/_L’l,

wrb, ’ Clearly, the parameter LYcould take different values for each sector but nothing would be gained by assuming this below. 3 See, for example, Akerlof (1982). ‘Note that effort is not included directly in the utility function [see, for example, Layard et al. (1991, Annex 4.2)] for simplicity. Having utility functions of the form u = w - e [e.g. Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984)] or u = WI- e* (e.g. Hendricks and Kahn (1991)] may create problems when effort is a function of wages, since, on the assumption that e,, < 0. u,, > 0. ’ In order to avoid complications introduced by imperfect competition in the product market, one can think of the two sectors as operating in a world market, where world prices are taken as given.

P.J. Sanfey

where p measures following equations:

the bargaining

I Economics

power

Letters 41 (1993) 319-324

of workers

in sector

321

A. The

solution

is given

by the

(9) aPn”-‘(w/b)“’

- w = 0.

(10)

One could solve these equations, at least implicitly, for w and n as functions of (Y, p, T, P and b. However, in this two-sector model, b is determined endogenously in equilibrium by the no-employment condition. Since employment is on the labour demand curve, this implies a*B

a-l=b=a(N-n)a-l,

(11)

where N is the total labour force (n = nJ. Equations (9)-( 11) constitute three equations of output is given by V= P((wlb)‘n)”

in three

w, n and b. The total value

unknowns,

+ (N - n)” .

(12)

3. Results Equations (9)-(12) form the basis of the analysis below. Note two things: first, p = 0 implies the competitive solution i.e. the situation where workers in both sectors have no bargaining power; and second, if j.~ = 0 and r < 1, then w = b, i.e. the ‘Solow condition’ [Solow (1979)] that at a maximum, the elasticity of effort with respect to wages is equal to 1, cannot be satisfied and so wages are driven down to the competitive level. However, the key point of this paper is that even when firms have no incentive to pay wages above the minimum, the value of output to society may be increased if they can be forced or persuaded to pay higher wages in the efficiency wage sector. This is now shown in two stages: to keep things simple, P is set equal to 1. Result 1. When F = 0, dnldp Proof. From Eq. rearranging gives (w/b)

(9),

< 0.

p > 0 implies

= PI”-*‘((N

that

w > b. Putting

_ n)/n)a(‘-u)‘(‘-u’)

Eqs.

(10)

and

(11)

together

.

and

(13)

Therefore, if w > b and P = 1, (N - n) > n, and so, starting (N - n) = II, the result follows.

from

the point

where

p = 0, and

Result 2. If r > 0, the competitive solution, where p = 0, is suboptimal in this economy. Proof.

The value

of output

V= (N - n)“n’ where X = ~(1

- a)/(1

in society,

V, can be written

[using

Eqs.

(10) and (ll)]

as

+ (N - FI)~ , - W) and Y = (~(1 - r)/(l

(14) - (YT). The objective

is to show that dV/dp

> 0

322

P.J. Sanfey

I Economics

Letters 41 (1993) 319-324

when I_L= 0. Clearly, dV/dp = (aV/&z)(dnld~). shown that dV/dn
- n)x-‘ny

+ (N - n)xYny-’

dnldp

< 0 when

- a(N - n)“-’

p = 0, it remains

to be

.

(15)

p = 0 and P = 1, (N - n) = n, Eq. (15) becomes

that when

dV/dn = (Y -X)nX+Y-’ =

Since

- cxn~~l

(16)

(Y(1 - 27 + (YT) -(y n”-’ 1 - (Y7 1

1

= -(2ar(l-

(17)

- cx7))na~’ CO.

a))/(1

(18)

To recapitulate: the total value of output may be increased by paying a wage premium in the efficiency wage sector, but in this model, the only way this can be brought about some power to the workers in this sector. What is the optimal level of pu?

to workers is by giving

Result 3. The optimal level of p (when P = 1) satisfies the following equation: a7-((u - 1) 1 - (Y7

P +

Eqs. (10) and (ll),

Finding the rearrangement,

optimal value yields

-X+

in terms of n and exogenous

setting

Eq.

(15)

equal

relating

Result 4. The wage premium, Substituting

Eq.

