Accepted Manuscript
Patent Licensing, Entry and the Incentive to Innovate Yair Tauman, Chang Zhao PII: DOI: Reference:
S0167-7187(16)30316-2 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2017.06.010 INDOR 2381
To appear in:
International Journal of Industrial Organization
Received date: Revised date: Accepted date:
20 October 2016 15 June 2017 30 June 2017
Please cite this article as: Yair Tauman, Chang Zhao, Patent Licensing, Entry and the Incentive to Innovate, International Journal of Industrial Organization (2017), doi: 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2017.06.010
This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Highlights • We analyze the economic impact of process innovations where the innovator auctions licenses to both potential entrants and incumbent firms. • It is shown that opening the market to entrant licensees, the incentive to innovate is maximized if the market is initially a monopoly.
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
AN US
CR IP T
• The post-innovation market structure, the diffusion of the innovation and the social welfare are analyzed and compared with the case where entry is excluded.
1
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Patent Licensing, Entry and the Incentive to Innovate∗
Abstract
CR IP T
Yair Tauman† Chang Zhao‡
We analyze the economic impact of process innovations where the innovator auctions
AN US
off licenses to both potential entrants and incumbent firms. It is shown that opening the market to entrant licensees, the incentive to innovate is maximized if the industry is initially a monopoly, as was envisioned by Schumpeter (1942). This is in contrast to previous literature on licensing of process innovations when entry is excluded: the incentive to innovate is maximized in an oligopoly market if licenses are sold by auction
M
(Sen and Tauman (2007)) or in a competitive market if licenses are sold by royalty
ED
(Arrow (1962)). The post-innovation market structure, the diffusion of the innovation and the social welfare are analyzed and compared with the case where entry is excluded.
PT
Keywords. Innovation, Patent Licensing, Entry, Incentive to Innovate
AC
CE
JEL codes: C72, L11, L13
We thank two anonymous referees and we are especially grateful to one of them for very extensive and valuable comments which improve the paper considerably. We are also thankful to Benny Moldovanu for helpful comments and suggestions. † Stony Brook University and The Interdisciplinary Center, Herzliya. Email address:
[email protected] ‡ Tel Aviv University. Email address:
[email protected] ∗
2
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
1
Introduction The analysis of optimal licensing strategies of an innovator, the post innovation market
structure as well as the incentive to innovate has been extensively studied in the literature and can be traced back to Arrow (1962). Arrow shows that the revenue of an innovator who
CR IP T
sells licenses by means of a per-unit royalty is higher in a competitive market, compared with a monopolistic market. By focusing on the comparison of a monopolistic and a competitive market, Arrow avoids the strategic interactions between potential licensees, which is crucial in the analysis of an oligopoly. The game-theoretic framework which enables such interaction
AN US
was introduced independently by Katz and Shapiro (1985) and Kamien and Tauman (1986) (see Kamien (1992) for a review of the first decade results on this topic). Kamien and Tauman (1986) and the extended analysis in Sen and Tauman (2007) show that an oligopoly (instead of a monopolist or a competitive market) maximizes the revenue of an innovator who sells licenses by either a lump sum fee or by a two part tariff (a combination of a lump sum fee
M
and a per unit royalty).1 In these papers, as well as most other papers on optimal licensing of new innovations, it is assumed that incumbent firms are the only potential licensees. An
ED
important point not sufficiently perceived in the literature, and which constitutes our main subject, is that when the innovation reduces the previously high entry cost and makes entry
PT
profitable, the innovator may benefit from selling licenses to entrants as well as to incumbent
CE
firms.
For example in the US steel industry, the traditional technology (integrated mills) pro-
AC
duces on a large scale that is typically economical to build in 2 million-ton per year annual capacity and up. The introduction of a new technology for producing steel, the minimill, requires a much smaller capacity (a typical size is 200,000 to 400,000 tons per year) and can be easily started and stopped on a regular basis. Collard-Wexler and De Loecker (2014)) show that the introduction of minimill brought in entry into the steel market and led to a 1
The optimal size of the oligopoly depends on the magnitude of innovation, demand intensity and the marginal cost of production.
3
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
drop in the market share of the incumbent technology. Moreover, minimill is more efficient in the sense that its total factor productivity is at least as high as that of the old technology.2 This paper analyzes the economic impact of process innovations where the innovator can sell licenses to both potential entrants and incumbent firms. Licenses in our model are sold
CR IP T
by auction aiming to maximize the revenue of the innovator. The post-innovation market structure, the diffusion of the innovation and the incentive to innovate are analyzed.
In contrast to the literature dealing with licensing of process innovation to incumbent firms only, it is shown, surprisingly at first glance, that opening the Cournot market to entrant licensees, the incentive to innovate is maximized if the industry is initially a monopoly.
AN US
This is true for drastic as well as non-drastic innovations. If the initial industry exogenously had one less incumbent, the innovator could induce the same post-licensing market structure by selling the same number of total licenses but shifting one license from incumbents to entrants. This yields the innovator a weakly higher revenue since it avoids an incumbent’s
M
“replacement effect”. This result is consistent with the observation of Schumpeter (1942) that monopolistic industries, those in which individual firms have a measure of control over
ED
their product price, provide a more hospitable atmosphere for innovation than purely competitive ones. This is also in line with Chen and Schwartz (2013), who show that the gain
PT
of a innovator from the exclusive use of a product innovation can be larger in a monopoly market than in a perfectly competitive one.
CE
It is further shown that the post-innovation number of firms is larger the smaller is the magnitude of innovation. Namely less significant innovations diffuse more (i.e., are licensed
AC
to a larger number of firms). To clarify this point notice that the (negative) competition effect of an additional licensee on the innovator’s revenue is increasing in the magnitude of the innovation and as a result the innovator is more reluctant to issue a large number 2 Another example is in the television industry. The traditional cable TV was introduced nearly a half century before the Internet. When the Internet was first developed, sending video through it was difficult as the result of limited bandwidth capacity. By the mid of the first decade in the 21st century the broadband price went dramatically down and as a result many Internet TV companies entered the television industry (e.g., Netfix and Amazon). The entry of Internet TV companies induced one quarter of households to abandon their cable subscriptions (see Einav (2017)).
4
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
of licenses for more significant innovations. Furthermore, it is shown that for relatively significant innovations the innovator chooses to sell licenses only to incumbent firms and not to entrants. For less significant innovations the innovator sells licenses to some entrants and to all incumbent firms. The result that the innovator prefers incumbent licensees to entrant
CR IP T
licensees seems puzzling at first glance, since typically entrants are willing to pay for a license more than incumbent firms (each entrant is willing to pay all his profit while each incumbent firm is willing to pay only the incremented profit). However, an entrant licensee increases the number of active firms by 1 causing the Cournot profit of each firm to shrink. The effect of a weaker competition on the revenue of the innovator is larger and the innovator prefers
AN US
incumbent firms to entrants.
We are aware of only few papers which consider entrants as potential licensees. Gilbert and Newbery (1982) (GN hereafter) study a monopolistic market and show that the monopolist has an incentive to maintain its monopoly power by patenting new technologies to
M
preempt potential competition. This leads to patents that are neither used nor licensed to others (shelving).3 While GN analyze the interaction between a monopolistic incumbent
ED
and a potential entrant competing for an innovation, this paper studies the the interaction between multiple incumbent firms and potential entrants where an outside innovator sells
PT
multiple licenses.
Hoppe, Jehiel, and Moldovanu (2006) (HJM hereafter) is the paper closest to ours as
CE
it considers a market with several incumbent firms and many potential entrants. In HJM an innovator sells licenses through a uniform auction (UA), where he chooses a number k
AC
of licenses to sell to both incumbent firms and entrants. Each one of the k highest bidders (whether incumbent firm or entrant) obtains a license and all licensees pay the same amount, the (k + 1)th highest bid. Externality plays an important role in UA, since each bidder’s
3 In a recent paper, Tauman, Weiss, and Zhao (2017) show that shelving may not occur under a monopolistic market if the innovator cannot give a take-it-or-leave-it offer, but rather engage in a bargaining process with the incumbent. The innovator may benefit from selling a few licenses to entrants before approaching the incumbent because it allows the innovator to collect fees from entrants during the bargaining process and not less important will credibly increase the innovator’s threat on the incumbent, as it increases the number of licenses the innovator credibly sells in case the bargaining fails.
5
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
willingness to pay for a license depends not only on the total number of licenses, but also on the distribution of entrants and incumbent licensees. Unfortunately, UA has multiple equilibrium outcomes which results in multiple equilibrium payoffs of the innovator. In fact, for any number of licenses, k ≥ 1, every partition (k1 , k2 ) of k can be supported as an
CR IP T
equilibrium outcome, where k1 is the number of incumbent licensees and k2 is the number of entrant licensees. The innovator only controls k and has no control over the partition of k into incumbent and entrant licensees. It is, therefore, difficult (if not impossible) to predict the economic impact of the innovation under UA. HJM show that the multiplicity of equilibrium outcomes in UA remains a problem even if (weakly) dominated strategies are
AN US
eliminated. HJM therefore mostly deal with the sale of an exclusive license as well as some special cases involving multiple licenses and focus on whether entrants can be winners of licenses.
In this paper, we use, in addition to UA, an alternative auction mechanism, the non-
M
uniform auction (NUA) which results in a unique equilibrium. In NUA the innovator chooses in addition to k, the exact partition (k1 , k2 ). The winners of the auctions are the k1 highest
ED
incumbent bidders and the k2 highest entrant bidders. Each incumbent licensee pays the (k1 + 1)th highest bid among the incumbents’ bids while each entrant licensee pays the
PT
(k2 + 1)th highest bid among the entrants’ bids.4 In contrast to UA, externalities do not play a role in NUA since the post-innovation market structure is fixed regardless of the bids.
CE
For every (k1 , k2 ), the equilibrium outcome (in undominated strategies) of the auction is uniquely determined.
AC
At first glance it seems that the ability to choose (k1 , k2 ) and to differentiate the license fee
of entrants from incumbent firms must yield the innovator a higher payoff in NUA (than in UA). But this may not be the case. Indeed, on one hand every entrant licensee pays in NUA her entire profit while in UA it is (like any incumbent licensee) only the incremental profit 4
Another auction mechanism, semi-uniform auction (SUA), with a weaker asymmetry requirement than NUA is briefly discussed in Section 5. In SUA, the innovator, like in NUA, chooses both k and the partition (k1 , k2 ) of k. The winners of the auctions are, again, the k1 highest incumbent bidders and the k2 highest entrant bidders. But unlike NUA, the license fee is the same across all licensees.
6
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
of an incumbent licensee. However, an incumbent is willing to pay more in UA as a licensee if he takes the place of an entrant licensee and thereby limits entry (preemption effect). In contrast, in NUA the preemption effect is absence since every incumbent licensee takes the place of another incumbent firm and thus does not change the number of active firms. It is
CR IP T
shown that for relatively significant innovations, the innovator’s highest equilibrium payoff in UA exceeds his unique equilibrium payoff in NUA. As mentioned before, for significant innovations, the innovator is best off having a small (or even 0) number of entrant licensees in both types of auctions. In this case the benefit from a higher willingness to pay of incumbent firms (preemption effect) exceeds the loss in revenue due to the inability to price differentiate
AN US
entrant licensees.
This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we describe the model. In Section 3 we analyze the uniform auction (UA) and show that UA has multiple equilibrium outcomes. In Section 4 we study an alternative auction mechanism, the non-uniform auction (NUA) and
M
use NUA to analyze the post-innovation market structure, the diffusion of the innovation
The Model
PT
2
ED
and the incentive to innovate. We close with conclusion and extensions in Section 5.
Consider an industry with a set N = {1, ..., n} of incumbent firms who produce the
CE
same product with marginal cost c > 0. Potential entrants are unable to enter the market either because of high entry cost or since the current technology is protected by a patent.
AC
An outside innovator comes along with an innovation which eliminates the entry cost and reduces the constant per unit cost from c to c − , 0 < ≤ c.5 The number of potential entrants is assumed to be sufficiently large that exceeds the optimal number of licenses sold by the innovator. Remark: The assumption that the new technology has zero entry cost is made for 5
In principle even ≤ 0 may be valuable, if the innovation allows for a profitable entry. In this paper, however, we focus on the case > 0.
7
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
simplicity only. Our main insights remain valid as long as the entry cost with the new technology is relatively small. The inverse demand function is assumed to be linear,6 p = max(a − Q, 0), a > c. After the licensing stage, denote by m0 (≤ n) the number of firms producing at the old marginal
CR IP T
cost c (the non-licensee incumbent firms) and by m1 (= k) the number of firms producing at the new marginal cost c − (the incumbent and entrant licensees). Denote by π0 (m0 , m1 ) the Cournot profit of a firm producing with the old technology and by π1 (m0 , m1 ) the Cournot profit of a firm producing with the new technology. It can be verified that
(a−c)+(m0 +1) 2 m0 +m1 +1
(a−c)+ 2 m1 +1
M
π1 (m0 , m1 ) =
0
(a−c)−m1 2 m0 +m1 +1
AN US
π0 (m0 , m1 ) =
if m1 ≤
a−c
if m1 >
a−c
if m1 ≤
a−c
if m1 >
a−c
(1)
ED
Without loss of generality we normalize a − c, the quantity demanded at the price c, to be 1. Note that the innovation is drastic iff ≥ a − c. Therefore, after normalization, the
PT
innovation is drastic if ≥ 1 and non-drastic if < 1. In UA the players are engaged in a three-stage game, Gu . In the first stage the innovator
CE
chooses and announces the number k of licenses to be auctioned off, to both incumbent firms and new entrants. In the second stage the licenses are allocated to the winners of a uniform
AC
auction where each one of the k highest bidders obtains a license and pays the (k + 1)th
highest bid. In case of a tie, it is assumed that incumbent firms have priority over entrants.7 6
One of our main results which shows that the innovator’s incentive to innovate is maximized when the market is initially a monopoly is true for a general demand structure. 7 Let Ti (or Te ) be the set of incumbent (or entrant) bidders who bid the lowest winning bid b. Let |Ti | and |Te | be the number of firms in Ti and Te , respectively. Let h be the number of bidders bid above b. Each of the h highest bidders (whether an incumbent or an entrant) obtains a license. The allocation of the remaining k − h licenses uses the following tie-breaking rule: if k − h ≤ |Ti |, k − h incumbents are chosen at random from Ti to be licensees. if k − h > |Ti |, each incumbent in Ti obtains a license and k − h − |Ti | entrants are chosen at random from Te to be licensees. The priority on incumbent firms can be justified by
8
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
If a tie involves only one type of bidders, the tie is resolved at random. In the third and last stage the incumbents and the entrant licensees compete à la Cournot. Let Gu (k) be the subgame of Gu which starts after the announcement of k. In NUA the players are also engaged in a three-stage game, Gnu . In the first stage the
CR IP T
innovator chooses and announces (k1 , k2 ), where 0 ≤ k1 ≤ n − 1 and k2 ≥ 0 are the number of licenses he auctions off to incumbent firms and entrants, respectively. Let Gnu (k1 , k2 ) be the subgame of Gnu which starts in the second stage of Gnu . In Gnu (k1 , k2 ), licenses are sold through a non-uniform auction. Each of the k1 highest incumbent bidders obtains a license and pays the (k1 + 1)th highest bid among the incumbents’ bids. Similarly, each of
AN US
the k2 highest entrant bidders obtains a license and pays the (k2 + 1)th highest bid among the entrants’ bids. Ties are resolved at random. In the third stage the firms in the industry (licensees and non-licensees) engage in Cournot competition. Note that the auction is not well defined for k1 = n. Thus we limit k1 to n − 1.
