Property Rights Institutions and Firm Performance: A Cross-Country Analysis

Property Rights Institutions and Firm Performance: A Cross-Country Analysis

World Development Vol. 39, No. 4, pp. 648–661, 2011 Ó 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved 0305-750X/$ - see front matter www.elsevier.com/locate/wo...

219KB Sizes 2 Downloads 83 Views

World Development Vol. 39, No. 4, pp. 648–661, 2011 Ó 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved 0305-750X/$ - see front matter www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2010.09.009

Property Rights Institutions and Firm Performance: A Cross-Country Analysis MAHMUT YASAR The University of Texas at Arlington, Arlington, TX, USA CATHERINE J. MORRISON PAUL   University of California, Davis, CA, USA

and MICHAEL R. WARD * The University of Texas at Arlington, TX, USA Summary. — This paper empirically examines the link between firms’ performance and institutional quality using data for firms in 52 countries. We control for potential endogeneity by instruments alternatively based on legal origin and “related-firm” institutions, and by a “bribery” variable. We also use two indicators of institutional quality: firms’ expectations that their contractual and property rights will be protected by the legal system, and a property rights index from The Heritage Foundation. We incorporate firm-specific characteristics including industry type and international linkages. We find significantly positive relationships between firms’ performance and perceived property rights protection independent of other observable firm characteristics. Ó 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Key words — legal enforcement, property rights, institutions, firm performance, productivity, cross-country analysis

“Institutions are the humanly devised constraints that structure human interaction. They are made up of formal constraints (e.g., rules, laws, constitutions), informal constraints (e.g., norms of behavior, conventions, self-imposed codes of conduct), and their enforcement characteristics. Together they define the incentive structure of societies and specifically economies. Institutions and the technology employed determine the transaction and transformation costs that add up to the costs of production.” North (1994).

the security of property rights as one of the “three essential prerequisites of market economies.” In accordance with these predictions about the importance of institutions for economic development, recent macroeconomic studies have examined the role of institutional structure in international comparisons of economic performance using cross-country data. Some of these studies have explored this relationship by using clever instruments to control for reverse causality. For example, Hall and Jones (1999) use the distance from the equator as an instrument to show that differences in institutions and government policies are primary factors underlying countries’ income differences. La Porta, Lopez-deSilanes, Shleifer, and Vishny(1998, 1999), Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001), Djankov, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (2002), Glaeser, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (2004), and Acemoglu and Johnson (2005) similarly use instruments including legal and colonial origins and human capital to identify country-level growth, investment, and financial impacts of legal institutions. 1 These studies use country-level data to show that institutions matter for economic development. However, analyses

1. INTRODUCTION Over the past decade a sizable literature has emerged on the role of institutions in economic performance and growth. It has been hypothesized that institutional mechanisms create the “rules of the game” (North, 1990) that determine the strategies of both domestic and foreign firms (Wright, Filatotchev, Hoskisson, & Peng, 2005). Firms’ productivity and economic performance are thus expected to be augmented by higher quality institutions that are more supportive of firms’ business strategies and competitiveness. In particular, North (1990) defines an economic institution as, “. . . an arrangement between economic units that defines and specifies the ways by which these units can co-operate or compete” (p. 5). He argues that higher quality institutions reduce transaction and transformation costs, allowing firms to increase productivity by planning and organizing (or strategizing) more effectively, resulting in improved performance and competitiveness and thus higher industry- and country-level productivity growth. Further, Dixit (2009) emphasizes the “support” of economic activity and transactions provided by the “structure and functioning” of legal institutions, including

  Catherine J. Morrison Paul passed away on June 30, 2010. She was a leading economist in applied production economics and econometrics, who made significant contributions to the economic development field. She ranks amongst the top in both the quantity and quality of her published work. She will be missed greatly, but many will continue the work in her spirit. * We would like to thank the World Bank Enterprise Surveys Staff for very helpful discussions about the data. We also thank two anonymous referees for useful suggestions and comments. Final revision accepted: August 26, 2010. 648

PROPERTY RIGHTS INSTITUTIONS AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: A CROSS-COUNTRY ANALYSIS

at the country level, rather than firm level, often cannot identify the mechanisms through which better institutions affect economic performance. For example, better institutions may increase investments if they allow entrepreneurs to appropriate a greater share of the returns from investment. Otherwise, governments may specifically target the successful projects for taxation, either legally or extra-legally. Better institutions may allow increased efficiency if firms know that supplier contracts are more enforceable. Otherwise, a firm may inefficiently integrate into the production of the input so as to assure sufficient quality. Similarly, better institutions may make input markets thicker so that inputs (including labor inputs) become better suited to the specialized use; they may foster more competitive markets if firms are prevented from erecting legal entry barriers that potential entrants would have to overcome; and they may allow firms to offer more appropriate product variety by equalizing tax and regulatory treatment across sectors. Otherwise, firms will avoid products that face the highest tax rates or most onerous restrictions. Our goal in this paper is thus to examine how firms’ performance is affected by the institutional environment, using crosscountry firm-level data and specific indexes of institutional quality. Our firm-level treatment complements the macro-level studies; it allows us to empirically assess the economic performance effects of property rights or contractual enforcement institutions for different types of firms in different countries. Our underlying hypothesis is that better property rights institutions facilitate contracting and trade, which improves firms’ abilities to make productivity- and economic performance-enhancing business decisions. Institutions could also impose constraints on firm strategies, which determine performance in combination with industry conditions and firm capabilities (Peng, 2002; Wright et al., 2005). Institutional quality in this context is expected to affect firm performance through the domestic competitive environment as well as multinational investments and other international linkages. Our empirical framework explicitly models how firms’ performance is affected by their expectations that their contractual and property rights will be protected by the legal system. We estimate our model by ordinary least squares (OLS), controlling for firm heterogeneity, and by an instrumental variable (IV) estimator that also controls for endogeneity. For our IV estimator (Generalized Method of Moments, GMM), we use two alternative sets of instruments—legal origin dummy variables and the average levels of our institutional variable for other firms in a firm’s industry and location category. To check the robustness of our results we also directly accommodate potential endogeneity from unobserved corruption (bribery) by including an indicator for the revenue share spent on bribes in our estimating model. Further, we use two indicators of institutional quality: firms’ expectations that their contractual and property rights will be protected by the legal system, and a property rights index from The Heritage Foundation. We also adapt our estimated standard errors for potential within-cluster (within-country and sector) correlation using a method that produces cluster-robust standard errors. We find positive associations between two measures of firm performance, productivity, and profits, and the perceived quality of the legal system from survey responses about firms’ confidence in the legal protection of their property rights. The estimated performance impacts of legal system quality become even more pronounced after recognizing potential endogeneity of the institutional variable, via both instrumental variable estimation and directly controlling for impacts of “political connections.” We also find that other external and internal sources of technology are positively related to firm perfor-