(w’b)p =

/.A

which

establishes

variables

to zero

which,

after

some

-a{(N-n)lr~}~=O. the optimal

(21) level of n to LYand 7, and so combining

The amount of bargaining power implied by Eq. (19) could p = -1 (CRRA = 2), cy = 0.8 and r = 0.3 implies or. = 0.59. Two more results can be derived analytically:

Proof.

(19)

0.

p + a(1 - /J)(l - 7) j_l+ cr(1 - j_L)(l - r) + /.Lup((Y- 1) = O *

of n implies

Y{(N-n)ln}

This is an implicit equation and (21) gives Eq. (19).

_

=

1

Eq. (9) can be re-written

[Pn”_’ (N _ n)‘-a]p”-aT

I (a(‘-r)lD(‘-a))

41 - PL)(l_ 4

-ff [ ~++(l-j.L)(1-7)+((Y-l)/_@ Proof. Using as follows:

{(‘-m7)lP(‘-u’)

P + a(1 - P)(l - 7) /.L++(l-/_L)(l-7)+((Y-l)j_Lp

(w/b),

be considerable:

Eqs. (20)

for example,

if

is invariant to changes in P.

(13) into (20) gives El. + +

41 - P.)(l_ 7)

cw(1- /A)(1 - T) + j@((Y - 1) ’

the result,

since P drops

out of the equation.

(22)

P.J. Sanfey

I Economics

323

Letters 41 (1993) 319-324

In words, although workers in the efficiency wage sector earn a wage premium, exogenous increases in productivity are shared proportionately by both sectors, as competitive labour market theory suggests they should be. Result 5. The elasticity of wlb with respect to p, E, rises as r rises. Proof. From eq. (22), one can derive

E= /_L +

l-41-a)

(23)

(Y(1 - /J)(l - T) + /.$?((Y- 1)

Therefore

w-41- a)(1 - /J)

ae’a7 = {p+(Y(1 -

p)(l -r)

+ @((Y - l)}’ ‘O

According to this result, the elasticity of the wage premium to changes in bargaining power is greater, the more important are efficiency wage considerations. In this sense, therefore, efficiency wage and rent-sharing models complement each other, contrary to the implications of Lindbeck and Snower (1991). 6

4. Discussion Does this paper have implications for the current debate about ‘performance-related pay’? 7 Arguments in favour of this are usually based on efficiency wage ideas, and I have shown an example in this paper where the value of society’s output is increased if workers in the efficiency wage sector are paid a wage premium. However, this outcome may be achieved only if workers in this sector possess bargaining power, a conclusion which may be disconcerting for proponents of performance-related pay. Two other points arise from the model above. First, nothing in this paper vitiates the standard result that exogenous productivity gains in one sector should be shared across different sectors. In this sense, ‘going wage’ increases maintain a valid role in promoting efficiency. Second, the conclusion of Lindbeck and Snower (1991) that efficiency wage and insider-outsider models do not reinforce each other is not robust, and merits further examination.

References Akerlof, G.A., 1982, Labor contracts as partial gift exchange, Quarterly Journal of Economics 97, 543-569. Hendricks, W.E. and L.M. Kahn, 1991, Efficiency wages, monopoly unions and efficient bargaining, Economic Journal 101, 1149-1162. Layard, R., S. Nickel1 and R. Jackman, 1991, Unemployment: Macroeconomic performance and the labour market (Oxford University Press, Oxford). Lindbeck, A. and D.J. Sower, 1991, Interactions between the efficiency wage and insider-outsider theories, Economics Letters 37. 193-196.

’ One explanation for the apparent discrepancy is that their paper looked an elasticity. ’ Oswald (1991) contains a discussion of this issue in the U.K. context.

at a simple

cross-partial

derivative,

rather

than

324

P.J. Sanfey

I Economics

Letters 41 (1993) 319-324

Oswald, A.J., 1991, Pay-setting, self-employment and the unions, Oxford Review of Economic Policy 7, 31-40. Shapiro, C. and J.E. Stiglitz, 1984, Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device, American Economic 74, 433-444. Solow, R.M., 1979, Another possible source of wage stickiness, Journal of Macroeconomics 1, 79-82.

Review