M
In Gnu (k1 , k2 ), the value of a license is uniquely determined for each bidder. This is not the case in UA where the value of a license typically depends on the distribution of
ED
incumbent and entrant licensees. Note that bidders do not usually have dominant strategies in UA.
PT
Proposition 1. Suppose bidders do not use dominated strategies. (i) If the innovator auctions off a total of
1
licenses (using either UA or NUA), then the Cournot price is c, the
CE
pre-innovation marginal cost, and every non-licensee firm is driven out of the market. Each licensee pays his entire profit and the innovator obtains the total industry profit. (ii) It is
AC
never optimal for the innovator in both UA and NUA to auction off more than
1
licenses.
Proof. Part (i) is a straightforward consequence of (1). Part (i) asserts that when k =
1
only licensees are active firms in the market, and this is obviously true for all k ≥ 1 . Since the total industry profit is decreasing in k for k ≥ 1 , part (ii) follows. cheaper training and installation costs of the new technology (although negligible compared with the license fee) for incumbent licensees than for entrant licensees.
9
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
It will be shown (see Proposition 3 and Proposition A.6, below) that for > optimal number of licenses for the innovator is k =
1
2 n+1
the
in both UA and NUA .
Remark: Here we treat the number of licenses as a continuous variable, which is a simplification assumption that is standard in the patent licensing literature (see Kamien (1992)).
CR IP T
Our main insights remain valid if, instead, we assume that when the integer constraint is violated, the number of licenses awarded will be the next higher integer (the detailed analysis, however, is much more tedious).
When ≥ 1 (drastic innovation), even if the innovator sells an exclusive license, every non-licensee firm is driven out of the market and the only licensee will achieve the maximum
AN US
industry profit - the monopolistic profit with the new technology. The innovator extracts the entire profit from this licensee via competitive bidding for the license. When < 1 (nondrastic innovation), the pre-licensing market price is above c, and the post-licensing market price is below c if and only if the innovator auctions off more than
1
licenses (regardless of
M
the identity of the winners). Therefore when the innovator auctions off k ≥
1
licenses, he
obtains the entire industry profit. Since the total industry profit is decreasing in the number
selling only k =
1
1
licenses would reduce the industry profit compared with
ED
of active firms, selling more than
licenses. The rest of the paper focuses on non-drastic innovations ( < 1)
PT
and on the case where in both UA and NUA the total number k of licenses does not exceed
Uniform Auction
AC
3
CE
1 .
Consider the subgame Gu (k) of Gu , for 1 ≤ k ≤ 1 . Suppose (k1 , k2 ) is an equilibrium
outcome of Gu (k), where k1 , 0 ≤ k1 ≤ n, is the number of incumbent licensees and k2 = k−k1 is the number of entrant licensees. Let b(i) be the ith highest bid in UA (b(i) = b(i+1) if more than one bidders bid b(i) ). The willingness to pay of an incumbent firm, i, for a license is the difference between his
10
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
profit π1 (n − k1 , k) as a licensee and his profit as a non-licensee if he drops out. The latter depends on the type of licensee replacing i. If it is an incumbent, the willingness to pay of i is wilk (k1 ) = π1 (n − k1 , k) − π0 (n − k1 , k).
(2)
CR IP T
If i expects to be replaced by an entrant, the total number of firms increases by 1 and the willingness to pay of i is
k wih (k1 ) = π1 (n − k1 , k) − π0 (n − k1 + 1, k).
(3)
AN US
k Note that wih can be regarded as an incumbent’s willingness to pay for limiting entry and k for using the superior technology. Since π0 (n − k1 + 1, k) ≤ π0 (n − k1 , k) (see (1)), wih (k1 ) ≥
wilk (k1 ) (by Proposition 1 the equality holds only when k = 1 ). The fact that the incumbent is willing to pay for a license more than his value from using the superior technology reflects
M
the incumbent’s incentive to preempt entry.
ED
The willingness to pay of an entrant for a license is simply his Cournot profit,
PT
wek (k1 ) = π1 (n − k1 , k).
k For every k1 , wek (k1 ) ≥ wih (k1 ) ≥ wilk (k1 ), and the equality holds only when k =
(4) 1 .
CE
That is, if k < 1 , for any fixed post-auction market structure (k1 , k2 ), any entrant licensee k is willing to pay for a license more than any incumbent licensee (wek (k1 ) > wih (k1 )). This
AC
reflects Arrow’s “replacement effect”. That is, without any strategic consideration, the incumbent gains less from the innovation than an entrant because the incumbent “replaces” his technology with a more efficient one, while the entrant had nothing to “rest on”. Nevertheless it is still possible that in equilibrium some incumbent firm wins a license. To clarify this point note that the post-auction market structure changes when an entrant outbids an incumbent licensee (the number of active firms increases by 1). Even though
11
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
k k wek (k1 ) > wih (k1 ), it is possible that wih (k1 ) > wek (k1 − 1). That is, the incumbent’s incentive
to prevent entry may be larger than the entrant’s gain when he becomes a licensee. For n = 1 (monopolist incumbent) and k = 1 (single license), since the industry profit is maximized under monopoly,
CR IP T
1 wih (1) = π1 (0, 1) − π0 (1, 1) > π1 (1, 1) = we1 (0).
If bidders do not use dominated strategies, the monopoly incumbent wins the auction and entry does not occur - this phenomenon is first discussed in Gilbert and Newbery (1982). Hoppe, Jehiel, and Moldovanu (2006) further analyze the market with more than one in-
AN US
cumbent firms and show that entry may not be preempted in this case. This is because each incumbent may rely on the other to deter entry - as a result no one really carries out such action (bidders are required to use mixed strategies to support such equilibrium). The next proposition shows that, in fact, if bidders are not restricted to use undominated strategies, then for any given k, every distribution (k1 , k2 ), k1 + k2 = k, can be supported
M
as an equilibrium outcome. Our result does not require bidders to use mixed strategies. The multiplicity arises because each bidder’s willingness to pay depends on his expectation
PT
equilibrium behaviors.
ED
about the post-auction market structure and the variation in such beliefs supports different
Proposition 2. Let 1 ≤ k <
1 .
Then (i) any (k1 , k2 ), 0 ≤ k1 ≤ n and k2 ≥ 0 s.t.
CE
k1 + k2 = k, is an equilibrium outcome of Gu (k). (ii) For k1 = 0, π is an equilibrium payoff of the innovator in Gu (k) if and only if π ∈ [0, kwek (0)]. (iii) For 1 ≤ k1 ≤ n, π is an
AC
k equilibrium payoff of the innovator in Gu (k) if and only if π ∈ [0, kwih (k1 )].
Proof. See A.4 of the Appendix. Proposition 2 asserts that there are two types of multiplicity in Gu (k) (1 ≤ k < 1 ). First,
every (k1 , k2 ) s.t. k1 + k2 = k is an equilibrium outcome of Gu (k). Second, every (k1 , k2 ) generates for the innovator a continuum of equilibrium payoffs. In fact, if in equilibrium the highest k + 1 bids are b∗(1) , ..., b∗(k) , b∗(k+1) then for every b, 0 ≤ b ≤ b∗(k+1) , changing only the 12
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
(k + 1)th highest bid from b∗(k+1) to b also constitutes an equilibrium outcome. The multiplicity of equilibrium outcomes remains a problem even if (weakly) dominated strategies are eliminated. Hoppe, Jehiel, and Moldovanu (2006) deal with the game Gu with this restriction and show how complicated is the equilibrium analysis. The unfortunate
CR IP T
conclusion is that there is no obvious way to predict the outcome of Gu nor the choice k of the innovator. To have some UA benchmark (which will be compared with the innovator’s payoff in NUA), we focus here on a specific type of equilibrium in UA - the one that for any k yields the innovator the highest payoff in Gu (k).
Proposition 3. Suppose the innovator obtains for every k the highest equilibrium payoff in
AN US
Gu (k). (i) The corresponding equilibrium number of licensees in Gu is n+1 n ∗ ku (n, ) = ˜ ) k(n, 1
if 0 < < g(n)
if g(n) ≤ ≤ f (n)
M
if f (n) < < if
2 n+1
≤ < 1.
ED
2 n+1
(ii) If 0 < < g(n) all licensees are entrants and if g(n) ≤ < 1 all licensees are incumbent
PT
firms.
˜ ) are complicated and appear in A.1 of the Appendix. The formulas of f (n), g(n) and k(n,
CE
For ∈ [g(n), 1), ku∗ (n, ) is continuous and decreasing in . It worth notice that g(n) > 0 only for n ≥ 4.
AC
Proof. See A.2 of the Appendix. Proposition 3 asserts that for less significant innovations the innovator obtains the highest
equilibrium payoff when all licensees are entrants. On one hand an entrant licensee increases the number of active firms by 1 causing the Cournot profit of each firm to shrink. However when selling licenses only to entrants each licensee pays her entire Cournot profit for a license as opposed to the case where the innovator sells some licenses to incumbent firms (in the later 13
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
case every licensee pays only the incremental profit of an incumbent licensee). When the magnitude of the innovation is relatively small the willingness to pay of an incumbent firm for a license is small and the negative effect of additional entry is offset by the incremental willingness to pay of entrants, as compared with incumbent firms. For relatively significant
CR IP T
innovations, the benefit from having only entrant licensees does not compensate for the loss caused by a stronger competition and the innovator is best off when all licensees are incumbent firms. Remark: Let
2 n+1
≤ < 1 and suppose bidders do not use dominated strategies. Then
the unique optimal strategy of the innovator is to auction off k =
1
licenses. The Cournot
AN US
price reduces to the pre-innovation marginal cost c, and every non-licensee firm is driven out of the market. Consequently, the multiplicity of equilibrium points of UA occurs only for less significant innovations, <
2 . n+1
Denote by πu∗ (n, ) the highest equilibrium payoff of the innovator in Gu (see formula in
M
A.5 of the Appendix). We use πu∗ (n, ) as a benchmark to compare the innovator’s equilibrium
ED
payoff in UA with that obtained in NUA.
Non-Uniform Auction
PT
4
In this section the innovator can choose and announce the number of licenses to be sold to
CE
incumbent firms (0 ≤ k1 ≤ n−1)8 and the number of licenses to be sold to potential entrants (k2 ≥ 0). Each incumbent licensee pays the (k1 + 1)th highest bid among the incumbents’
AC
bids. Each entrant licensee pays the (k2 + 1)th highest bid among the entrants’ bids. In Gnu (k1 , k2 ), since incumbents and entrants bid on separate auctions, each incumbent cannot
prevent entry and therefore his willingness to pay is wil (k1 , k2 ) = π1 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ) − π0 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ). The willingness to pay of each entrant is we (k1 , k2 ) = π1 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ). Since 8
The auction is not well defined for k1 = n, thus we limit k1 to n − 1. We could extend our definition to k1 = n if we allow the innovator to charge a fixed fee in this case. For n = 1 this fee should be π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k). The analysis of NUA with this extension is tedious (see Sen and Tauman (2007)) and it will not change the main results of this paper.
14
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
bidding the true valuation is a (weakly) dominant strategy for each bidder, it is assumed that bidders bid truthfully in NUA. The innovator’s equilibrium payoff in Gnu (k1 , k2 ) is then uniquely determined and it is given by (5)
CR IP T
πnu (k1 , k2 ) = k1 wil (k1 , k2 ) + k2 we (k1 , k2 ). The next proposition deals with the innovator’s incentive to innovate.
Proposition 4. Regardless of the demand structure, if the innovator sells licenses by NUA,
AN US
his revenue is maximized if the industry is initially a monopoly.
Proof. Suppose there are n, n ≥ 2 incumbent firms. Denote by (k1∗ , k2∗ ) the optimal licensing ∗ strategy in Gnu . Let Knu = k1∗ + k2∗ . The innovator’s highest payoff is
(6)
M
∗ ∗ ∗ α ≡ k1∗ π1 (n − k1∗ , Knu ) − π0 (n − k1∗ , Knu ) + k2∗ π1 (n − k1∗ , Knu ).
Suppose the market has one less incumbent. That is, there are only n − 1 incumbents left
ED
in the market.
PT
Case 1. k1∗ ≥ 1. Using the licensing strategy (k1∗ − 1, k2∗ + 1), the innovator obtains (7)
CE
∗ ∗ ∗ β ≡ (k1∗ − 1) π1 (n − k1∗ , Knu ) − π0 (n − k1∗ , Knu ) + (k2∗ + 1)π1 (n − k1∗ , Knu ).
∗ ∗ ∗ Clearly for Knu = 1 , π0 (n − k1∗ , Knu ) = 0 and α = β. For Knu < 1 , β > α.
AC
Case 2. Suppose k1∗ = 0. Using the licensing strategy (0, k2∗ ), the innovator obtains γ ≡ k2∗ π1 (n − 1, k2∗ ) ≥ k2∗ π1 (n, k2∗ ) ≡ α.
(8)
Again for k2∗ = 1 , γ = α. For k2∗ < 1 , γ > α ∗ Combining Cases 1 and 2, if Knu <
1
the innovator extracts strictly higher revenue with
∗ n − 1 than with n incumbent firms. For Knu = 1 , when the number of incumbent firms is
15
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
n − 1 the innovator obtains a payoff which is at least as high as the case where the number of incumbent firms is n. Since this is true for all n ≥ 2, the proof is complete. Note that Proposition 4 does not depend on the linear structure of the demand function. For any fixed post-auction market structure, because of the “replacement effect”, an entrant
CR IP T
licensee is willing to pay at least as much as an incumbent licensee (more if k < 1 , and the same if k = 1 ). Note that the “preemption effect” in GN is absent in NUA, since incumbents and entrants bid on separate licenses. Therefore for any number of licenses (k1 , k2 ), the innovator contemplates, if the initial industry exogenously had one less incumbent, the innovator could induce the same post-licensing market structure by selling the same number of total
AN US
licenses but shifting one license from incumbents to entrants. This yields the innovator a weakly higher revenue since it avoids an incumbent’s “replacement effect”.9 Proposition 4 is in contrast to Arrow (1962), which asserts that the gain from a process innovation under a competitive market is higher compared with a monopolistic market. The
M
reason for the contradicting conclusion derives from Arrow’s assumption that entry is not possible and licenses can be sold only to those who are already in the market.10 Kamien and
ED
Tauman (1986) and the extended analysis in Sen and Tauman (2007) take into account the strategic interaction between potential licensees (which is crucial in the analysis of oligopoly)
PT
and show that the revenue of an innovator who sells licenses by either a lump sum fee or by a two part tariff (a combination of a lump sum fee and a per unit royalty) is maximized
9
CE
in an oligopoly market of a size which depends on the magnitude of innovation, demand
AC
As pointed out by one referee, the innovator’s revenue would be maximized with no incumbents at all (instead of an initial monopoly), because an entrant would then bid the entire monopoly profit under the new technology. 10 In Arrow (1962), if the innovation is drastic, the innovator in a monopolistic market can extract only the increment of the monopoly’s profit, while in a competitive market (since each firm originally earns zero profit) the innovator can extracts the entire monopoly profit under the new technology. If the innovation is non-drastic, the benefit from a process innovation comes solely from reducing variable cost and, hence, is proportional to the size of output, which is lower under monopoly than under competitive market. Note that Arrow’s result for non-drastic innovation does not extend to product innovations, where the scale of output is no longer a sufficient statistic, as noted by Chen and Schwartz (2013) (they term the opposing force the “coordination effect” - a two-product monopolist can profitably coordinate the post-innovation prices, unlike a rivalrous firm.)