649

mance; firms that export, import, have a foreign direct investment share and invest in research and development have significantly higher productivity levels than those that are not involved in these activities, independent of institutional effects. 2. THE LITERATURE In a seminal paper, Baumol (1990) argued that institutions affect economic growth because they help to determine whether entrepreneurship is directed toward productive or unproductive activities. Bowen and Clercq (2008) empirically tested this hypothesis, and found that institutions contribute to economic growth both by creating conditions that support entrepreneurial activity and by directing entrepreneurial effort toward high growth activities. More specifically, institutions that facilitate entrepreneurial activity provide incentives for firms to engage in more productive activity, whereas corruption reduces such incentives. In fact, better institutions (or less corruption) have been shown empirically to be associated with greater investment, economic growth, income equality, and technical efficiency, as well as with economic growth drivers such as human capital, urbanization, financial depth, and foreign trade (Delios & Henisz, 2003; Depken & LaFountain, 2006; Doh, Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck, Collins, & Eden, 2003; Friedman, Johnson, Kaufmann, & Zoido-Lobato´n, 2000; Henisz, 2004; Klein & Luu, 2003; Li, Xu, & Zou, 2000; Mauro, 1995; Murphy, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1993). 2 For example, Doh et al. (2003) show that corruption imposes both direct and indirect costs, which might be somewhat mitigated by strategies of multinational corporations. Klein and Luu (2003) find that technical efficiency is enhanced by both current policies supporting business stability and by expectations that these policies will remain in place. Empirical macroeconomic studies have more recently focused on the (aggregate) productivity effects of institutions (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1997, 1998, 1999; Hall & Jones, 1999; Acemoglu et al., 2001; Djankov et al., 2002; Easterly & Levine, 2003; Glaeser et al., 2004; Rodrik, Subramanian, & Trebbi, 2004; Kwok & Tadesse, 2006). 3 For example, Hall and Jones (1999) find that differences in institutions are primary factors underlying countries’ differences in capital accumulation, educational attainment, and productivity. Acemoglu et al. (2001) show significant effects of colonial origins and resulting institutional structure on economic performance. Rodrik et al. (2004) document a significant impact on income levels of institutional quality, controlling for geography and openness. Loayza, Oviedo, and Serven (2005) argue that the mechanism underlying such effects is that high quality institutions increase productive efficiency by encouraging firms to invest in technology (capital) and in the creation and transfer of knowledge. 4 Aron (2000) attributes the performance effects of better institutions to property rights enforcement that mitigates bureaucratic red tape and rent-seeking activities, thus releasing firm resources for more efficient investments. More generally, higher quality institutions will reduce two types of production costs faced by firms: transformation costs (the cost of production and processing), and transaction costs (such as the costs of establishing contracts and relations with other agents, of searching for appropriate trading partners and products, of negotiation, and of monitoring and enforcing contracts). The latter is likely to be affected the most by institutional factors, as Aron (2000) states: “. . .Transaction costs, for example, are far higher when property rights or the rule of law are not reliable. In such situations private firms typically

650

WORLD DEVELOPMENT

operate on a small scale, perhaps illegally in an underground economy, and may rely on bribery and corruption to facilitate operations. Transformation costs, too, can be raised substantially because unenforceable contracts mean using inexpensive technology and operating less efficiently and competitively on a short-term horizon.” Such costs determine firm productivity and profitability. In particular, strong property rights and contract institutions create a business environment that encourages firms to produce on a larger scale, use better technology, have longer-term horizons, and operate within the legal framework, which all facilitate economic performance and competitiveness (Aron, 2000). Poor quality institutions instead make contract enforcement difficult or make the payment of bribes necessary, sometimes prohibitively increasing the cost of doing business. The implication from macro empirical studies that better institutions positively affect aggregate economic performance by enhancing firm-level productivity and profitability is also consistent with the international business perspective that the institutional “leg” of the “strategy tripod” (along with industry and firm characteristics), determines firms’ strategies and resulting economic performance and competitiveness. Our treatment, using firm-level data to directly evaluate the effects of institutional quality on firms’ productive and accounting performance, controlling for industry type and other firm characteristics, thus can be thought of as combining these three components of firm behavior developed in Peng et al. (2008). Specifically, our hypothesis to be tested empirically is that a better institutional environment (represented by firms’ expectations about property rights protection by the legal system) results in better productive and accounting performance of firms, independent of other firm characteristics that might affect economic performance such as industry type and international linkages. 3. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION AND DATA DESCRIPTION Our empirical model relates firms’ performance to a measure of institutional quality (property rights enforcement, Legal, defined below), controlling for a variety of firm characteristics. The regression equation representing this relationship for our firm-level data, which we estimate for 17,082 observations in 52 countries, is specified as: ln P j ¼ b0 þ b1 Legalj þ b2 Agej þ b3 Age2j þ b4 Expj þ b5 FDI j þ b6 Impj þ b7 CU j þ b8 SLj þ b9 ln RDj þ b10 SZDumj þ b11 IndDUM j þ b12 YRDumj þ uj :

ð1Þ

The dependent variable (ln P) represents firms’ performance, for which we use two proxies. The first proxy is labor productivity (LP), defined as output (Y) per unit of labor input (L), Y/L (or in log-form as ln LP = ln Y  ln L), 5 which represents firms’ productive performance. The second is the log of gross profit, defined as total revenue minus the cost of goods sold, which represents firms’ accounting performance. The independent variables, in addition to Legal, are: the age of the firm (Age); whether or not the firm is an exporter (Exp); whether or not the firm has a foreign share (FDI); the firms’ share of imported material inputs and supplies (Imp); the firm’s capacity utilization (CU); the share of skilled production workers, professionals and managers in total employment (SL); the natural log of the firm’s R&D expenditures (ln RD) 6; and size (SZDum), industry, (IndDum) 7 and year (YRDum) dummy variables.