16
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
intensity and the marginal cost of production. But these papers also limit potential licensees to incumbent firms only. We next characterize the equilibrium of Gnu . Since k1 ≤ n − 1 the case n = 1 is trivial to analyze. The following analysis focuses only on n ≥ 2. Note that if the total number of
CR IP T
licensees is 1 , every non-licensee firm is driven out of the market and each licensee pays his entire Cournot profit (see Proposition 1). In this case any partition (k1 , k2 ), k1 + k2 =
1
yields the innovator the same payoff. To avoid multiple equilibrium outcomes in Gnu we assume that the innovator in this case chooses k1 =
1
Proposition 5. (i) For significant innovations ( ≥
and k2 = 0. 1 ) 2n−4
the innovator sells licenses only
AN US
to incumbent firms and not to entrants. For less significant innovations ( <
1 ) 2n−4
the
innovator sells licenses to some entrants and to all (but one) incumbent firms. (ii) The post-innovation number of firms is larger the less significant is the magnitude of innovation.
M
Proof. (i) The unique equilibrium strategy of the innovator is characterized in A.6 of the Appendix. For n ≥ 3, the claims follow from (20) - (21), the inequality
1 2n−4
≤
2 , 3n−5
and
ED
from k1∗ (n, ) being decreasing in . The case n = 2 is an immediate consequence of (22) (23). (ii) See A.9 of the Appendix.
PT
Proposition 5 (i) asserts that for large innovations the innovator sells all licenses to incumbents, while for smaller innovations he sells n − 1 licenses to incumbents and the
CE
∗ ∗ remaining Knu − (n − 1) licenses to entrants (here Knu is the total number of licenses).11
The result that the innovator prefers incumbents to entrants seems puzzling at first glance,
AC
since the preemption effect is absent in NUA (the post-auction market structure is fixed regardless of the bids), and each entrant is willing to pay his entire profit for a license while the incumbent is willing to pay only the increment. However, on the other hand an entrant licensee increases the number of active firms by 1 causing the Cournot profit of each firm to
11
Note that if n = 2, < entrants.
1 2n−4
always holds and licenses are sold to one incumbent firm and to some
17
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
shrink. The effect of a weaker competition on the revenue of the innovator is larger and the innovator prefers incumbent firms to entrants. Part (ii) of Proposition 5 states that smaller innovations diffuse more. To clarify this point notice that the (negative) competition effect of additional licensee on the innovator’s
CR IP T
revenue is increasing in the magnitude of the innovation. As a result the innovator is more reluctant to issue a larger number of licenses for larger innovations. In fact, for n ≥ 3 and for relatively small the innovator sells 2n licenses (n − 1 licenses to incumbent firms and n + 1 licenses to new entrants). As grows the number of licenses decreases and as the innovation becomes closer to a drastic innovation ( → 1), the innovator sells one license only.
AN US
We next compare the innovator’s equilibrium payoff in UA and in NUA. At first glance it seems that the ability to separate entrants (who has a higher willingness to pay) from incumbent firms and hence charge them differently should yield the innovator in NUA a higher payoff than UA. However, an incumbent licensee is willing to pay more in UA if he
M
takes the place of an entrant licensee and hence limit entry (in contrast, this preemption effect is absence in NUA since the post-auction market structure is fixed regardless of the bids). It
ED
∗ is, therefore, not clear which mechanism serves better the innovator. Denote by πnu (n, ) the
innovator’s (unique) equilibrium payoff in Gnu (see formula in A.7 of the Appendix). The
PT
∗ (n, ) with πu∗ (n, ), the innovator’s highest equilibrium payoff next proposition compares πnu
in UA (see formula in A.5 of the Appendix).
CE
∗ Proposition 6. For n ≥ 4, πnu (n, ) > πu∗ (n, ) iff < h(n). For n = 2 or n = 3,
AC
∗ πnu (n, ) ≤ πu∗ (n, ) for all 0 < < 1.
The formula of h(n) is complicated and appears in A.1 of the Appendix.
Proof. See A.8 of the Appendix. Consider the market with at least 4 incumbent firms. Proposition 6 asserts that for
significant innovations the innovator can obtain a higher payoff in UA than in NUA. For ≥
1 (> 2n−4
h(n)), in both types of auctions the innovator is best off having only incumbent 18
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
licensees (see Propositions 3 and 5) and hence the innovator strictly prefers (the highest equilibrium payoff in) UA. When decreases from
1 2n−4
to 0 the innovator in NUA sells
an increasing number of licenses to entrants in addition to all (but one) incumbent firms. This implies that the benefit from differentiating the license fee of entrants from incumbent
CR IP T
firms is more significant for smaller . In particular, for < h(n) the benefit from price differentiating entrant licensees exceeds the loss in revenue due to lower willingness to pay of incumbent firms (absence of preemption effect), and the innovator is better off using NUA. If the pre-innovation market is duopoly or triopoly, the highest equilibrium payoff in UA yields the innovator a (weakly) higher payoff compared with NUA, regardless of the
AN US
magnitude of the innovation. Note that unlike UA, in NUA the innovator is constrained by k1 ≤ n − 1. Intuitively, in UA an incumbent firm always faces the threat of being replaced by an entrant; while in NUA each incumbent firm obtains a license for certain if k1 = n and therefore his willingness to pay in this case is 0.12 The constraint k1 ≤ n − 1 in NUA always
M
leaves at least one incumbent firm producing with the old technology and this has a negative competition effect on every licensee. The magnitude of this (negative) effect is larger when
ED
the number of incumbent firms is smaller and it dominates all other (positive) effects when n = 2 or 3.
PT
∗ (n, ), there may exist other equilibrium points in UA which Finally, even if πu∗ (n, ) > πnu
yields the innovator a lower payoff than in NUA. We illustrate this in the next example.
AC
CE
Example: Suppose = 0.2 and n = 5.13 In NUA, the innovator’s unique equilibrium payoff is 4 π1 (1, 4)−π0 (1, 4) = 0.213 and it is obtained when he auctions off 4 licenses only to incumbent firms. In UA the innovator’s highest equilibrium payoff is 4 π1 (1, 4) − π0 (2, 4) = 0.214, and it is obtained when he auctions off 4 licenses and all winners happen also to be
incumbent firms. To support this equilibrium in UA the 5th highest bid has to be submitted 12 Even with a minimum reservation price, the innovator is still reluctant to choose k1 = n in NUA. The optimal reservation price is π1 (0, n + k2 ) − π0 (1, n − 1 + k2 ). That is, when an incumbent drops out, no one replaces him and he reduces the number of licensees. This increases the value of the “outside option” which in turn reduces each incumbent’s willingness to pay. 13 Recall that we assume a − c = 1.
19
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
by entrants only. In this case each of the 4 incumbent licensees pays more in UA than in NUA in attempt to limit entry. However, there are other equilibrium points in UA which yields the innovator a much lower payoff. Following Proposition 2, there is an equilibrium in which
5
Conclusion and Extensions
CR IP T
all 4 winners are entrants. In this equilibrium the innovator obtains only 4π1 (5, 4) = 0.194.14
This paper analyzes the economic impact of process innovations where the innovator auctions off licenses to both potential entrants and incumbent firms. If the innovator uses
AN US
the uniform auction (UA), he has control over the total number k of licenses but not over the final distribution of licensees. Each bidder’s willingness to pay for a license depends not only on the number of licenses but also on his expectation about the post-innovation market structure (the number k1 of incumbent licensees and the number k2 of entrant licensees,
M
k1 + k2 = k). The multiplicity of such beliefs supports multiple equilibrium behaviors, which makes it almost impossible to predict the outcome of UA. This motivates us to use
ED
an alternative auction mechanism, the non-uniform auction (NUA), where the innovator conducts two separate auctions to entrants and incumbent firms, respectively. Since the
PT
post-innovation market structure is deterministic, the equilibrium outcome of the auction is unique and as such provides sharp predictions - this allows us to study the economic impact
CE
of innovations in the presence of potential entrants. The post-innovation market structure, the diffusion of the innovation and the incentive
AC
to innovate are analyzed under NUA. Since most literature on patent licensing assumes that incumbent firms are the only potential licensees, we next briefly compare our results with the case where entry is excluded. Opening the market to entrant licensees, the incentive to innovate is maximized if the industry is initially a monopoly.15 This is in contrast to the case where entry is excluded, where 14
Moreover this is the highest equilibrium payoff of the innovator among all equilibrium points where all 4 licensees are entrants. 15 This result is proved under general demand structure and it does not confine to linear demand.
20
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
q the innovator’s incentive to innovate is maximized in an industry of size n = max 3, 2 2 + 1 − 1 (this result is in line with Kamien, Oren, and Tauman (1992), see A.10 of the Appendix for a proof). Not surprisingly, opening the market to entrants has positive effect on social
welfare and it yields the innovator a higher revenue, compared with the case where entry
CR IP T
is excluded. However, it is shown (in A.10 of the Appendix) that these differences become smaller (namely, excluding entrants becomes less “harmful”) when the magnitude of innovation increases. In particular, for sufficiently significant innovations, the innovator chooses to sell licenses only to incumbent firms and not to entrants - in this case the exclusion becomes completely “harmless”. The “preemption effect” described in Gilbert and Newbery (1982)
AN US
is absence in NUA, since the post-auction market structure is fixed regardless of the bids of incumbent firms. Still, the innovator of a relatively significant innovation prefers to sell licenses only to incumbents and not to entrants. This is because an entrant licensee increases the number of active firms by 1 causing the total industry profit and the Cournot profit of
M
each firm to shrink.
Another related auction mechanism is the semi-uniform auction (SUA), which has a
ED
weaker asymmetry requirement than NUA. In SUA the innovator, like in NUA, chooses both k and the exact partition (k1 , k2 ) of k where the winners of the auction are the k1
PT
highest incumbent bidders and the k2 highest entrant bidders (ties are resolved at random). But unlike NUA, the license fee is the same across all licensees. To ensure the participation
CE
of incumbent firms in SUA the license fee is set to be the k-th highest bid.16 Like in NUA, when selling licenses by SUA, a monopolistic market provides the high-
AC
est incentive to innovate. Comparing the innovator’s payoff, NUA always (irrespective of the number of incumbent firms and the magnitude of the innovation) yields the innovator a (weakly) higher payoff. This is obvious since NUA, like SUA, specifies the partition of licenses into entrants and incumbent firms but, in addition, allows the innovator to price differentiate 16
If (as in UA) every licensee pays the highest losing bid, it may happen that the bids of all incumbent licensees fall below the (k + 1)th highest bid. This is the case if the (k + 1)th highest bid is submitted by an entrant who bids her entire industry profit. Such bid exceeds the willingness to pay of incumbent firms and incumbents are best off not participating in this auction.
21
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
entrant licensees.17 More surprisingly, when the innovation is relatively small, NUA results in a higher diffusion of technology than SUA. This is because when the innovation is small, in NUA the innovator sells licenses to all (but one) incumbent firms as well as some potential entrants; while in SUA he sells licenses only to new entrants and not to incumbent firms.
CR IP T
This difference stems from the fact that in SUA, as long as the innovator sells licenses to incumbent firms, every winner pays the incremental profit of an incumbent licensee (this increment decreases to zero as the magnitude of the innovation decreases to zero). In contrast, the innovator in NUA can extract entrant licensees’ entire profits even in the presence of incumbent licensees. To conclude, the ability to price differentiate new entrant licensees has
AN US
positive effect not only on the innovator’s revenue but also on social welfare, as compared with SUA. The detailed analysis of SUA appears in A.11 of the Appendix.
M
References
[1] Kenneth Arrow. “Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention”. The
ED
rate and direction of inventive activity: Economic and social factors. Princeton University Press, 1962, pp. 609–626.
PT
[2] Yongmin Chen and Marius Schwartz. “Product innovation incentives: monopoly vs. competition”. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 22.3 (2013), pp. 513–528.
CE
[3] Allan Collard-Wexler and Jan De Loecker. “Reallocation and technology: evidence from the US steel industry”. The American Economic Review 105.1 (2014), pp. 131–171.
AC
[4] Gali Einav. “Television and the Internet”. Mimeo (2017). [5] Richard J. Gilbert and David M.G. Newbery. “Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly”. The American Economic Review (1982), pp. 514–526.
17
SUA also yields the innovator a (weakly) lower payoff than his highest payoff in UA. On one hand all winners in SUA pays a uniform price, like in UA. On the other hand because of the absence of the “preemption effect” each incumbent firm is willing to pay less in SUA.
22
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
[6] Heidrun C. Hoppe, Philippe Jehiel, and Benny Moldovanu. “License auctions and market structure”. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 15.2 (2006), pp. 371– 396. [7] Morton I. Kamien. “Patent licensing”. Handbook of game theory with economic appli-
CR IP T
cations 1 (1992), pp. 331–354. [8] Morton I. Kamien, Shmuel S. Oren, and Yair Tauman. “Optimal licensing of costreducing innovation”. Journal of Mathematical Economics 21.5 (1992), pp. 483–508. [9] Morton I. Kamien and Yair Tauman. “Fees versus royalties and the private value of a
AN US
patent”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics (1986), pp. 471–491.
[10] Michael L. Katz and Carl Shapiro. “On the licensing of innovations”. The RAND Journal of Economics (1985), pp. 504–520.
[11] Joseph Alois Schumpeter. Socialism, capitalism and democracy. Harper and Brothers,
M
1942.
[12] Debapriya Sen and Yair Tauman. “General licensing schemes for a cost-reducing inno-
ED
vation”. Games and Economic Behavior 59.1 (2007), pp. 163–186. [13] Yair Tauman, Yoram Weiss, and Chang Zhao. “Bargaining in Patent Licensing with
AC
CE
PT
Inefficient Outcomes”. Mimeo (2017).
23
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
A
Appendix
A.1
√ 2n3 +10n2 +16n+4n+8+6− 4n6 2 +34n5 2 +119n4 2 +4n4 +220n3 2 +26n3 +227n2 2 +62n2 +124n2 +4n2 +64n+282 +12n+24+9 3(2n+3)
AN US
˜ ) = k(n,
CR IP T
√ n3 + n2 + 2n + 4 + n6 + 8n5 + 30n4 + 56n3 + 50n2 + 20n + 4 f (n) = 3n4 + 8n3 + 10n2 + 4n − 4
√ 3n4 + 6n3 + 7n2 + 4n − 4 − 2 n8 + 9n7 + 31n6 + 49n5 + 29n4 − 9n3 − 16n2 − 4n g(n) = max 0, 5n5 + 15n4 + 19n3 + 9n2 + 4
M
√ n4 + n3 + 2n2 + 4n − 3n7 + 14n6 + 18n5 + 7n4 + 24n3 + 40n2 − 16 h(n) = max 0, 2(n5 + 2n4 + n3 + n2 + 4n + 4)
ED
AC
where
CE
PT
e1 (n) r(n) = f −1 (n)
8
if 2 ≤ n ≤ 16
√ 3 n − 5 − 2 n2 − 4 n + 3 e1 (n) = 5 n2 − 14 n + 13
and
f1 () = −
1
if n ≥ 17
√
1+2 3/2 −11 2 +2
√
−48
√
1+2 7/2 −12 2
√
1+2 5/2 +68 4 +34 3 +2 2 −3
Figure 1 shows that the inverse function of f1 () exists for 0 < < 12 .
24
Figure 1: The value of f1 ()
Proof of Proposition 3
Lemma 1. For any 1 ≤ k ≤
1 ,
AN US
A.2
CR IP T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
the innovator’s highest equilibrium payoff in Gu (k) is
obtained when either k1 = 0 or k1 = min(k, n).
Proof. By Proposition 2, given an arbitrary 1 ≤ k ≤ 1 , any 0 ≤ k1 ≤ min(k, n) can emerge
M
as an equilibrium outcome. In addition the highest payoff of the innovator is kπ1 (n, k) if k k (k1 ) is (k1 ) if 1 ≤ k1 ≤ n. It is shown in the Appendix (see A.3) that wih k1 = 0 and kwih
ED
k increasing in k1 . Thus kwih (k1 ) is maximized when k1 = min(k, n).
CE
PT
By Lemma 1 the highest equilibrium payoff of the innovator in Gu is πu∗ (n, ) = max π 0 (n, ), π ˆ (n, )
where π (n, ) = maxk≥1 kπ1 (n, k) and π ˆ (n, ) = maxk≥1 k π1 n − min(k, n), k − π0 n − min(k, n) + 1, k .
AC
0
ˆ ) be maximizers of π ∗ (n, ), π 0 (n, ) and π Let ku∗ (n, ), k 0 (n, ) and k(n, ˆ (n, ), respecu
ˆ ) is a maximizer of π ∗ (n, ). tively. Clearly either k 0 (n, ) or k(n, u Lemma 2. k(π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k)) is decreasing in k. Proof. Let
1+ 1 − k 2 2 J = k π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k) = k − 1+k 2+k 25
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Then ∂J = A2 + B + C ∂k where A, B and C are functions of k. In particular,
B=−
CR IP T
k 6 + 9 k 5 + 22 k 4 + 24 k 3 + 12 k 2 − 4 k − 8 (1 + k)3 (2 + k)3 −6 k 4 − 14 k 3 − 12 k 2 − 16 k − 16 (1 + k)3 (2 + k)3 C=−
4 k3 + 9 k2 + k − 6 (1 + k)3 (2 + k)3
and B 2 − 4AC =
AN US
A=−
−16(k 3 + k 2 − 2k − 1) (k + 2)4 (1 + k)2
Clearly A < 0 for k ≥ 1 and B 2 − 4AC < 0 for k ≥ 2. Therefore 1 ( 36
1 + 5)(5 + 1) and J|k=2 = − 72 (10 + 1)(2 − 7), for every
ED
Since J|k=1 =
< 0 for k ≥ 2 and J is
M
maximized either at k = 1 or at k = 2.
∂J ∂k
J|k=1 − J|k=2 =
5 2 2 1 − + >0 12 9 24
PT
Thus J = k π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k) is decreasing in k for k ≥ 1.
CE
ˆ ) ≤ n. Lemma 3. (i) k 0 (n, ) ≤ n + 1 and (ii) k(n,
AC
Proof. (i) By (1) and Proposition 1 2 k 1 + (n + 1) π 0 (n, ) = max1 (n + k + 1)2 1≤k≤
and it is maximized at k = min(n + 1, 1 ). Hence k 0 (n, ) ≤ n + 1. (ii) Let π ˆ1 (n, ) = max k π1 (n − k, k) − π0 (n − k + 1, k) 1≤k
26
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
and π ˆ2 (n, ) = max k π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k) k≥n
Then π ˆ (n, ) = max π ˆ1 (n, ), π ˆ2 (n, ) . But k π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k) is decreasing in k (Lemma ˆ ). The next lemma characterizes both k 0 (n, ) and k(n, Lemma 4.
n+1 0 k (n, ) = 1
if 0 < < if
and
(9)
≤<1
if 0 < < f (n) if f (n) ≤ ≤
if
2 n+1
2 n+1
(10)
<<1
M
where
1 n+1
AN US
n ˆ ) = ˜ ) k(n, k(n, 1
1 n+1
CR IP T
ˆ ) ≤ n. 2). This implies k(n,
1
˜ ) ≤ n for f (n) ≤ ≤ ≤ k(n,
2 n+1
˜ ) is decreasing in . and k(n,
CE
Here
√ 2n3 +10n2 +16n+4n+8+6− 4n6 2 +34n5 2 +119n4 2 +4n4 +220n3 2 +26n3 +227n2 2 +62n2 +124n2 +4n2 +64n+282 +12n+24+9 3(2n+3)
PT
˜ ) = k(n,
ED
√ n3 + n2 + 2n + 4 + n6 + 8n5 + 30n4 + 56n3 + 50n2 + 20n + 4 f (n) = , 3n4 + 8n3 + 10n2 + 4n − 4
ˆ ). Proof. (9) follows from the proof of part (i) of Lemma 3. We next analyze k(n,
AC
ˆ ) ≤ n. Then By part (ii) of Lemma 3, k(n, π ˆ (n, ) = max k π1 (n − k, k) − π0 (n − k + 1, k) 1≤k≤n
=k
(1 + (n − k + 1))2 (n + 1)2
(1 − k)2 − (n + 2)2
The first order condition is ∂π ˆ (n, ) = Dk 2 + Ek + F ∂k 27
(11)
.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
where D=
−4 n3 2 − 20 n2 2 − 32 n2 − 8 n − 16 2 − 12 , (n + 1)2 (n + 2)2
E=
n4 2 + 6 n3 2 + 2 n3 + 13 n2 2 + 10 n2 + 12 n2 + 16 n + 4 2 + 2 n + 8 + 3 (n + 1)2 (n + 2)2
and
2 (4 n6 2 +34 n5 2 +119 n4 2 +4 n4 +220 n3 2 +26 n3 +227 n2 2 +62 n2 +124 n2 +4 n2 +64 n+28 2 +12 n+24 +9) (n+1)4 (n+2)4
AN US
E 2 − 4DF = 4
CR IP T
F =
6 n2 + 9 2 > 0, (n + 1)2 (n + 2)2
Let c1 and c2 be the solution in k of the quadratic function
∂π ˆ (n,) ∂k
= 0. Then
√ 2n3 +10n2 +16n+4n+8+6− 4n6 2 +34n5 2 +119n4 2 +4n4 +220n3 2 +26n3 +227n2 2 +62n2 +124n2 +4n2 +64n+282 +12n+24+9 3(2n+3)
c2 =
√ 2n3 +10n2 +16n+4n+8+6+ 4n6 2 +34n5 2 +119n4 2 +4n4 +220n3 2 +26n3 +227n2 2 +62n2 +124n2 +4n2 +64n+282 +12n+24+9 3(2n+3)
M
c1 =
ED
It can be easily verified that when ≥ 0 and n ≥ 1, c1 > 0. Next we compare c1 with 1 . 1 s(n, ) − t(n, ) − c1 = 3(2n + 3)
PT CE
where √
4n6 2 + 34n5 2 + 119n4 2 + 4n4 + 220n3 2 + 26n3 + 227n2 2 + 62n2 + 124n2 + 4n2 + 64n + 282 + 12n + 24 + 9
AC
s(n, ) =
(12)
and
t(n, ) = 2n3 + 10n2 + 16n + 8 − 2n − 3
For ≥ 0, s(n, ) > 0 and it can be easily verified that t(n, ) ≤ 0 iff ≤ (12) for ≤
2 n+3 , 2(n+1)(n+2)2
c1 ≤ 1 . If, however, >
28
2 n+3 2(n+1)(n+2)2
(13) 2 n+3 . 2(n+1)(n+2)2
By
by (13) t(n, ) > 0. It can be
>0
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
easily verified that s(n, )
2
2 ≥ t(n, )
2 n+1
iff 0 ≤ ≤
(14)
and for all n ≥ 1, in which case, again, c1 ≤ 1 . It can also be verified that (Proposition 1), for >
iff >
1
2 , n+1
2 . n+1
ˆ ) = k(n,
>
2 n+3 2(n+1)(n+2)2
Since the optimal k is bounded above by
1 .
Next we analyze the case 0 ≤ ≤
equivalently c1 ≤ 1 ). We first compare the value of
1
2 n+1
CR IP T
for n ≥ 1. Therefore c1 >
2 n+1
1
(or
and c2 .
−s(n, ) − t(n, ) 1 − c2 = 3(2n + 3)
AN US
2 n+3 2 n+3 2 as shown above, t(n, ) ≥ 0 iff ≥ 2(n+1)(n+2) ≤ ≤ n+1 , c2 ≥ 1 . Since 2 . For 2(n+1)(n+2)2 2 2 2 n+3 2 1 1 s(n, ) ≥ t(n, ) for 0 ≤ < 2(n+1)(n+2) 2 , again c2 ≥ . Thus for any ≤ n+1 , c2 ≥ .
This together with (11) imply that π ˆ (n, ) is maximized at k = c1 . Finally we compare the value of c1 with n.
M
s(n, ) − (2n3 + 4n2 + 7n + 4n + 8 + 6) 3(2n + 3)
ED
n − c1 = It can be easily verified that
PT
2 s(n, ) − (2n3 + 4n2 + 7n + 4n + 8 + 6)2 =
CE
(18n5 + 75n4 + 132n3 + 114n2 + 12n − 36)2 − (12n4 + 30n3 + 42n2 + 84n + 72) − (12n2 + 36n + 27)
AC
Thus c1 ≥ n iff the last term ≤ 0. The solution of this quadratic inequality is √ n3 +n2 +2n+4− n6 +8n5 +30n4 +56n3 +50n2 +20n+4 3n4 +8n3 +10n2 +4n−4
It can be easily verified that also be verified that f (n) ≤
≤≤
√ n3 +n2 +2n+4+ n6 +8n5 +30n4 +56n3 +50n2 +20n+4 3n4 +8n3 +10n2 +4n−4
√ n3 +n2 +2n+4− n6 +8n5 +30n4 +56n3 +50n2 +20n+4 3n4 +8n3 +10n2 +4n−4
2 n+1
≡ f (n)
< 0 for n ≥ 1. It can
for n ≥ 1.
Consequently, for 0 ≤ ≤ f (n), n ≤ c1 ≤
1
29
ˆ ) = n; for f (n) < ≤ and k(n,
2 , n+1
c1 < n,
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
c1 <
1
ˆ ) = c1 ; for and k(n,
2 n+1
≤ ≤ 1,
1
ˆ ) = 1 . It is left to show that < c1 < n and k(n,
c1 is decreasing in . We first compute the first order derivative of c1 with respect to .
=
√ 6 2 5 2 4 2 4 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 n3 +5 n2 +8 n−2 √ 4 n +34 n +119 n +4 n +220 n +26 n +227 n +62 n +124 n +4 n +64 n+28 +12 n+24 +9+2 n+4 +3 32 4 n6 2 +34 n5 2 +119 n4 2 +4 n4 +220 n3 2 +26 n3 +227 n2 2 +62 n2 +124 n2 +4 n2 +64 n+28 2 +12 n+24 +9
It can be easily verified that
∂c1 ∂
< 0 for n ≥ 1 and > 0. The proof of Lemma 4 is
complete.
CR IP T
∂c1 ∂
We are now ready to characterize the equilibrium number of licensees in Gu , for the "lucky" innovator.
1 , f (n) n+1
ˆ ) = n. , then k 0 (n, ) = n + 1 and k(n,
AN US
Case 1: Suppose 0 ≤ ≤ min
π 0 (n, ) − π ˆ (n, ) = (n + 1)π1 (n, n + 1) − n π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k) =
(5n5 +15n4 +19n3 +9n2 +4)2 −(6n4 +12n3 +14n2 +8n−8)+n3 −3n2 −4n+4 . 4(n+1)2 (n+2)2
(15)
M
It is easy to verify that π 0 (n, ) ≤ π ˆ (n, ) iff
d2 =
√ 3n4 +6n3 +7n2 +4n−4+2 n8 +9n7 +31n6 +49n5 +29n4 −9n3 −16n2 −4n 5n5 +15n4 +19n3 +9n2 +4
√ 3n4 +6n3 +7n2 +4n−4−2 n8 +9n7 +31n6 +49n5 +29n4 −9n3 −16n2 −4n and 5n5 +15n4 +19n3 +9n2 +4 √ 3n4 +6n3 +7n2 +4n−4+2 n8 +9n7 +31n6 +49n5 +29n4 −9n3 −16n2 −4n . We 5n5 +15n4 +19n3 +9n2 +4
1 , f (n) n+1
AC
d2 −
1 n+1
=
√ (n+1) n8 +9n7 +31n6 +49n5 +29n4 −9n3 −16n2 −4n−(n5 +3n4 +3n3 +4−n2 ) . 1 (5n5 +15n4 +19n3 +9n2 +4)(n+1) 2
It can be easily verified that d2 >
1 n+1
for n ≥ 1. Thus d2 ≥ min
that 1 n+1
thus d1 <
− d1 =
1 . n+1
next show that d1 <
< d2 . First observe that
CE
min
≤≤
PT
Let d1 =
ED
√ 3n4 +6n3 +7n2 +4n−4−2 n8 +9n7 +31n6 +49n5 +29n4 −9n3 −16n2 −4n 5n5 +15n4 +19n3 +9n2 +4
1 , f (n) n+1
. Next observe
√ (n+1) n8 +9n7 +31n6 +49n5 +29n4 −9n3 −16n2 −4n+(n5 +3n4 +3n3 +4−n2 ) 1 (5n5 +15n4 +19n3 +9n2 +4)(n+1) 2
>0
The analytical comparison between the value of d1 and f (n) is complicated. 30
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
The numerical comparison is shown in Figure 3. Form the figure, d1 (blue) is less than f (n)
AN US
CR IP T
for 1 ≤ n ≤ 100.