(a) Data The variables in Eqn. (1) are based on the “Investment Climate Survey,” a cross-section survey of firms conducted during 2000–05 8 by the World Bank in various countries grouped into six regions. 9 For the few countries in which surveys were conducted in two years, we used the data for the most recent year. 10 We also dropped observations that were clearly erroneous, such as negative values of age, output, and labor. 11 After dropping such observations, we had 17,802 observations for 52 countries. The data are based on face-to-face interviews with firms’ managers and bookkeepers or accountants. 12 The sampling method was designed to ensure a random sample, 13 with adequate representation of firms by industry, 14 size, 15 ownership, export orientation, and location. We made adjustments so that all the sales and cost variables were in US dollar (USD) currency units, to make the data comparable across the countries in our sample. 16 The industry value added data for the tradable sector come from the Centre D’etudes Prospectives et D’informations Internationales’ Trade, Production and Bilateral Protection Database database. The data were collected by the United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO), which is the most comprehensive source of industry-level production data across the countries. The data include information on 28 ISIC (Revision 2) manufacturing sectors at the three digit level for 180 countries for 1980–2004. The value added data for the non-tradable sector are from the United Nations’ Statistical Division. We weighted the observations by the average value added share of each industry in each country from 1980 to 2004 to adjust the data for unequal sampling probabilities, to obtain unbiased estimates of our model coefficients. 17, 18 As we elaborate below, we also adjusted the standard errors for potential within-cluster (within-country and within sector) correlation using cluster-robust standard errors, as when there is similarity within countries and sectors (clusters), but heterogeneity between clusters, one would expect high estimated standard errors. Our institutional variable (Legal) was phrased in the survey as follows: “I am confident that the judicial system will enforce my contractual and property rights in business disputes. To what degree do you agree with this statement? Do you (read 1–6)? 1. Fully disagree; 2. Disagree in most cases; 3. Tend to disagree; 4. Tend to agree; 5. Agree in most cases; 6. Fully agree.” 19 We converted this variable to 10–60 to make its units more consistent with our alternative property rights index, which is measured from 0 to 100. The other explanatory variables are included to control for firm heterogeneity and for alternative productivity factors. In particular, the Exp, FD,I and Imp variables control for productivity effects of international technology transfer found in various studies (including Buckley, Clegg, & Wang, 2002; Feinberg & Majumdar, 2001; Hejazi & Safarian, 1999; Liu, Siler, Wang, & Wei, 2000; Yasar & Paul, 2007). For example, studies such as Kraay (1999) and Castellani (2001) find significant firm-level productivity effects from exporting. Caves (1974), Globerman (1979), and Aitken and Harrison (1999) find that both industries and firms with higher foreign shares (FDI) are more productive. Coe and Helpman (1995), Keller (2002), and Rodrigue and Kasahara (2004) find significant productivity effects from importing technology at the country, industry, and firm levels, respectively. Variables for other firm characteristics include Age because more production experience would be expected to enhance

PROPERTY RIGHTS INSTITUTIONS AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: A CROSS-COUNTRY ANALYSIS

productivity. Capacity utilization (CU) controls for the average utilization of a firm’s fixed inputs. Own-firm R&D (ln RD) captures internal knowledge creation. The share of skilled production workers, professionals, and managers in total employment (SL) represents firms’ labor skill heterogeneity. As explained below, we also tried using real GDP, openness and the share of investment in real GDP data from the Penn World Tables (version 6.2) as variables in our model, with little support. The remaining variables are firm-specific controls for firm size, industry, and year. Summary statistics for the variables are presented in Table 1. To check for potential inference problems from multicollinearity of the explanatory variables, we constructed a correlation matrix (presented in Table A1) that did not reveal problematically high correlations. Multicollinearity tests based on variance inflation factors (VIFs) and tolerance levels (presented in Table A2) further confirmed that relying on the variables in (1) is justified. Specifically, there were no variables with VIFs greater than 10 and tolerance levels less than 0.1, which are generally accepted thresholds to identify multicollinearity problems.

651

improvement in institutions (La Porta et al., 1997). For this method, in a first stage we regressed Legal on dummy variables for British, 25 French, and German legal origins (summarized in Table 2, where the socialist legal origin is the base group) and the exogenous variables in Eqn. (1). In a second stage we regressed the performance variable ln Pj on the predicted value of Legal (from the first stage regression) and the other variables in Eqn. (1). To evaluate the correlation between the instruments and the error term, we used the Sargan test of overidentifying restrictions. The null hypothesis is that the instruments and the error terms are independent, so rejecting this hypothesis would invalidate the use of the instruments. To assess whether our instruments are sufficiently related to our Legal variable, we use an F-test of the joint significance of the instruments in reduced form, which supports their use. As a final adaptation for potential endogeneity, we include a bribery indicator as an argument of estimating Eqn. (1). 26 This approach directly recognizes that the extent of bribery is a key omitted variable that might generate endogeneity. Our bribery variable Br is defined as the share of informal payments to public officials to “get things done” as a percent of annual sales value.

4. ESTIMATION METHOD (a) Fully standardized coefficients We used both ordinary least squares (OLS) and an instrumental variable (IV) estimator to empirically estimate our model in Eqn. (1). The IV estimator was used to control for potential endogeneity of our primary variable of interest, Legal. 20 To briefly reiterate the use of the instrumental variable estimator (Generalized Method of Moments, GMM), suppose we are interested in estimating y i ¼ x0i b þ ui . In the presence of endogeneity, one must control for potential estimation biases by specifying J instruments in an associated vector zi. For b to be a consistent estimator, the population moment condition E½ðy i  x0i bÞzi  ¼ 0 should hold. 21 The GMM estimator the corresponding sample moment condition Pn solves 1 0 i ðy i  xi bÞzi ¼ 0 by choosing values of b that drive this N condition as close to zero as possible by minimizing: " #0 " # N N 1 X 1 X 0 0 ð2Þ ðy  xi bÞzi XN ðy  xi bÞzi ; QN ðbÞ ¼ N i i N i i where XN is a weighting matrix. Because GMM allows one to optimally choose the weighting matrix, it is more efficient than a standard two-stage least squares estimator. We used two sets of instruments for Legal to estimate our model by the GMM method. First, we used the average levels of the Legal variable for other firms (j – i) in a firm’s industry 22 and location category 23 for each country and year as an instrument. Assuming the industry averages are independent of firm-specific effects (i.e., they are unaffected by firm idiosyncratic productivity or profitability shocks), these industry- and location-based instruments will be uncorrelated with the error term, as required for valid instruments. Further, since the industry-specific variables define the environment in which a firm operates (Jaffe, 1986), we can expect the endogeneous variable and the instruments to be related. To check the sensitivity of our results to the specification of instruments, we alternatively used the legal origin indicators of La Porta et al. (1997, 1998, 1999) as instruments for Legal. La Porta et al. (1997, 1998, 1999) and Glaeser et al. (2004) argue that legal origin is a valid instrument because Europeans imposed their own legal systems on the countries they colonized, 24 and that the greater protections of property against the state embodied in common law systems represents an

To facilitate the interpretation of our estimated coefficients, we compute “fully standardized coefficients.” 27 Assuming that rp is the unconditional standard deviation of the independent variable Xp, the fully standardized coefficient for Xp is calculated as bFS p ¼ rp bp =ry . This measure indicates that for a standard deviation increase in Xp, the dependent variable yi is expected to increase by bFS p standard deviations, holding all other variables constant. (b) Clustering It is expected that, in our cross-country firm-level data, firms in a single country (or cluster) will have similarities not shared by firms in other countries due to both observable and unobservable factors. For example, prices for material and labor and the effects of macro factors such as a recession would be expected to be similar for firms in the same country. One might therefore expect correlations among the residuals of the estimating equation for different firms in the same country. Failing to adjust for such dependencies may result in biased standard errors (the estimated standard errors will be too small), mis-specified test statistics (the test statistic will be too large), and inefficiency of OLS estimation. 28 We thus adapted our estimated standard errors for potential within-cluster (within-country and sector) correlation using a method that produces cluster-robust standard errors. P The ro 1 Nc 0 29 0 ðX X Þ  bust cluster variance estimator is j¼1 uj uj  ðX 0 X Þ1 (where Nc is the total number of clusters, PN j uj ¼ i¼1 ei X i , Nj is the number of observations in cluster j, ei is the residual for the ith observation and Xi is a vector of explanatory variables), whereas the OLS variance estimator P is s2  ðX 0X Þ1 (where s2 ¼ 1=N  k Ni¼1 e2i ). 5. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION Our estimates for Eqn. (1), with firm performance alternatively characterized by labor productivity and gross profits,

652

WORLD DEVELOPMENT Table 1. Summary statistics (No. of Obs. = 17,082)

Variable

Mean

Standard deviation

Log output (ln Y) Log labor (ln L) Log material (ln M) Log capital (ln K) Labor productivity (LP = log(output/labor)) Value added labor productivity (LPVA = log(value added/labor)) Log gross profit (GP) Legal system will enforce contractual and property rights in business disputes (Legal)a Age of the firm (Age)b Exporting dummy (Exp)c Foreign direct investment dummy (FDI)d Import share (Imp)e Capacity utilization (CU)f Skilled labor share (SL)g Research and development expenditures dummy (ln RD)h Bribery (Br)i Natural log of real GDP per capita (ln GDP)j Openness (OP)k Investment share of real GDPl Property rights (PR)m

12.391 2.751 11.570 7.313 9.640 9.175 11.910 38.422 15.941 0.134 0.104 0.230 81.478 0.723 0.926 0.979 2.840 79.267 15.431 48.295

3.101 1.611 2.909 3.624 2.894 2.837 3.080 13.960 16.208 0.341 0.306 0.356 19.029 0.291 2.882 3.604 0.899 37.815 7.870 19.212

a

Legal: in the survey, managers were asked whether they are confident that the judicial system will enforce their contractual and property rights in business disputes. The level of confidence is measured in six increasing categories (1. Fully disagree; 2. Disagree in most cases; 3. Tend to disagree; 4.Tend to agree; 5.Agree in most cases; 6. Fully agree). We converted this variable to 10–60 so that it is more comparable to the property right index. b Age: mangers were asked in what year their firm began operations. c Exp: a dummy variable that is equal to one if firm is an exporter, and zero otherwise. d FDI: a dummy variable that is equal to one if firm is owned by the foreign private sector, and zero otherwise. e Imp: managers were asked what percent of their establishment’s material inputs and supplies are imported. f CU: capacity utilization is the amount of output actually produced relative to the maximum amount that could be produced with existing machinery and equipment and regular shifts. g SL: the share of skilled production workers, professionals, and managers in total employment. h ln RD: managers were asked how much their establishment spent on design or R&D last year, where spending includes wages and salaries of R&D personnel, such as scientists and engineers; materials; education costs; and subcontracting costs. i Br: the survey question reads: “We have heard that establishments are sometimes required to make gifts or informal payments to public officials to “get things done” with regards to customs, taxes, licenses, regulations, services, etc. On average, what percent of annual sales value would such expenses cost a typical firm like yours?” This variable is available for 13,944 observations. j ln GDP: natural log real GDP per capita. Real GDP is obtained by adding up consumption, investment, government expenditures and exports, and subtracting imports. This variable is from the Penn World Tables, version 6.2. k OP: exports plus imports divided by real GDP. This variable is from the Penn World Tables, version 6.2. l INV: investment share of real GDP. This variable is from the Penn World Tables, version 6.2. m PR: property rights index from The Heritage Foundation. This variable is scaled from 10 to 100. Higher values imply better institutional quality and vice versa. We rescaled this variable to 10–60 to make it comparable to Legal.

are presented in Tables 3 and 4, respectively. The OLS parameter estimates are reported in the first columns of these tables, with one, two, and three asterisks indicating statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels. The cluster-robust standard errors (which are almost double the unadjusted OLS standard errors), are in parentheses. The estimates show that both productivity and profitability are positively associated with our Legal variable representing a firm’s expectations that the legal or judicial system will enforce their contractual and property rights in business disputes. The fully standardized coefficients for the independent variables of Eqn. (1) are reported in the second columns of Tables 3 and 4. These estimates indicate that a one standard deviation increase in Legal is associated with a 0.058 standard deviation increase in labor productivity and a 0.053 increase in profit, controlling for the other variables. This supports the findings of macro studies that better institutions create an environment in which firms can organize their activities more efficiently, resulting in greater economic performance and competitiveness. For more interpretation of these values, consider the impact of Legal on productivity across specific countries in the data

set. For example, the average values for Legal for the Philippines and Germany are 37 and 47, respectively, so the difference in Legal is ten. These estimates thus imply that if the Philippines had a legal system equivalent to Germany, labor productivity would be about 12.07% higher ([100  (exp (0.012)  1)  10] = 12.07). That is, a one unit increase in Legal increases labor productivity by 0.012, so productivity would increase by 1.2% (100  (exp(0.012)  1)) as a result of a one unit change in Legal, or 12.07% for a ten unit change in Legal. 30 Our OLS estimates also show that firm productivity and profits are positively and significantly related to international connections through exports, imports, and foreign direct investment, conditional on the control variables. The fully standardized coefficients show that a one standard deviation increase in the materials import share increases firm productivity and profit by 0.019 and 0.034 standard deviations, respectively, although the impact on productivity is not statistically significant. Having a foreign share is associated with increased productivity and profit of 0.032 and 0.046 standard deviations, respectively. These results corroborate suggestions in the

PROPERTY RIGHTS INSTITUTIONS AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: A CROSS-COUNTRY ANALYSIS

653

Table 2. Summary statistics for the macro variables Country

Year

Obs.