Since d1 < min
1 , f (n) n+1
Case 2: Suppose
2 n+1
M
Figure 2: Comparison between d1 and f (n)
ED
< d2 , for 0 ≤ < d1 , π 0 (n, ) ≥ π ˆ (n, ) and k2∗ (n, ) = 1 ˆ ) = n. k 0 (n, ) = n + 1. For d1 ≤ ≤ min n+1 , f (n) , π 0 (n, ) < π ˆ (n, ) and k2∗ (n, ) = k(n,
PT
Clearly k2∗ (n, ) = 1 .
ˆ ) = ≤ < 1, then k 0 (n, ) = k(n,
Case 3: Suppose min 1
<<
2 . n+1
Consider next the case
1 n+1
and π 0 (n, ) = π ˆ (n, ) = .
Consider first the case
thus π ˆ (n, ) > . Since k 0 (n, ) =
CE
ˆ ) < Lemma 4 k(n,
1 , f (n) n+1
1
> f (n). (i) Suppose
1
1 n+1
≤ f (n). By
ˆ (n, ) > π 0 (n, ). and π 0 (n, ) = , π
1 n+1
≤ <
2 , n+1
AC
argument applies and π ˆ (n, ) > π 0 (n, ). (ii) Suppose f (n) < <
then the previous
1 , n+1
k 0 (n, ) = n + 1
ˆ ) = k(n, ˜ ). We next compare π 0 (n, ) and π and k(n, ˆ (n, ) in this case. First observe that ˜ ) < n for f (n) < < 1 , thus π k(n, ˆ (n, ) > n π (0, n) − π (1, n) . If we can show that 1 0 n+1 n π1 (0, n) − π0 (1, n) > (n + 1)π1 (n, n + 1)
(16)
then the proof is complete. This is indeed true since (16) holds iff d1 ≤ ≤ d2 and we have 31
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
shown that d1 ≤ f (n) and d2 ≥
A.3
1 . n+1
Denote g(n) = max(d1 , 0), Proposition 3 is complete.
Proof of π1 (n − k1 , k) − π0 (n − k1 + 1, k) being increasing in k1
Let m = n − k1 , we will show that π1 (m, k) − π0 (m + 1, k) is decreasing in m.
CR IP T
2 1 + (m + 1) (1 − k)2 π1 (m, k) − π0 (m + 1, k) = − (m + k + 1)2 (m + k + 2)2 The first order condition (using Maple) is
AN US
∂ π1 (m, k) − π0 (m + 1, k) = G2 + H + I ∂m where
G=
2 k5 +8 k4 m+12 k3 m2 +8 k2 m3 +2 km4 +8 k4 +30 k3 m+36 k2 m2 +14 km3 +18 k3 +54 k2 m+36 km2 +26 k2 +40 mk+16 k (m+k+1)3 (m+2+k)3
H=
−2 k4 −8 k3 m−12 k2 m2 −8 km3 −2 m4 −2 k3 −18 k2 m−30 km2 −14 m3 −36 mk−36 m2 −12 k−40 m−16 (m+k+1)3 (m+2+k)3
ED
M
>0
and
Therefore
PT
I=
∂ π1 (m,k)−π0 (m+1,k)
is in quadratic in with G > 0.
∂m ∂ π1 (m,k)−π0 (m+1,k)
CE
The equation
−6 k2 −12 mk−6 m2 −18 k−18 m−14 (m+k+1)3 (m+2+k)3
∂m
= 0 has two solutions in . 2
2
AC
+6 mk+3 m +9 k+9 m+7 1 = − k4 +4 k3 m+6 k2 m2 +4 km3 +m4 +43kk3 +15 <0 k2 m+18 km2 +7 m3 +9 k2 +27 mk+18 m2 +13 k+20 m+8
and
2 = Therefore for 0 < ≤
1 ∂ π1 (m,k)−π0 (m+1,k) , k ∂m
1 >0 k < 0 and π1 (m, k) − π0 (m + 1, k) is decreasing
in m. Since m = n − k1 , π1 (n − k1 , k) − π0 (n − k1 + 1, k) is increasing in k1 . 32
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
A.4
Proof of Proposition 2
(i) Let k ≥ 1 and let (k1 , k2 ) s.t. 0 ≤ k1 ≤ n−1 and k2 = k−k1 (the case where k1 = n will be dealt separately). Let us show that (k1 , k2 ) is an equilibrium outcome of Gu (k). Denote b = π1 (n−k1 −1, k) (b is well defined since k1 ≤ n−1) and b = π1 (n−k1 , k)−π0 (n−k1 +1, k).
CR IP T
Suppose that exactly k1 incumbent firms and k2 entrants bid b and only one entrant bids b. All other incumbents or entrants bid below b. Clearly b(1) = ... = b(k) = b, b(k+1) = b and b ≤ b. We claim that these bid profile constitutes an equilibrium of Gu (k). Any incumbent licensee, i, obtains
AN US
π1 (n − k1 , k) − b(k+1) = π0 (n − k1 + 1, k).
If i lowers his bid below b the entrant who bids b will replace i. As a result there will be n − k1 + 1 firms producing with the inferior technology and i will obtain π0 (n − k1 + 1, k), the same as his payoff as a licensee. Since the opportunity cost of any entrant is zero, an
M
entrant licensee (when k2 ≥ 1) has no incentive to lower her bid. Next let us show that a non-licensee (incumbent or entrant) can not benefit from outbidding a licensee. Suppose j
ED
(incumbent or entrant) outbids a licensee i. Then he/she will increase the license fee from b to b. We claim that the industry profit of j is at most b and hence he has no incentive to
PT
become a licensee. Indeed, if both j and i are incumbent firms the industry profit of j as a licensee will be π1 (n − k1 , k) which is smaller than b = π1 (n − k1 − 1, k). If j is an incumbent
CE
firm and i is an entrant, the number of firms using the inferior technology will reduce to n − k1 − 1. The gross profit of j as a licensee will be b and his payoff, net of the new license
AC
fee, is zero. If j is an entrant, j will obtain an industry profit of π1 (n − k1 + 1, k) < b if i is an incumbent firm and π1 (n − k1 , k) < b if i is an entrant. In both cases j’s net payoff is negative. To complete the proof of part (i) suppose that k1 = n and hence k2 = k − n. Suppose every incumbent firm and exactly k2 entrants bid b = π1 (0, k), one entrant only bids b = π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k) and every other bidder bids below b. The license fee is b and it
is easy to verify that these bids constitute an equilibrium of Gu (k).
33
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
(ii) Let k1 = 0, ˜b ∈ [0, π1 (n, k)] and b = π1 (n − 1, k). Suppose exactly k entrants bid b, one entrant only bids ˜b and every other bidder bids below ˜b. The license fee is b(k+1) = ˜b. Since π1 (n, k) − ˜b ≥ 0, no (entrant) licensee benefits from lowering his bid below ˜b. Suppose next that a non-licensee j (incumbent or entrant), bids above b. Then the new license fee
CR IP T
will increase to b = π1 (n − 1, k) and j’s industry profit is π1 (n − 1, k) if j is an incumbent firm, and π1 (n, k) if j is an entrant. In both cases the industry profit does not exceed the license fee. Finally, there is no equilibrium of Gu (k) with k1 = 0 and s.t. b(k+1) > π1 (n, k). Otherwise, the industry profit of a licensee does not cover the license fee.
k k = π1 (n − k1 , k) − (k1 )], where by (3) wih (iii) Suppose 1 ≤ k1 ≤ n − 1 and let ˜b ∈ [0, wih
AN US
π0 (n − k1 + 1, k). Denote b = π1 (n − k1 − 1, k). Suppose exactly k1 incumbent firms and k2 entrants bid b, one entrant only bids ˜b and every other bidder bids below ˜b. Then b(k+1) = ˜b is the license fee. An incumbent licensee obtains
(17)
M
π1 (n − k1 , k) − ˜b ≥ π0 (n − k1 + 1, k).
ED
If he lowers his bid below ˜b he will obtain π0 (n − k1 + 1, k). By (17) this will not benefit him. A non-licensee j (incumbent or entrant) who outbids a licensee i (incumbent or entrant) will
PT
increase the license fee from ˜b to b = π1 (n − k1 − 1, k). It is easy to verify that independently of the identity of j and i, j’s industry profit will not exceed π1 (n − k1 − 1, k).
CE
Next suppose k1 = n. Let ˜b ∈ [0, π1 (0, k) − π0 (1, k)] and let b = π1 (0, k). Suppose every incumbent firm and exactly k2 = k − n entrants bid b. Suppose also that only one entrant
AC
bids ˜b and all other bidders bid below ˜b. Then the license fee is b(k+1) = ˜b. A licensee obtains π1 (0.k) − ˜b ≥ π0 (1, k) ≥ 0.
(18)
If an incumbent licensee lowers his bid below ˜b he will obtain π0 (1, k) and by (18) he will not improve his payoff. If a non-licensee entrant j outbids a licensee i the new license fee will be b = π1 (0, k) and again, independently of the identity of i, the industry profit of j will 34
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
not exceed π1 (0, k). Finally, for k ≥ 1 the willingness of an incumbent firm to pay for a license is at most k k (k1 ). (k1 ). Thus there is no equilibrium b∗ of Gu (k) s.t. 1 ≤ k1 ≤ n and b∗(k+1) > wih wih
The Highest Equilirbium Payoff of the Innovator in UA
The highest equilibrium payoff of the innovator in Gu is
if 0 < < g(n)
if g(n) ≤ ≤ f (n) if f (n) < <
AN US
(n + 1)π1 (n, n + 1) n π1 (0, n) − π0 (1, n) πu∗ (n, ) = ˜ ˜ ˜ ˜ ˜ k π n − k, k − π n − k + 1, k 1 0
CR IP T
A.5
˜ ). where k˜ = k(n,
if
2 n+1
2 n+1
(19)
≤ < 1.
Equilirbium Licensing Strategy in NUA
ED
A.6
M
Proof. Follows immediately from Proposition 3.
The unique equilibrium licensing strategy of the innovator in Gnu is n−1 n+1 k1n∗ (n, ) = + 4 1
PT
AC
CE
(i) For n ≥ 3
(ii) For n = 2
k2n∗ (n, )
if 0 < ≤ 1 2
=
2(n+2) 2n+1
0
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
if
2 n+1
≤ < 1,
− (n − 1)
k1n∗ (2, ) = 1,
2 n+1
if 0 < ≤ if
35
2 3n−5
1 2n−4
1 2n−4
(20)
(21)
≤ < 1.
(22)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
k2n∗ (2, ) =
3 4+1
if 0 < ≤
1
if
−1
1 2
1 2
(23)
≤ < 1.
Proof. By Proposition 1, we focus only on the case where k1 + k2 ≤ . The innovator solves π
CR IP T
D z }| { max k1 π1 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ) − π0 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ) + k2 π1 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 )
k1 ,k2
s.t.
AN US
0 ≤ k1 ≤ n − 1 0 ≤ k2
k1 + k2 ≤
(k2 2 +2n2 +22 )k12 (n+k2 +1)2
−
1
(k22 2 +2k2 n2 −n2 2 +2k2 2 −2n2 −2n−2 −2)k1 (n+k2 +1)2
M
πD = −
(24)
+
k2 n2 2 +2k2 n2 +2k2 n+k2 2 +2k2 +k2 (n+k2 +1)2
ED
Note first that πD is continuous on k1 and k2 . Moreover, for any k2 , πD is quadratic in k1 . Denote (k1∗ , k2∗ ) the optimal choice of the innovator. Given any k2 , let k1 (k2 ) be the
PT
maximizer of πD . Then
AC
CE
k1 (k2 ) = min{− |
k22 + (2n + 2)k2 − n2 − 2n − 2n − − 2 1 , n − 1, − k2 } 2(k2 + 2n + 2) {z } k1s
It can be easily verified that k1s
< n − 1 iff k2 >
−2n + |
p (n2 + 2n + 2n + 5 + 2) {z } c1
36
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
and k1s <
1 − k2
iff k2 <
2 − n − } | {z c2
It can also be verified that c1 ≤ c2 iff ≤ 21 . We first analyze the case 0 < ≤ 12 . 1 2
CR IP T
Case 1. 0 < <
Subcase 1.1: Suppose k2 ≤ c1 , then n − 1 < k1s < 1 − k1 and k1 (k2 ) = n − 1. Substituting k1 in πD with n − 1,
(n − 1)2 k22 + (2n2 2 − 4n2 − 2n − 22 − 2 − 1)k2 + (n − 1)(n + 1)(n − 3 − 2) (n + k2 + 1)2
It can be easily verified that
1 ∂πD ∂k2
AN US
1 πD =−
is decreasing in k2 . Let k˜2 be the solution of
1 ∂πD ∂k2
= 0. Then
M
2n + n + 4 + 1 − 2n2 k˜2 = 2n + 1 It can be verified that k˜2 ≤ c1 iff ≤
1 2
thus πD is maximized at k2 = k˜2 for k2 ≤ c1 .
ED
Subcase 1.2: Suppose c1 ≤ k2 ≤ c2 , then k1s < n − 1, k1s <
1
− k2 and k1 (k2 ) = k1s .
PT
Substituting k1 in πD with k1s ,
k22 2 + (2n2 + 22 )k2 + n2 2 + 2n2 + 4n + 2 + 4 + 4 4(k2 + 2n + 2)
CE
2 πD =
2 It can be verified that πD is decreasing in k2 for 0 ≤ k2 ≤ c2 , thus πD is maximized at k2 = c1
AC
for c1 ≤ k2 ≤ c2 .
Subcase 1.3: Suppose c2 ≤ k2 , then
1
− k2 < k1s < n − 1 and k1 (k2 ) =
1
− k2 . Since the
innovator’s payoff is the same for all (k1 , k2 ) s.t. k1 + k2 = 1 , for any k2 ≥ c2 the innovator
obtains the same payoff. By the assumption that the incumbent has the priority in case of a tie, πD is maximized at k2 = c2 in the region k2 ≥ c2 . To summarize, for k2 ≤ c1 , πD is maximized at (k1 = n − 1, k2 = k˜2 ); for k2 ∈ [c1 , c2 ], πD 37
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
is maximized at (k1 = k1s , k2 = c1 ); for k2 ≥ c2 , πD is maximized at (k1 =
1
− c2 , k2 = c2 ).
Since πD is continuous in k2 , πD is maximized at k2 = max(k˜2 , 0). For n ≥ 3, it can be easily verified that k˜2 ≥ 0 iff ≤
=
2n+n+4+1−2n2 2n+1
0
if 0 < < if
Next we analyze k1∗ . Suppose 0 < <
1 . 2n−4
Then
1 2n−4
1 2n−4
≤
CR IP T
k2∗ (n, )
1 . 2n−4
Since k2∗ = k˜2 and k˜2 < c1 (for 0 ≤ < 12 ), 1 2n−4
1 then depends on the relation between 0, c1 and c2 . (i) If 0 ≤ c1 ( 2n−4 ≤≤
2 ), 3n−5
following
2 ≤≤ the analysis of subcase 1.1, k1 (k2∗ ) = n − 1. (ii) If c1 < 0 ≤ c2 ( 3n−5
2 ), n+1
following
AN US
k2∗ < c1 . Following the analysis in subcase 1.1, k1 (k2∗ ) = n − 1. Suppose next
the analysis of subcase 1.2, k1 (k2∗ ) = k1s |k2 =0 =
n+1 4
+
1 . 2
≤ , k1 (k2∗ )
2 (iii) If c2 < 0 ( n+1 < ), following
the analysis of subcase 1.3, k1 (k2∗ ) = 1 . Thus for n ≥ 3
M
n−1 n+1 k1∗ (n, ) = + 4 1
ED
1 2
PT
k2∗ (n, )
=
if 0 < <
if
2 3n−5
if
2 n+1
2n+n+4+1−2n2 2n+1
0
2 3n−5
≤≤ <<
2 n+1
1 2
if 0 < < if
1 2n−4
1 2n−4
≤<
1 2
CE
Consider next n = 2. It can be easily verified that k˜2 > 0. Therefore k2∗ (2, ) = k˜2 and k2∗ (2, ) < c1 (since k˜2 < c1 for 0 ≤ < 21 ). Following subcase 1.1 k1∗ (2, ) = 1. The
AC
innovator’s optimal payoff is obtained for k1∗ = 1 and k2∗ = k˜2 |n=2 = Case 2.
1 2
3 . 4+1
≤<1
In this case c1 > c2 , k˜2 >
1 2
and k˜2 > c1 .
Subcase 2.1: Suppose k2 ≤ c2 , then n − 1 < k1s ≤
1
− k2 and k1 (k2 ) = n − 1. Following
similar argument as in Subcase 1.1, πD is maximized at min(k˜2 , c2 ). Since k˜2 > c1 and 38
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
c1 > c2 , k˜2 > c2 . Therefore πD is maximized at k1 = n − 1 and k2 = c2 . Subcase 2.2: Suppose c2 ≤ k2 ≤ c1 , then k1s ≥ n − 1, k1s ≥ min(n − 1, 1 − k2 ). It can be easily verified that c2 ≤ Suppose first c2 ≤ k2 ≤
1
1
− k2 and k1 (k2 ) =
− n + 1 ≤ c1 for ≥
1
− n + 1 (or equivalently n − 1 ≤
1
1 . 2
(i)
− k2 ). Then k1 (k2 ) = n − 1.
k˜2 > c1 ≥ 1
1
CR IP T
Following similar argument as in Subcase 1.1, πD is maximized at min(k˜2 , 1 − n + 1). Since − n + 1, πD is maximized at (k1 = n − 1, k2 =
− n + 1 ≤ k2 ≤ c1 (or equivalently n − 1 ≥
1
1
− n + 1). (ii) Suppose next
− k2 ) then k1 (k2 ) =
payoff is maximized at k1 + k2 = 1 . Subcase 2.3: Suppose k2 ≥ c1 , then
1
1
− k2 . The innovator’s
− k2 < k1s < n − 1 and k1 (k2 ) =
− k2 . The
AN US
innovator’s payoff is maximized again at k1 + k2 = 1 .
1
Consider first n ≥ 3. Since ≥ 21 , n − 1 ≥
holds. Therefore Subcase 2.1 and part (i)
1
of Subcase 2.2 are irrelevant. In this case πD is maximized at k1 + k2 = 1 . By assumption, 1
and k2∗ = 0.
Consider next n = 2. Since
1 2
≤ ≤ 1, n − 1 ≤
M
in this case k1∗ =
1
holds. Therefore Part (ii) of Subcase
2.2 and Subcase 2.3 are irrelevant. Since πD is continuous on k2 , combining Subcases 2.1
A.7
1
− n + 1).
PT
ED
and Part (i) of Subcase 2.2 πD is maximized at (k1 = n − 1, k2 =
The Innovator’s Equilibrium Payoff in NUA
CE
The innovator’s equilibrium payoff in Gnu is:
AC
For n ≥ 3
∗ πnu (n, ) =
42 +4n+1 4(n+1)
(n−1) −(n−3)2 +2 n+1
(n++2)2 8(n+1)
39
if 0 < ≤
1 2n−4
if
1 2n−4
<≤
2 3n−5
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
2 n+1
if
2 n+1
≤ < 1.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
For n = 2 ∗ πnu (n, )
=
Proof. Follows from (5) and A.6.
42 +4n+1 4(n+1)
if 0 < ≤ if
1 2
1 2
(25)
≤ < 1.
Proof of Proposition 6
CR IP T
A.8
∗ If n = 2, comparing (19) and (25), it is easy to verify that πnu (2, ) ≤ πu∗ (2, ) for
0 < ≤ 1. We next consider the case n ≥ 3.
2 , n+1
∗ (n, ) < πu∗ (n, ). (iii) If πnu
2 n+1
AN US
∗ (n, ) > πu∗ (n, ). (ii) If Lemma 5. Consider the case n ≥ 3. (i) If ≤ g(n), πnu
1 2n−4
≤<
∗ (n, ) = πu∗ (n, ). ≤ < 1, πnu
Proof. (i) If < g(n), in UA the innovator’s highest payoff is π ˆ = (n + 1)π1 (n, n + 1) which is obtained when he auctions off n + 1 licenses and all winners are entrants. In NUA if the
M
innovator chooses k1 = 0 and k2 = n + 1 he obtains π ˆ . But he can obtain more by choosing other combinations of (k1 , k2 ). It can be shown that g(n) <
1 2n−4
for n ≥ 3 (the analytic
ED
proof is difficult, see Figure 3 for a numerical comparison). Thus by Proposition A.6 when
AC
CE
PT
∗ < g(n), k1∗ (n, ) > 0 and πnu >π ˆ.
Figure 3: Comparison between 40
1 2n−4
and g(n)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
(ii) If
1 2n−4
≤<
2 n+1
then in NUA k2∗ (n, ) = 0. Since the advantage of NUA on UA
lies only on the innovator’s ability to charge for a license a higher price to entrants than to incumbent firms, this advantage disappears when k2∗ (n, ) = 0. Moreover, for any (k1 , k2 ) an incumbent’s willingness to pay in NUA is π1 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ) − π0 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ) while it can
CR IP T
be as high as π1 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ) − π0 (n − k1 + 1, k1 + k2 ) in UA (incumbent may be willing ∗ ∗ ∗ (n, ) < πu∗ (n, ). < 1 , πnu (n, ) ≤ πu∗ (n, ). Since Knu to pay more to limit entry). Thus πnu
(iii) If
2 n+1
≤ < 1 the innovator auctions off in total
1
licenses in both UA and NUA.
By Proposition 1, the innovator obtains the same payoff which is the total industry profit in both auctions.
Thus in Gnu , k1∗ (n, ) = n − 1 and k2∗ (n, ) = whether ≤ f (n) or > f (n). Case 1: Suppose f (n) ≤
1 2n−4
1 . 2n−4
Clearly
1 2n−4
AN US
Next we focus on the analysis of g(n) < <
2n+n+4+1−2n2 . 2n+1
<
2 3n−5
<
2 n+1
for n ≥ 3.
In Gu , πu∗ (n, ) depends on
(this inequality holds for n ≤ 8). Then
ED
M
n π1 (0, n) − π0 (1, n) ∗ πu (n, ) = ˜ k˜ − π0 n − k˜ + 1, k˜ k˜ π1 n − k,
if g(n) ≤ ≤ f (n) if f (n) < <
1 2n−4
PT
We first analyze g(n) ≤ ≤ f (n).
(4n5 +8n4 +4n3 +4n2 +16n+16)2 4(n+1)2 (n+2)2
CE
∗ πnu − πu∗ =
−
(4n4 +4n3 +8n2 +16n) 4(n+1)2 (n+2)2
+
n3 −3n2 −4n+4 4(n+1)2 (n+2)2
AC
∗ It can be easily verified that πnu < πu∗ iff
√ n4 +n3 +2 n2 − 3 n7 +14 n6 +18 n5 +7 n4 +24 n3 +40 n2 −16+4 n 2(n5 +2 n4 +n3 +n2 +4 n+4)
Let e1 = e2 =
<<
√ n4 +n3 +2 n2 + 3 n7 +14 n6 +18 n5 +7 n4 +24 n3 +40 n2 −16+4 n 2(n5 +2 n4 +n3 +n2 +4 n+4)
√ n4 +n3 +2 n2 − 3 n7 +14 n6 +18 n5 +7 n4 +24 n3 +40 n2 −16+4 n 2(n5 +2 n4 +n3 +n2 +4 n+4) √ n4 +n3 +2 n2 + 3 n7 +14 n6 +18 n5 +7 n4 +24 n3 +40 n2 −16+4 n . 2(n5 +2 n4 +n3 +n2 +4 n+4)
and Figure 4 compare the value of f (n),
g(n), e1 and e2 . Note that n ∈ [3, 8] since in this section we deal with n ≥ 3 and f (n) ≤ 41
1 . 2n−4
CR IP T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
AN US
Figure 4: Comparison between f (n), g(n), e1 and e2
∗ > πu∗ for It can be easily verified that g(n) and e1 intersect at g(n) = e1 = 0. Thus πnu ∗ ≤ πu∗ for e1 ≤ ≤ f (n). g(n) ≤ < e1 and πnu
Next consider the case f (n) < <
1 . 2n−4
Again, the analytic comparison between πu∗ and
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
∗ ∗ πnu is difficult and Figure 5 shows that πu∗ (n, ) − πnu (n, ) ≥ 0 numerically.
∗ (n, ) Figure 5: The value of πu∗ (n, ) − πnu
To summarize, if f (n) ≤
1 , 2n−4
Case 2: Suppose f (n) >
1 2n−4
∗ ∗ πnu > πu∗ for g(n) ≤ < e1 and πnu ≤ πu∗ for e1 ≤ ≤
1 . 2n−4
(this inequality holds for n ≥ 9). Clearly for g(n) < < 42
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
1 , 2n−4
e2 >
∗ πu∗ (n, ) = n π1 (0, n) − π0 (1, n) . Again πnu < πu∗ iff e1 < < e2 . Figure 6 shows that
1 2n−4
1 . 2n−4
Let h(n) = max(0, e1 ), Proposition 6 follows.
AN US
CR IP T
e1 ≤ <
∗ ∗ > e1 > g(n) numerically. Clearly πnu > πu∗ for g(n) ≤ < e1 and πnu ≤ πu∗ for
1 , 2n−4
g(n), e1 and e2
M
Figure 6: Comparison between
Total Number of Licensees in NUA
ED
A.9
PT
∗ Let Knu = k1n∗ + k2n∗ . For n ≥ 3
AC
CE
2(n+2) 2n+1 n−1 ∗ Knu (n, ) = n+1 + 21 4 1
For n = 2
∗ Knu (n, )
=
3 4+1
+1
if 0 < ≤ if
1 2n−4
≤≤
2 3n−5
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
2 n+1
if
2 n+1
≤ < 1,
if 0 < ≤ if
1
Proof. Follows immediately from A.6.
43
1 2n−4
1 2
1 2
≤<1
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
A.10
Entry Vs. No Entry
Our next goal is to compare our results with the existing literature on optimal licensing where entry is excluded. As shown in previous sections, UA has continuum of equilibrium points and there is no obvious way to predict which equilibrium will emerge. Therefore
CR IP T
we base our study on the comparison between G0 and Gnu , where G0 is the game defined similarly to Gnu , but where entry is excluded.
Suppose bidders do not use dominated strategies. The willingness to pay of each bidder in G0 (k), k ≥ 1, is uniquely determined and so is the innovator’s equilibrium payoff. The
AN US
next proposition characterizes the innovator’s optimal licensing strategy in G0 .
Proposition 7. The unique equilibrium licensing strategy of the innovator in G0 is: n−1 n+1 k0∗ (n, ) = + 4 1
if 0 < <
1 2
M
(i) For n ≥ 3
(ii) For n ≤ 2
if
2 3n−5
≤<
if
2 n+1
≤ < 1.
2 n+1
(26)
ED
2 3n−5
k0∗ (n, ) = n − 1.
PT
The proof follows from Kamien, Oren and Tauman (1992). Observe that by Proposition 7, k0∗ (n, ) = k1n∗ (n, ) where k1n∗ (n, ), the optimal number
CE
of incumbent licensees in Gnu , is given in Proposition A.6. This is not very surprising in light of Corollary 5. By propositions A.6 and 7 for less significant innovations (0 < ≤
1 ), 2n−4
AC
k0∗ (n, ) = k1∗ (n, ) and k2∗ > 0. In this case Gnu results in a higher diffusion of technology and bigger post-innovation number of firms. The difference in post-innovation number of firms is larger for less significant magnitude of innovation. The next proposition characterizes the innovator’s revenue and the post-innovation market price in G0 . Proposition 8. Consider the game G0 . (i) the innovator’s equilibrium payoff is 44
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
π0∗ (n, ) =
For n ≤ 2
(n−1) −(n−3)2 +2 n+1
(n++2)2 8(n+1)
π0∗ (n, )
if 0 < ≤ if
2 3n−5
≤≤
if
2 n+1
≤ < 1.
c+ p∗0 (n, ) = c+ c
1−(n−1) n+1
if 0 ≤ ≤
2−(n+1) 4(n+1)
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
if
2 n+1
≤ < 1.
2 n+1
1 − (n − 1) . n+1
M
p∗0 (n, ) = c + Proof. Follows from Proposition 7
2 3n−5
AN US
For n ≤ 2
2 n+1
(n − 1) − (n − 3)2 + 2 = . n+1
(ii) The post-innovation market price is For n ≥ 3
2 3n−5
CR IP T
For n ≥ 3
PT
in n and decreasing in .
ED
∗ Corollary 1. Suppose n ≥ 3. πnu (n, ) − π0∗ (n, ) and p∗0 (n, ) − p∗nu (n, ) are both decreasing
Proof. See A.12 of the Appendix.
CE
Corollary 1 asserts that the increment in the innovator’s revenue from allowing entry is smaller when there are larger number of incumbent firms or when the magnitude of the
AC
innovation is more significant. The same result holds true for the difference in the postinnovation market price. It is shown in Corollary 2 below that these differences vanishes if either n or is sufficiently large.
Corollary 2. Allowing entry will not change the innovator’s revenue nor the social welfare if either (i) > 0 and n is sufficiently large, or (ii) n ≥ 3 and is sufficiently large.
45
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Proof. By propositions A.6 and 7 k0∗ (n, ) = k1n∗ (n, ) for any n and , k2n∗ (n, ) = 0 for n ≥ 3 and
1 2n−4
≤ < 1.
Corollary 2 asserts that for any > 0 there is no difference in price nor in the innovator’s payoff between Gnu and G0 , for sufficiently large n. This is because the innovator sells
CR IP T
licenses to entrants only if he sells licenses to all (but one) incumbent firms (Corollary 5). For a market with large number of incumbents the innovator will not sell licenses to entrants even when entry is allowed. For any n ≥ 3, the same result holds for sufficiently large . Next we characterize the market structure that provides the highest incentive to innovate in G0 .