British

French

German

Socialist

PR

ln GDP

OP

INV

Albania Armenia Bangladesh Belarus Benin Bosnia and Herzegovina Brazil Bulgaria Cambodia Croatia Czech Republic Ecuador El Salvador Estonia Georgia Germany Greece Guatemala Honduras Hungary Ireland Kazakhstan Korea, Rep. Kyrgyz Republic Latvia Lithuania Macedonia, FYR Madagascar Mali Mauritius Moldova Nicaragua Oman Philippines Poland Portugal Romania Russian Federation Senegal Slovak Republic Slovenia South Africa Spain Sri Lanka Tajikistan Tanzania Turkey Uganda Ukraine Uzbekistan Vietnam Zambia

2005 2005 2002 2005 2004 2005 2003 2005 2003 2005 2005 2003 2003 2005 2005 2005 2005 2003 2003 2005 2005 2005 2005 2005 2005 2005 2005 2005 2003 2005 2005 2003 2003 2003 2005 2005 2005 2005 2003 2005 2005 2003 2005 2004 2005 2003 2005 2003 2005 2005 2005 2002

141 293 818 179 155 99 1,569 201 203 152 224 343 453 151 101 1,045 373 429 393 453 422 400 419 149 140 160 100 208 107 127 214 428 47 571 715 366 491 358 164 133 194 511 523 367 173 98 298 172 414 212 455 171

0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 1

0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0

0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

1 1 0 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 0

30 50 30 30 30 10 50 30 30 30 70 30 50 70 30 90 50 30 50 70 90 30 70 30 50 50 30 50 50 70 50 30 50 50 50 70 30 30 50 50 50 50 70 50 30 30 50 50 30 30 10 50

2.402 2.313 1.685 3.371 1.292 2.179 3.041 3.050 0.405 3.263 3.679 2.530 2.622 3.474 2.426 4.290 3.706 2.419 1.875 3.500 4.285 2.943 3.822 2.288 3.265 3.283 2.730 0.871 1.115 3.784 1.864 2.303 3.853 2.410 3.221 3.920 2.719 3.294 1.520 3.340 3.970 3.176 4.040 2.466 1.575 0.867 2.811 1.125 2.678 2.333 1.852 0.924

55.090 73.620 37.270 143.620 57.740 82.110 22.840 116.760 116.640 99.390 132.000 68.060 69.830 180.350 60.920 66.400 61.630 48.760 98.340 151.550 184.100 105.030 78.300 89.430 91.590 96.140 112.150 68.620 63.190 124.150 126.160 74.520 91.140 102.960 62.220 74.320 71.370 68.090 69.250 144.090 115.830 52.790 61.200 89.160 154.600 37.960 54.160 34.180 119.860 60.010 112.500 52.470

45.270 9.610 11.980 14.470 7.560 8.790 16.490 8.060 5.420 13.290 20.410 12.830 8.570 14.910 6.950 23.340 24.200 5.970 18.540 24.340 23.560 7.960 34.790 8.840 13.550 11.810 12.150 4.120 6.320 12.150 8.890 13.770 6.700 13.970 22.690 25.960 10.830 8.900 4.910 18.620 27.950 7.720 26.010 12.330 3.390 3.540 19.360 3.130 8.180 5.760 15.810 12.840

Notes: (1) data on the countries’ legal origin come from La Porta et al. (1997, 1998, 1999). (2) PR is from The Heritage Foundation. (3) ln GDP, OP and INV are from the Penn World Tables, version 6.2.

literature that multinational firms may be less vulnerable to institutional limitations (Henisz & Williamson, 1999). Productivity also tends to be significantly related (positively) to exporting. Internal innovation through direct investment in R&D also appears to enhance performance. For the R&D performing sub-sample, a standard deviation increase in R&D increases firms’ productivity and profit by 0.069 and 0.079 standard deviations, respectively, holding all other variables constant.

Domestic as well as foreign sources of technology are thus positively related to performance, as suggested by the endogenous growth literature (Coe & Helpman, 1995; Eaton & Kortum, 1996; Keller, 2002), although our capacity utilization and skilled labor share variables are not significantly related to the performance indicators. Our findings for these technology transfer variables should be interpreted cautiously since our empirical analysis is restricted to cross-sectional data that precludes standard

654

WORLD DEVELOPMENT

adaptations for correlation of these variables with the error term due to measurement error, omitted variables, simultaneity, or self-selection. That is, these findings cannot necessarily be interpreted as a causal relationship since the methodology used does not control for associated biases. However, comparable results for one country’s panel data using alternative methodologies that control for such issues does support a causal relationship (Yasar & Paul, 2007, 2008). (a) Endogeneity of “Legal” Our OLS estimates reveal a positive and significant relationship between our institutional variable, Legal, and firm productive and accounting performance, controlling for other observed sources of economic performance. However, it is possible that variables not captured in our data, such as bribes to government officials, have an impact on both firm performance and the quality of property rights enforcement. It is also possible that recently successful firms due to idiosyncratic avoidance of legal complications unduly attribute their success to the legal environment—or in reverse, that firms that are unsuccessful due to innate managerial problems may blame their failure on the legal system. 31 The error term will then be correlated with the performance measures and our OLS estimates will be biased. To control for this potential endogeneity of our Legal variable, we alternatively estimated our model using GMM methods, as explained above. The results denoted IV1, in the fifth columns of Tables 3 and 4, are based on the instruments computed for firms i as the average levels of Legal for other firms (j – i) in firm i’s industry and location category for each country and year. Using the Sargan test of overidentifying restrictions to test for correlation between the instruments and error term, the P-values are 0.275 and 0.285 for productivity and profit, respectively, validating the use of these instruments.

We also used an F-test to examine whether the instruments are sufficiently related to our Legal variable by estimating their joint significance in reduced form. The F-statistics for this test reported in Tables 3 and 4 show that the instruments are highly related to Legal, and that the equation is not weakly identified. The instruments were also individually significant in the first stage. These results further support the use of these instruments to accommodate any endogeneity. Our GMM results based on these instruments, and the fully standardized coefficients for the independent variables, are reported in the fifth and sixth columns of Tables 3 and 4 for productivity and profit, respectively. These estimates show that each standard deviation increase of the Legal variable increases firms’ productivity and profit by 0.499 and 0.410 standard deviations, respectively, holding the other variables constant. Controlling for the potential endogeneity of Legal by IV estimation thus raises its estimated performance effect, indicating that the OLS coefficients are under-estimated. The coefficients for the remaining independent variables are similar in terms of both their magnitude and significance for the IV estimation. This greater impact can be clarified by an example. The average values for Legal for Turkey and Germany are 42 and 47, respectively, so the difference in Legal is 5. This implies that if Turkey had the legal system of Germany, labor productivity would increase by 54.08% ([100  (exp(0.104)  1)  5] = 54.08). That is, a one unit increase in Legal increases productivity by 0.104, which indicates that productivity increases by 10.96% (100  (exp(0.104)  1)) as a result of a one unit increase in Legal, or 54.08% for a five unit increase in Legal. To check the robustness of these IV results, we alternatively used the legal origin indicators (illustrated in Table 2) of La Porta et al. (1997, 1998, 1999) as instruments for Legal. Our Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions for this model resulted in P-values of 0.762 and 0.525 for productivity and profit, confirming the exogeneity of the instruments. F-tests

Table 3. OLS and IV parameter estimates [dependent variable = natural log of labor productivity] Independent variables

Ordinary least squares (OLS) OLS

bFS p

OLSBR

Legal system (Legal) 0.012 (0.005)** 0.058 0.013 (0.005)*** Age of the firm (Age) 0.021 (0.004)*** 0.119 0.022 (0.004)*** 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.083 0.000 (0.000)*** Age squared (Age2) Exporting dummy (Exp) 0.457 (0.166)*** 0.054 0.371 (0.098)*** Foreign direct investment dummy (FDI) 0.303 (0.118)*** 0.032 0.270 (0.115)** Import share (Imp) 0.152 (0.146) 0.019 0.001 (0.162) Capacity utilization (CU) 0.007 (0.005) 0.048 0.007 (0.005) Skilled labor share (SL) 0.028 (0.208) 0.010 0.082 (0.145) Natural log of 1 + R&D (ln RD) 0.069 (0.026)*** 0.069 0.065 (0.025)*** Bribery (Br) 0.042 (0.020)** Observations R-squared F-statistic of instruments (P-value) Sargan statistic (P-value)

17,082 0.64 0.000

13,944 0.55 0.000

Instrumental variables (IV) bFS p 0.073 0.142 0.092 0.050 0.033 0.000 0.049 0.020 0.077 0.084

IV1

bFS p

IV2

bFS p

0.104 (0.022)*** 0.499 0.186 (0.030)*** 0.896 0.016 (0.004)*** 0.088 0.007 (0.007) 0.042 0.000 (0.000) 0.053 0.000 (0.000) 0.011 0.353 (0.109)*** 0.042 0.409 (0.104)*** 0.048 0.223 (0.146) 0.024 0.024 (0.132) 0.003 0.375 (0.129)*** 0.046 0.622 (0.134)*** 0.077 0.009 (0.004)** 0.058 0.001 (0.006) 0.005 0.219 (0.172)** 0.048 0.131 (0.107)* 0.029 0.076 (0.016)*** 0.075 0.046 (0.022)** 0.046 17,040 0.951 0.000 0.275

17,082 0.912 0.000 0.762

Notes: (1) the OLS regressions reported in this table include dummy variables that control for size, year, and industry characteristics. The IV regressions include dummy variables that control for size and year. The coefficients for these dummy variables are not reported here in the interest of space, but are available from the authors upon request. (2) The standard errors are clustered by country and sector. The clustered standard errors are much larger, by up FS SY   to a factor of two. (3) bFS p are the fully standardized coefficients for Xp (bp ¼ rp bp =rY ¼ rp bp ). (4) IV1 denotes the instrumental variables results in which average levels of the Legal variable for other firms (j – i) in a firm’s industry and location category for each country and year are used as instruments. (5) IV2 denotes the instrumental variables results in which dummy variables for English, French, and German legal origin are used as instruments. Socialist legal origin is the omitted category. * Significant at the 10% level. ** Significant at the 5% level. *** Significant at the 1% level.

PROPERTY RIGHTS INSTITUTIONS AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: A CROSS-COUNTRY ANALYSIS

655

Table 4. OLS and IV parameter estimates [dependent variable = natural log of profit] Independent variables

Ordinary least squares (OLS) OLS

Legal system (Legal) Age of the firm (Age) Age squared (Age2) Exporting dummy (Exp) Foreign direct investment dummy (FDI) Import share (Imp) Capacity utilization (CU) Skilled labor share (SL) Natural log of research and development expenditures (ln RD) Bribery (Br) Observations R-squared F-statistic of instruments (P-value) Sargan statistic (P-value)

bFS p

OLSBR

Instrumental variables (IV) bFS p

IV1

bFS p

IV2

bFS p

0.012 (0.005)** 0.053 0.014 (0.004)*** 0.067 0.091 (0.020)*** 0.410 0.184 (0.029)*** 0.832 0.032 (0.003)*** 0.170 0.033 (0.004)*** 0.191 0.029 (0.005)*** 0.151 0.021 (0.007)*** 0.113 *** *** *** 0.000 (0.000) 0.107 0.000 (0.000) 0.114 0.000 (0.000) 0.086 0.000 (0.000) 0.052 0.568 (0.178)*** 0.063 0.495 (0.113)*** 0.059 0.495 (0.099)*** 0.055 0.572 (0.100)*** 0.063 *** *** ** 0.046 0.426 (0.115) 0.045 0.330 (0.134) 0.033 0.110 (0.128) 0.011 0.470 (0.126) 0.297 (0.126)** 0.007 (0.005) 0.134 (0.223) 0.085 (0.024)***

0.034 0.045 0.028 0.079

0.134 (0.124) 0.006 (0.005) 0.229 (0.168) 0.080 (0.022)***

0.017 0.039 0.050 0.084

0.036 (0.016)**

0.046

16,659 0.673

13,605 0.634

0.258

0.856

0.472 (0.118)*** 0.010 (0.003)*** 0.082 (0.152) 0.099 (0.014)***

0.054 0.061 0.017 0.092

0.668 (0.137)*** 0.002 (0.007) 0.034 (0.146)* 0.079 (0.025)***

0.077 0.013 0.010 0.074

0.127 16,618 0.969 0.000 0.285

0.315 0.074

16,659 0.941 0.000 0.525

Notes: (1) the OLS regressions reported in this table include dummy variables that control for size, year, and industry characteristics. The IV regressions include dummy variables that control for size and year. The coefficients for these dummy variables are not reported here in the interest of space, but are available from the authors upon request. (2) The standard errors are clustered by country and sector. The clustered standard errors are much larger, by up FS SY   to a factor of two. (3) bFS p are the fully standardized coefficients for Xp (bp ¼ rp bp =rY ¼ rp bp ). (4) IV1 denotes the instrumental variables results in which average levels of the Legal variable for other firms (j – i) in a firm’s industry and location category for each country and year are used as instruments. (5) IV2 denotes the instrumental variables results in which dummy variables for English, French, and German legal origin are used as instruments. Socialist legal origin is the omitted category. * Significant at the 10% level. ** Significant at the 5% level. *** Significant at the 1% level.