AN US
q Proposition 9. An oligopoly industry with size n = max 3, 2 2 +
revenue of the innovator in G0 .
Proof. See A.13 of the Appendix.
1
− 1 maximizes the
M
Proposition 9 asserts that when entry is excluded, the incentive to innovate is maximized
ED
when the market is oligopoly and the optimal size is decreasing in the magnitude of the innovation (with at least 3 firms). If however the market is open to entry the incentive to
Semi-Uniform auction
CE
A.11
PT
innovate is maximized in a monopoly market (Proposition 4).
Finally we introduce and analyze another auction mechanism, a semi-uniform auction
AC
(SUA), with a weaker asymmetry requirement than NUA. In this auction the innovator chooses (k1 , k2 ), 1 ≤ k1 ≤ n − 1 and k2 ≥ 0. The k1 highest incumbent bidders and the k2 highest entrant bidders win the auction and all of them pay the same license fee which is the lowest winning bid.18 Note that the willingness to pay of an incumbent firm is 0 if k1 = n. This is the reason we restrict our analysis to k1 ≤ n − 1. In SUA, like in NUA, the innovator 18
Note that in SUA the highest losing bid, if submitted by an entrant, may be higher than the willingness to pay of an incumbent winner. To avoid this problem we define the license fee as the lowest winning bid.
46
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
controls the number of incumbent and the number of entrant licensees, but unlike NUA the innovator charges every licensee the fee. Let Gsu be the game associated with SUA. In the subgame Gsu (k1 , k2 ) of Gsu each incumbent is willing to pay
CR IP T
wl (k1 , k2 ) = π1 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ) − π0 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ). Each entrant is willing to pay
AN US
we (k1 , k2 ) = π1 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ).
Clearly wl (k1 , k2 ) ≤ we (k1 , k2 ). In particular, for k1 + k2 < 1 , π0 (n − k1 , k1 + k2 ) > 0 and wl (k1 , k2 ) < we (k1 , k2 ). It can be verified that the innovator’s equilibrium payoff in Gsu (k1 , k2 ) is uniquely determined and it is (k1 + k2 )wl (k1 , k2 ) for k1 > 0 and k2 we (0, k2 ) for
M
k1 = 0.
Remark: Notice that some entrants may bid above the SUA license fee and still do not
ED
obtain a license. Yet in equilibrium the innovator has no incentive to increase k2 since it will increase competition and lower his total revenue.
AC
where
CE
PT
∗ Let πsu (n, ) be the innovator’s equilibrium payoff in Gsu .
0 ∗ πsu (n, ) = max πsu (n, ), π ˆsu (n, )
(27)
0 πsu (n, ) = max k2 we (0, k2 ) k2 ≥1
and
π ˆsu (n, ) =
max (k1 + k2 )wl (k1 , k2 ).
1≤k1 ≤n−1 0≤k2
(28)
When k1 = 0 each entrant licensee pays her entire profit for a license. But when k1 > 0 47
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
each entrant licensee pays less, only the willingness to pay of an incumbent licensee. ∗ ∗ ∗ (n, ). (n, ) ≤ πnu (n, ) ≤ πu∗ (n, ) and (ii) πsu Proposition 10. (i) πsu
Proof. (i) In UA the highest equilibrium payoff of the innovator is
CR IP T
ˆu (n, ) πu∗ (n, ) = max πu0 (n, ), π
where πu0 (n, ) = maxk≥1 kwe (0, k) and π ˆu (n, ) = max1≤k1 ≤n−1 (k1 + k2 )wh (k1 , k2 ). Part (i) 0≤k2
follows from wh (k1 , k2 ) ≥ wl (k1 , k2 ) for any (k1 , k2 ).
AN US
(ii) Follows from the fact that for any (k1 , k2 ), NUA yields the innovator a higher payoff than SUA.
The innovator in UA can choose only k while in SUA he can choose in addition the partition of k. In the first glance the innovator should always obtain a higher payoff in SUA
M
than in UA. But this is not necessarily the case. There are cases in which UA yields the innovator a higher payoff than SUA since an incumbent licensee is willing to pay more in UA
ED
for further entry prevention. As for the comparison between SUA and NUA, note that in NUA, in addition to choosing the partition (k1 , k2 ), the innovator can discriminate in price
PT
entrants from incumbent licensees. Therefore for any (k1 , k2 ) and k2 > 0, NUA yields the innovator a higher payoff than SUA.
CE
Next we characterize the market structure that provides the highest incentive to innovate in Gsu . Like in NUA, in SUA the innovator obtains the highest payoff in a monopoly market.
AC
Proposition 11. A monopoly industry maximizes the revenue of the innovator if he sells licenses by SUA. Proof. The proof is similar to that of Proposition 4, and hence omitted. We next analyze for any industry size n the optimal licensing strategy of the innovator
in SUA as a function of . Unlike NUA, the equilibrium licensing strategy is discontinuous 48
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
for one value of (the equilibrium revenue of the innovator is however continuous for any ). We will discuss this point after stating the next proposition. Proposition 12. Consider the equilibrium of Gsu . For n ≥ 3 there exists r(n), r(n) > 0, such that (i) if r(n) < ≤ 1 then the innovator sells positive number of licenses to entrants
CR IP T
only if he sells n − 1 licenses to all (but 1) incumbent firms. In this region the total number of licensees is larger, the less significant is the magnitude of innovation. (ii) At = r(n) the innovator has two optimal licensing strategies: either selling n−1 licenses to incumbent firms and some licenses to entrants, or selling n + 1 licenses to only entrants. (iii) if 0 < < r(n),
AN US
the innovator sells n + 1 licenses to entrants only.
The proof as well as the exact formula of the equilibrium strategy of the innovator in SUA appears in A.15 of the Appendix.
The reason for selling licenses only to entrant in SUA for less significant innovations is
M
the ability of the innovator to extract the entire industry profit of every entrant licensee. This is in contrast to the case where he sells some licenses also to incumbent firms. In the
ED
latter case the license fee an entrant pays is equal to the willingness to pay of an incumbent licensee which decreases to zero as → 0. To illustrate this point suppose that = 0.19 In
PT
this case if the innovator sells some licenses to incumbent firms, every licensee in SUA will pay zero license fee to the innovator. If instead, the innovator sells licenses only to entrants,
CE
he obtains the entire industry profit of all new entrant licensees (entrants wouldn’t be able to enter the market otherwise). If there are n incumbent firms the linear demand assumption
AC
implies that the innovator maximizes his revenue if the number of entrant licensees is n + 1. Let us compare the outcome of SUA with the outcome of NUA. First observe that for
> r(n) in both SUA and NUA the total number of licenses the innovator sells is decreasing in the magnitude of the innovation and the innovator may sell licenses to entrants, only if he also sells licenses to all (but 1) incumbent firms. The main difference between SUA and 19
This is the case where the innovator provides no improvement in cost but his technology allows free entry.
49
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
NUA is when < r(n). In this case, unlike NUA, the innovator in SUA sells licenses only to new entrants and not to incumbent firms. This shift in the innovator’s optimal strategy generates a discontinuity in the number of licenses at = r(n). In contrast, the innovator in NUA can discriminate the entrant licensees and can extract their entire industry profit
CR IP T
whether or not he sells licenses to incumbent firms. Therefore in NUA the innovator sells licenses to both new entrants and incumbent firms, even for small .
∗ ∗ Let Ksu and Knu be the total number of licenses the innovator sells in SUA and NUA,
respectively.
AN US
Proposition 13. Suppose n ≥ 2. There exists l(n), 0 < l(n) < 1, such that if 0 < ≤ l(n), ∗ ∗ (n, ). (n, ) > Ksu Knu
Proof. See A.18 of the Appendix.
Proposition 13 shows that comparing with SUA, NUA results in higher diffusion of tech-
M
nology for less significant innovations. As shown in Proposition 12 for less significant innovations, the innovator in SUA does not sell licenses to incumbent firms while in NUA he sells
ED
licenses to entrants in addition to all (but 1) incumbent firms. Therefore the ability to price discriminate new entrant licensees has positive effect not only on the innovator’s revenue but
Proof of Corollary 1
CE
A.12
PT
also on social welfare, as compare with SUA.20
AC
(i) For n ≥ 3
20
∗ πnu (n, ) − π ∗ (n, ) =
4(n+1)
0
When ≤ l(n) the market price in SUA is c + 1−2 is c + 2(n+1) (Proposition A.7).
2
1−(2n−4)
1−(n+1) 2(n+1)
50
if 0 ≤ ≤ if
1 2n−4
1 2n−4
(29)
≤ < 1,
(easy to verify) while the market price in NUA
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
2
1−(2n−4)
Let E =
4(n+1)
.
(2n − 4) − 1 (n − 2) ∂E = ∂ n+1
Observe that (29) is continuous in and
∂E ∂
≤ 0 for 0 < ≤
1 . 2n−4
Thus for any n ≥ 3,
∗ − π ∗ is non-increasing in for 0 < < 1. πnu
∗
− π (n, ) =
and (30) is continuous in n. Since
2
1−(2n−4) 4(n+1)
0
if 3 ≤ n ≤ if
1 2
1 2
+2
(30)
+ 2 ≤ n,
AN US
∗ πnu (n, )
CR IP T
Next observe that for 0 < < 1
(2n − 4) − 1 (2n + 8 + 1) ∂E = , ∂n 4(n + 1)2 ∗ πnu − π ∗ is non-increasing in n for n ≥ 3.
ED
M
(ii) For n ≥ 3 ∗
=
PT
p (n, ) −
p∗nu (n, )
1−(2n−4) 2(n+1)
0
if 0 ≤ ≤ if
1 2n−4
1 2n−4
(31)
≤ < 1,
Clearly for any n ≥ 3, p∗ (n, ) − p∗nu (n, ) is non-increasing in .
AC
CE
For 0 < < 1,
Let F =
∗
p (n, ) −
1−(2n−4) 2(n+1)
p∗nu (n, )
=
1−(2n−4) 2(n+1)
0
It can be easily verified that ∂F 6 + 1 =− ∂n (n + 1)2
51
if 3 ≤ n ≤ if
1 2
1 2+2
+ 2 ≤ n,
(32)
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Since (32) is continuous in n and
A.13
∂F ∂n
< 0, (32) is non-increasing in n for n ≥ 3.
Proof of Proposition 9
For n ≤ 2
(n−1) −(n−3)2 +2 n+1
(n++2)2
8(n+1)
π0∗ (n, )
if 0 < ≤ if
2 3n−5
if
2 n+1
2 3n−5
≤≤
2 n+1
≤ < 1.
(n − 1) − (n − 3)2 + 2 . = n+1
AN US
π0∗ (n, ) =
CR IP T
By Proposition 8, for n ≥ 3
(33)
Consider first n ≥ 3. First note that for any ≥ 21 , π0∗ = regardless of the value of n. We next focus on 0 < < 21 . 2 3
+
5 3
(or equivalently 0 < <
2 ). 3n−5
Denote
M
Subcase 1: Suppose n <
(n − 1)(3 + 2 − n) . n+1
ED
π0∗1 =
PT
It can be easily verified that
CE
∂π0∗1 (−n2 − 2n + 7 + 4) = , ∂n (n + 1)2
AC
r ∂π0∗1 1 > 0 if 0 ≤ n < 2 2 + − 1 ∂n
and
q Denote n∗1 = 2 2 +
Therefore 3 < n∗1 <
r ∗1 ∂πD 1 ≤ 0 if n ≥ 2 2 + − 1 ∂n 1
− 1. It can be easily verified that 3 < n∗1 <
2 + 53 3
for 0 < ≤
1 3n−5
2 3
+
5 3
for 0 < < 12 .
and n∗1 is the maximizer of π0∗ for 3 < n <
52
2 + 53 . 3
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Subcase 2: Suppose
2 3
5 3
+
2
≤n≤
− 1 (or equivalently
π0∗2 =
2 3n−5
≤≤
2 ). n+1
Deonte
(n + + 2)2 . 8(n + 1)
∂π0∗2 2 n2 + 22 n + 2 − 4 = ∂n 8(n + 1)2 and
CR IP T
It can be easily verified that
Therefore n∗2 =
2 3
+
5 3
AN US
2 ∂π0∗2 < 0 for 0 ≤ n < − 1. ∂n is the maximizer of π0∗2 for
Subcase 3: Suppose
2
2 3
+
5 3
≤n≤
2
− 1.
2 − 1 ≤ n ( n+1 ≤ ≤ 12 ). Then π0∗ (n, ) = and the innovator’s
payoff is the same for any
2
− 1 ≤ n.
M
Combining subcases 1-3, for n ≥ 3, since
π0∗
q is continuous in n, n = 2 2 + 1 − 1 is the ∗
∗ maximizer of π0∗ . Let πD be the innovator’s equilibrium payoff when n = n∗ .
√
√
(2+1)
ED
=
2 2+1−
√
(2+1)
(2+1)−
if 0 < < if
1 2
1 2
≤<1
PT
∗ πD
Consider next n = 2. By (33), π0∗ |n=2 = 31 2 + 23 . Finally consider the case n = 1. By
CE
(33) the innovator obtains 0 since we restrict k ≤ n − 1. To provide a more reasonable comparison we assume in this case that the innovator sells the license to the incumbent firm 0
AC
by fixed fee. The innovator’s payoff is then π0∗ |n=1 = π1 (0, 1) − π1 (1, 0) = 41 2 + 12 . q ∗ Figure 7 provides the comparison of the innovator’s payoff when n = 2 2 + 1 −1, n = 2 and n = 1. Clearly in G0 the innovator obtains the highest payoff in an oligopoly market q with n∗ = 2 2 + 1 − 1 firms.
53
AN US
CR IP T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Figure 7: The innovator’s payoff under different n
A.14
∗ The maximizer of πsu (n, )
M
∗ Let (k1s∗ (n, ), k2s∗ (n, )) be the maximizer of πsu (n, ).
0 n−1 s∗ k1 (n, ) = n+1 + 4 1
For n = 2
if 0 < < r(n)
1 2
n+1 q k2s∗ (n, ) = 2 2 + 1 − (n + 1) 0
CE
AC
and
PT
ED
For n ≥ 3
0 s∗ k1 (2, ) = 1
if r(n) ≤ ≤
2 3n−5
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
2 n+1
if
2 n+1
≤<1
if 0 < < r(n) if r(n) ≤ ≤ if
4 n2 +2n−7
if 0 < < r(2) if r(2) ≤ ≤ 1
54
4 n2 +2n−7
≤ < 1.
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
and
3 q k2s∗ (2, ) = 2 2 + 1 − 3 1 −1
if 0 < < r(2) if r(2) ≤ ≤ if
1 2
1 2
≤ < 1.
A.15
CR IP T
For n = 1, k1s∗ (1, ) = 0 and k2s∗ (1, ) = 2.21
Proof of Proposition 12
0 (n, ) and π ˆsu (n, ), respectively. Clearly Let (0, k20 ) and (kˆ1 , kˆ2 ) be maximizers of πsu
Lemma 6.