based on the first stage also show that these instruments are sufficiently correlated to Legal to be valid instruments. Our resulting GMM estimates of the fully standardized coefficients, denoted IV2, are reported in the seventh and eighth columns of Tables 3 and 4 for productivity and profit, respectively. These estimates show that each standard deviation increase in the Legal variable increases firms’ productivity and profit by 0.896 and 0.832 standard deviations—an even greater estimated impact than using the industry and location instruments. For example, the difference in the average values for Legal for Turkey and Spain is 2. As a one unit increase in Legal increases labor productivity by 0.204, or by 20.04% (100  (exp(0.186)  1)), this implies that if Turkey’s legal system were equivalent to Spain’s, their productivity would increase by 40.89%. Finally, one specific endogeneity concern is that “political connections” or bribery may have impacts on both firm productivity and legal system quality. This is controlled for by our IV estimates that accommodate any unobserved or mismeasured variables that may result in a correlation between Legal and the error term. We also addressed this issue more directly, however, by including our “bribery” (Br) variable in the model to recognize that a firm with “political connections” may expect enforcement even with a poor quality legal system. The results of this experiment, presented in the fourth columns of Tables 3 and 4 as OLSBR, show larger and more significant productivity and profit impacts than with OLS, but smaller than with IV estimation. (b) Robustness To check the robustness of our results we also tried using an alternative institutional quality indicator—an Index of Economic Freedom (IEF) from The Heritage Foundation

(which is available annually from 1995; see Kane, Holmes, & O’Grady, 2007). In particular, we used the index most closely related to our Legal variable, their property rights index (with values from 0 to 100 and summary statistics presented in Tables 1 and 2) as a substitute for Legal. 32 GMM estimates of the resulting parameters and fully standardized coefficients for labor productivity and gross profits are presented in Panels A and B of Table 5, respectively, with cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. The results are broadly consistent with those based on our Legal variable. For example, a one standard deviation increase in the property rights index is associated with 0.435 and 0.386 standard deviations higher firm labor productivity and gross profit, respectively, when the industry and location instruments are used, and 0.325 and 0.308 standard deviations higher productivity and profit when the legal origin instruments are used. For example, consider the impact of property rights (PR) on productivity between Hungary and Germany, with average PR values of 70 and 90, respectively. If Hungary had the legal system of Germany, this implies that labor productivity would be 115.195% higher ([100  (exp(0.056)  1)  20] = 115.195) for this 20 unit change in PR. The results obtained by using the legal origin indicators of La Porta et al. (1997, 1998, 1999) as instruments for PR can be interpreted similarly. For example, the average PR values for Tanzania and South Africa are 30 and 50, respectively, so if Tanzania had the legal system of South Africa labor productivity would be expected to increase by 85.79% ([100  (exp(0.042)  1)  20] = 85.79). In addition, we incorporated macro-level variables in our analysis to assess whether simultaneously including such information affected our estimated performance impacts of property rights institutions. In particular, we tried including

656

WORLD DEVELOPMENT Table 5. Parameter estimates using the Economic Freedom Index for property rights Panel A: labor productivity IV1

bFS p

IV2

Panel B: profit bFS p

IV1

bFS p

IV2

bFS p

Property rights (PR) 0.056 (0.018)*** 0.435 0.042 (0.005)*** 0.325 0.053 (0.012)*** 0.386 0.042 (0.006)*** 0.308 Age of the firm (Age) 0.001 (0.005) 0.008 0.006 (0.005) 0.033 0.016 (0.004)*** 0.086 0.019 (0.006)*** 0.099 2 Age squared (Age ) 0.000 (0.000) 0.008 0.000 (0.000) 0.022 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.049 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.057 Exporting dummy (Exp) 0.190 (0.099)* 0.022 0.233 (0.082)*** 0.028 0.387 (0.092)*** 0.043 0.379 (0.103)*** 0.042 Foreign direct investment dummy (FDI) 0.152 (0.181) 0.016 0.204 (0.135) 0.022 0.334 (0.116)*** 0.033 0.330 (0.122)*** 0.032 Import share (Imp) 0.577 (0.188)*** 0.071 0.473 (0.125)*** 0.059 0.546 (0.166)*** 0.063 0.481 (0.111)*** 0.056 Capacity utilization (CU) 0.006 (0.003)* 0.042 0.007 (0.004)* 0.047 0.011 (0.003)*** 0.064 0.009 (0.004)** 0.054 Skilled labor share (SL) 0.181 (0.216) 0.040 0.058 (0.099) 0.013 0.132 (0.177)** 0.027 0.073 (0.154) 0.015 Natural log of 1 + R&D (ln RD) 0.041 (0.015)*** 0.041 0.047 (0.012)*** 0.047 0.079 (0.008)*** 0.073 0.074 (0.017)*** 0.068 Observations R-squared F-statistic of instruments (P-value) Sargan statistic (P-value)

17,040 0.967 0.000 0.509

17,587 0.972 0.000 0.790

16,618 0.979 0.028 0.433

17,053 0.981 0.000 0.516

Notes: (1) the OLS regressions reported in this table include dummy variables that control for size, year, and industry characteristics. The IV regressions include dummy variables that control for size and year. The coefficients for these dummy variables are not reported here in the interest of space, but are available from the authors upon request. (2) The standard errors are clustered by country and sector. The clustered standard errors are much larger, by up FS SY   to a factor of two. (3) bFS p are the fully standardized coefficients for Xp (bp ¼ rp bp =rY ¼ rp bp ). (4) IV1 denotes the instrumental variables results in which average levels of the Legal variable for other firms (j – i) in a firm’s industry and location category for each country and year are used as instruments. (5) IV2 denotes the instrumental variables results in which dummy variables for English, French, and German legal origin are used as instruments. Socialist legal origin is the omitted category. (6) When we rescale the PR variable to make it comparable to the Legal variable, the coefficients illustrated in the first row of this table are 0.090, 0.067, 0.085, and 0.067, respectively. * Significant at the 10% level. ** Significant at the 5% level. *** Significant at the 1% level.

country-level variables such as the natural log of real GDP per capita, openness, and investment share of real GDP as explanatory variables (see Table A3). As these variables and performance would be expected to be positively related, and so might involve reverse causality (for instance, countries with higher productivity levels have a higher per capita GDP), we used year 2000 values of these variables to mitigate this problem. The coefficients on these variables are positive, but the estimate for real GDP is insignificant and this adaptation makes little difference to the overall results. 33 In preliminary investigation we also tried using as explanatory variables a British colony dummy variable, the percent of Protestants and the average years of schooling in the population, which the literature implies might be important. However, these variables would also be expected to be closely related to Legal. That is, past British colonization, the percent of Protestants and legal institutions all reflect a country’s cultural heritage, as shown by the close correlation between the legal origin dummy variable and the Legal variable documented above. In addition, these variables are available for such a limited number of countries that there are too few clusters (countries) to calculate a robust variance-covariance matrix. We thus omitted these variables from the final empirical specification. Finally, we checked the robustness of our results by using value-added labor productivity (LPVA, defined as value added per unit of labor input, VA/L, or in log-form as ln LPVA = ln VA  ln L), and total factor productivity (TFP, defined as ln Y minus the sum of all inputs weighted by their Cobb Douglas production function coefficients) as performance indicators (see Table A4). Although there are fewer observations, due to missing data, the results are consistent with those obtained using labor productivity defined as sales per unit of labor. For instance one unit increase in Legal increases value-added labor productivity by 10.2% but output per unit of labor by 10.4% and total factor productivity by 12%.