AN US
∗ (n, ). either (0, k20 ) or (kˆ1 , kˆ2 ) is a maximizer of πsu
n+1 0 k2 (n, ) = 1
Proof. Easy to verify.
if 0 < <
if
1 n+1
1 n+1
≤<1
M
Next we focus on the analysis of π ˆsu (n, ). Note that n = 1 does not apply here since
ED
k1 = 0 in this case. Lemma 7. (i) For n ≥ 3
AC
CE
PT
n−1 n+1 kˆ1 (n, ) = + 4 1
(ii) For n = 2
21
kˆ2 (n, ) =
if 0 < ≤ 1 2
2 3n−5
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
if
2 n+1
≤<1
q 2 2 + 1 − (n + 1) 0
kˆ1 (2, ) = n − 1
2 n+1
if 0 < ≤
4 n2 +2n−7
if
≤<1
4 n2 +2n−7
In Gsu we restrict k1 ≤ n − 1 therefore k1s∗ (1, ) = 0. If, instead, an auction with minimum reservation price is conducted to the monopoly incumbent, there are parameters under which the innovator sells licenses to the incumbent firm in addition to entrants.
55
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
kˆ2 (2, ) = Note that
4 n2 +2n−7
≤
2 3n−5
q 2 2 + 1 − (n + 1)
1
− (n − 1)
if 0 < ≤ if
1 2
1 2
≤<1
for n ≥ 3.
CR IP T
Proof. See A.16 of the Appendix. 0 (n, ) and To find the optimal licensing strategy of the innovator, we next compare πsu
π ˆsu (n, ). 0 Lemma 8. For n ≥ 2, πsu (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff < r(n).
AN US
The formula of r(n) is quite complicated and it appears in the Appendix (A.1). Proof. See A.17 of the Appendix.
Proposition 14. For n ≥ 2
M
We are now ready to characterize the optimal licensing strategy of the innovator.
ED
0 ∗ k1 (n, ) = kˆ1 (n, )
PT
and
CE
k2∗ (n, ) =
n+1
if 0 < < r(n) if r(n) ≤ < 1
if 0 < < r(n)
kˆ2 (n, )
if r(n) ≤ < 1.
AC
Proof. Follows immediately from lemmas 6, 7 and 8.
A.16
Proof of Lemma 7
We first shows that the innovator in SUA sells licenses to entrants iff he sells licenses to all (but one) incumbent firms. Lemma 9. For any n ≥ 2 and 0 < < 1, kˆ2 (n, ) > 0 iff kˆ1 (n, ) = n − 1. 56
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Proof. Denote k = k1 + k2 . Suppose first k =
1 .
In this case each licensee (entrant or
incumbent firm) pays the entire Cournot profit and by the assumption that incumbent firms have priority over entrants in case of a tie, the innovator sells licenses to incumbent firms and only when he exhausts all (but 1) incumbents will he sell licenses to entrants. Suppose next 1 ≤ k < 1 ,
CR IP T
∂wl (k1 , k − k1 ) (k − 1) > 0. = −2 ∂k1 (n − k1 + k + 1)2
(34)
For any k, 1 ≤ k < 1 , the license fee paid by each licensee is increasing in the number of incumbent licensees in k. Therefore the innovator in this case also sells licenses to incumbents
AN US
first. Lemma 9 follows.
By Lemma 9, if k ≤ n − 1, k1 = k and k2 = 0. If, however, k > n − 1, k1 = n − 1 and k2 = k − (n − 1). Therefore
max kwl (k, 0), max (n − 1 + k2 )wl (n − 1, k2 )
1≤k≤n−1
k2
M
π ˆsu (n, ) = max
(35)
Suppose first n ≥ 3. It can be verified that the maximizer of max1≤k≤n−1 kwl (k, 0) is
CE
PT
ED
n−1 n+1 k˜1 (n, ) = + 4 1
if 0 < ≤ 1 2
2 3n−5
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
if
2 n+1
≤<1
2 n+1
(36)
AC
and the maximizer of (n − 1 + k2 )wl (n − 1, k2 ) is k¯2 (n, ) =
(37) states that for
q 2 2 + 1 − (n + 1) 0
4 n2 +2n−7
if 0 < ≤
4 n2 +2n−7
if
≤<1
4 n2 +2n−7
(37)
≤ < 1, the innovator is best off selling 0 licenses to
entrants even if he sells n − 1 licenses to incumbent firms. By Lemma 9 kˆ1 (n, ) = k˜1 (n, ) and kˆ2 (n, ) = 0 in this case. As for 0 < ≤ 57
4 , n2 +2n−7
the innovator is best off selling
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
positive number of licenses to entrants if he sells n − 1 licenses to incumbent firms. Since 4 n2 +2n−7
≤
2 3n−5
by (36) the innovator in this case is best off selling n−1 licenses to incumbent
firms even if k2 = 0. Therefore kˆ1 (n, ) = n − 1 and kˆ1 (n, ) = kˆ2 (n, ) in this case. Part (i) of Lemma 7 follows.
A.17
CR IP T
Suppose next n = 2. By Lemma 9, kˆ1 (2, ) = 1. It can be easily verified that kˆ1 (2, ) = q min(2 2 + 1 − 3, 1 − 1).
Proof of Lemma 8
0 πsu (n, )
=
AN US
By Proposition 6 it is easy to verify that ((n+1)+1)2 4(n+1)
if 0 < < if
1 n+1
1 n+1
(38)
≤<1
By Proposition 7 it is easy to verify that for n ≥ 3
ED
M
√ √ 2 1 + 2 − 2 2 (n−1) −(n−3) +2 (n++2)2 8(n+1)
4 n2 +2n−7
if
4 n2 +2n−7
<≤
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
if
2 n+1
≤<1
2 √1 + 2 − √ 2 π ˆsu (n, ) =
AC
CE
For n = 2
n+1
PT
π ˆsu (n, ) =
if 0 < ≤
Suppose ≥
1 , n+1
2 n+1
if 0 < ≤ if
1 2
2 3n−5
1 2
≤<1
0 0 then πsu (n, ) = and π ˆsu (n, ) ≥ . In this case π ˆsu (n, ) ≥ πsu (n, ).
We next focus on the case 0 < ≤
1 . n+1
Case 1: Consider first n ≥ 7. In this case
1 n+1
58
≥
2 . 3n−5
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Subcase 1.1: Suppose
2 3n−5
≤≤
1 . n+1
0 (n, ) = − π ˆsu (n, ) − πsu √
2 0 ≤ ≤ where π ˆsu (n, ) ≥ πsu (n, ) iff − n+1
≤≤
0 Therefore π ˆsu (n, ) ≥ πsu (n, ) holds for
1 . n+1
Subcase 1.2: Suppose
4 n2 +2n−7
0 πsu (n, ) − π ˆsu (n, ) =
≤≤
2 . 3n−5
(5 n2 − 14 n + 13) 2 (−6 n + 10) + + (4 n + 4)−1 4(n + 1) 4(n + 1)
5n2 −14n+13 0 (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff > 0 for n ≥ 7. It can be easily verified that πsu 4(n+1) √ √ n2 −4 n+3 n2 −4 n+3 < 3 n−5−2 or > 3 n−5+2 . 5 n2 −14 n+13 5 n2 −14 n+13 √ √ n2 −4 n+3 3 n−5+2 n2 −4 n+3 Denote e1 = 3 n−5−2 and e = . Figure 8 compares the value 2 5 n2 −14 n+13 5 n2 −14 n+13
Thus if
4 n2 +2n−7
4 n2 +2n−7
and
≤≤
numerically. Note that e1 and
2 , 3n−5
4 n2 +2n−7
intersects at n = 16.19.
0 for 7 ≤ n ≤ 16.19, π ˆsu (n, ) > πsu (n, ) holds. For n > 16.19,
4 n2 +2n−7
≤ < e1 .
AC
CE
PT
ED
0 (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff πsu
2 3n−5
M
of e1 , e2 ,
AN US
Note that
2 . n+1
CR IP T
2 3n−5
√
(n + 1)2 2 − 2 8(n + 1)
Figure 8: Comparison between e1 , e2 ,
59
4 n2 +2n−7
and
2 3n−5
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Subcase 1.3: Suppose 0 < ≤ 0 (n, ) − π ˆsu (n, ) = πsu
4 . n2 +2n−7
n2 2 +(16
√
1+2 3/2 −22 2 −6 )n+16 4 n+4
√
1+2 3/2 −23 2 −6 +1
−
8
√
1+2 3/2 −11 2 +2
√
√
√
1+2 7/2 −12 2
√
1+2 5/2 +68 4 +34 3 +2 2 −3
√
≤n≤
−8
√
1+2 3/2 +11 2 +2
8
1+2 3/2 −11 2 +2
−48
√
q iff n ≤ 2 2 +
Note that for n ≥ 7, 0 < ≤ q f2 > 2 2 + 1 − 1 always holds. Note that is constraint to
−48
√
1+2 7/2 −12 2
√
1+2 5/2 +68 4 +34 3 +2 2 +3
− 1. Figure 9 shows that
1 14
since we are dealing in this
and n ≥ 7.
AC
CE
PT
ED
M
4 n2 +2n−7
1
AN US
4 n2 +2n−7
subcase ≤
√
√ 1+2 7/2 −12 1+2 5/2 +68 4 +34 3 +2 2 −3 2 √ √ √ √ −8 1+2 3/2 +11 2 +2 −48 1+2 7/2 −12 1+2 5/2 +68 4 +34 3 +2 2 +3 . 2
Denote f1 = − and f2 =
−48
CR IP T
0 It can be easily verified that πsu (n, ) ≤ π ˆsu (n, ) iff
q Figure 9: Comparison between f2 and 2 2 + 1 − 1
q Figure 10 compares the value of f1 and 2 2 +
1
q − 1. Note that f1 and 2 2 +
1
−1
0 intersects at = 0.0139 and n = 16.19. By Figure 10, πsu (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff either
< 0.0139 or > 0.0139 and n < f1 (). Or equivalently, when 0 < ≤
4 , n2 +2n−7
0 πsu (n, ) >
π ˆsu (n, ) iff either n > 16.19 or n ≤ 16.19 and < f1−1 (n) (the existence of f1−1 (n) is shown in Figure 1). 60
CR IP T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
AN US
q Figure 10: Comparison between f1 and 2 2 + 1 − 1
0 (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff 0 < < e1 . For 7 ≤ n ≤ Combining subcases 1.1-1.3, for n ≥ 17, πsu 0 16, πsu (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff 0 < < f1−1 (n). √ Case 2: Consider next 1 + 2 3 ≤ n < 7. In this case 4 n2 +2n−7
1 n+1
<
2 . 3n−5
1 . n+1
(5 n2 − 14 n + 13) 2 (−6 n + 10) + + (4 n + 4)−1 4(n + 1) 4(n + 1)
ED
0 πsu (n, ) − π ˆsu (n, ) =
≤≤
≤
M
Subcase 2.1: Suppose
4 n2 +2n−7
√ where 5 n2 − 14 n + 13 > 0 for 1 + 2 3 ≤ n < 7. By the same argument as in Subcase 4 n2 +2n−7
≤≤
PT
0 0 1.2, πsu (n, ) ≤ π ˆsu (n, ) iff e1 ≤ ≤ e2 . Figure 11 shows that πsu (n, ) ≤ π ˆsu (n, ) for 1 . n+1
CE
Subcase 2.2: Suppose 0 < ≤ Clearly ≤
1√ . 2(1+ 3)
4 n2 +2n−7
√ √ 2 , or equivalently 1+2 3 ≤ n ≤ min 7, −+2 2 + .
0 By the same argument as in Subcase 1.3, πsu (n, ) ≤ π ˆsu (n, ) iff f1 ≤
AC
n ≤ f2 . It can be easily verified that f2 > 7 for 0 < ≤ 2(1+1√3) . Figure 12 compares the value √ √ √ 2 2 0 of f1 and −+2 2 + . Therefore for 1 + 2 3 ≤ n ≤ min 7, −+2 2 + , πsu (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) 0 iff either 0 < < f1−1 (7) or f1−1 (7) ≤ and n < f1 . Or equivalently,πsu (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff
< f1−1 (n).
√ 0 Combining subcases 2.1-2.2, for 1 + 2 3 ≤ n < 7, πsu (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff < f1−1 (n). √ 1 4 1 Case 3: Suppose 3 ≤ n ≤ 1 + 2 3. In this case n+1 ≤ n2 +2n−7 . Consider 0 < ≤ n+1 61
4 n2 +2n−7
and
1 n+1
ED
M
AN US
Figure 11: Comparison between e1 , e2 ,
CR IP T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
PT
Figure 12: Comparison between f1 , f2 and
−+2
√
2 2 +
CE
√ (or equivalently, 3 ≤ n ≤ min 1 + 2 3, 1 − 1 ). Clearly ≤ 14 . By the same argument as 0 in Subcase 1.3, πsu (n, ) ≤ π ˆsu (n, ) iff f1 ≤ n ≤ f2 . Figure 13 compares the value of f1 , f2
and
1
− 1.
AC
√ 0 Figure 13 shows that for 3 ≤ n ≤ 1 + 2 3, πsu (n, ) > π ˆsu (n, ) iff < f1−1 (n). Finally suppose n = 2. Clearly for
1 3
0 0 (2, ) ≤ π ˆsu (2, ) since πsu (2, ) = and ≤ < 1, πsu
0 (2, ) > π ˆsu (2, ) iff either f1 () > 2 or f2 () < 2. It can π ˆsu (2, ) ≥ . For 0 < ≤ 31 , πsu
0 (2, ) > π ˆsu (2, ) iff either be easily verified that f2 () > 2 for any 0 < ≤ 31 . Therefore πsu 0 f1 () > 2. Or equivalently, πsu (2, ) > π ˆsu (2, ) iff < f1−1 (2). 0 To summarize, for any n ≥ 2, πsu (n, ) ≤ π ˆsu (n, ) iff 0 < < r(n) where r(n) = e1 for
62
CR IP T
ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT
Figure 13: Comparison between f1 , f2 and
A.18
Proof of Proposition 13
n+1 q 2 1 + 1 − 2
M
For n ≥ 3,
ED
∗ Ksu (n, ) =
PT
n−1 n+1 + 4 1
1 2
2(n+2) 2n+1 n−1 ∗ Knu (n, ) = n+1 + 21 4 1
CE AC
−1
AN US
n ≥ 16.19 and r(n) = f1−1 (n) for 1 ≤ n < 16.19.
1
if 0 < < r(n) if r(n) ≤ ≤
4 n2 +2n−7
if
4 n2 +2n−7
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
if
2 n+1
≤<1
if 0 < ≤
≤≤
2 3n−5
2 n+1
1 2n−4
if
1 2n−4
≤≤
2 3n−5
if
2 3n−5
≤≤
2 n+1
if
2 n+1
≤<1
→0
∗ ∗ ∗ Observe that Knu (n, ) −−→ 2n > n + 1. Since Knu (n, ) is continuous on and Ksu (n, ) =
n + 1 for 0 < < r(n), Proposition 13 follows. The same argument can be applied to case n = 2.
63