6. CONCLUDING REMARKS Using country-level data, macro studies show that institutions matter for economic development. Dunning (2004) also emphasizes the importance of institutions for international business, saying that: “There can be little doubt that institutionrelated assets have become a more important influence over the extent of ownership and patterns of international business activity over the last 30 years. . . Institutional assets need to be in place if the economic objectives of society, and its constituent parts, are to be tackled and advanced in a socially acceptable way.” In this article we used firm level data to explore these influences. Our empirical results shed light on the contribution of institutions to firm performance in various industries and countries, controlling for firm heterogeneity by recognizing firm-specific characteristics and for endogeneity by using an instrumental variables (GMM) estimator. In particular, we evaluate whether higher quality institutions, in the form of property rights enforcement, enhance firms’ and thus ultimately countries’ productive and accounting performance. We find that better property rights institutions matter for firm performance and competitiveness. Specifically, we find a significantly positive association between firms’ performance, in terms of labor productivity or gross profits, and their expectations that the legal system will enforce their contractual and property rights. Our findings are consistent with the hypothesis that high quality institutions create an environment in which firms can organize their activities more efficiently and invest more confidently. One mechanism through which firms may become more efficient is by transferring or creating knowledge. This is supported by our findings that both external and internal sources of technology are also positively related to firm performance. Firms that export, import, have a foreign (FDI) share and invest in research and development (R&D) have significantly higher productivity and profit levels than those that are not involved in these activities, independent of institutional effects.

PROPERTY RIGHTS INSTITUTIONS AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: A CROSS-COUNTRY ANALYSIS

657

NOTES 1. Note that the implication of different legal origins have been challenged by, for example, Lamoreaux and Rosenthal (2005), who argue that during the relevant period of industrial development there was no significant difference between the Anglo-Saxon and French legal traditions in terms of property rights. We appreciate this being pointed out by an anonymous referee.

materials, Other manufacturing, Other services, Paper, Real estate and rental services, Retail and wholesale trade, Telecommunications, Textiles, Transport, Wood and furniture.

2. See Hillman, Rodriguez, Siegel, and Eden (2006) for a discussion and review of the literature.

16. In particular, the sales and the cost variables for Albania, Armenia, Belarus, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Georgia, Hungary, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Moldova, Poland, Romania, Russian Federation, Serbia Montenegro, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Tajikistan, Turkey, Ukraine, Uzbekistan, and Kosovo were reported in thousands of USDs. We thus just multiplied these variables by 1,000. Those variables for Germany, Greece, Ireland, Korea, Portugal, Spain, and Vietnam were in thousands of Euros. We thus multiplied them by 1,000 and converted them to USD by using the corresponding exchange rates. The data for Cambodia, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, and Nicaragua were in USD, so they did not require any changes. The variables for Bangladesh, Oman, Peru, Philippines, South Africa, Sri Lanka, and Zambia were in thousand domestic currency units and those for Benin, Brazil, Chile, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritius, Senegal, Tanzania, Uganda were in domestic currency units. We thus multiplied these variables by 1,000 and 1, respectively, and converted them to USD by using the appropriate exchange rates.

3. See Glaeser et al. (2004) for a useful review of this literature. 4. See Peng, Wang, and Jiang (2008) for a review of relevant studies in the international business literature and in particular the institutional third “leg” of the international business “strategy tripod”—the view that better institutions such as property rights enforcement combine with firm and industry conditions to enhance firms’ performance and competitiveness and thus countries’ aggregate productivity and income levels. 5. We also used value added per unit of labor and total factor productivity as performance indicators as alternative specifications to check robustness to the productivity definition. 6. Managers were asked how much their establishment spent on design or R&D last year, where spending includes wages and salaries of R&D personnel (such as scientists and engineers), materials, education costs and subcontracting costs. We used the natural log of (1 + R&D) to accommodate zeroes and missing observations. This approach has been used in the literature when there are missing observations in order not to lose observations (see, for example, Paul, Johnston, & Frengley, 2000). 7. Industry dummies are used only in the OLS regressions, as the industry is accommodated by our instruments for the GMM estimation. 8. The data are cross sections for each country but were collected for different years during 2000–05. 9. The regions are Africa-Sub-Saharan (AFR), East Asia and Pacific (EAP), Europe and Central Asia (ECA), Latin America and Caribbean (LCR), Middle East and North Africa (MNA), and South Asia (SAR). 10. We do not have information on which firms were surveyed, so we did not wish to double-count firms (or countries) by including two years for some countries. 11. The standardized data was obtained from the World Bank on February 6, 2006. There was a total of 51,169 observations in the data. 12. For an excellent discussion of these data see Lederman (2007).

15. The size dummies for estimation (SZDum) are created using the number of workers.

17. For the manufacturing sector the shares at three-digit industry-level were used, which is consistent with the industry classification in the survey. For the domestically-oriented non-tradable sectors (services and construction) and mining and quarrying, we used the share at the aggregate level, that is, the shares for service, construction and mining and quarrying. We replaced missing value added shares with the industry averages. 18. See Deaton (1997) for further information about this methodology. We use Stata’s pw command to weight the observations, in which the elements that have a smaller probability of selection relative to other elements are weighted more heavily. 19. We alternatively created a dummy variable indicating whether or not firms agree with the statement “I am confident that the judicial system will enforce my contractual and property rights in business disputes,” defined as equal to 1 if Legal = 4, 5 or 6, and equal to 0 if Legal = 1, 2, or 3. For this specification we generated similar results to those found for our final reported specification. 20. One might also try to recognize potential endogeneity of our international linkage variables. However, they are control variables rather than the focus of the analysis, and our cross-sectional data does not permit much consideration of endogeneity. Further, Yasar and Paul (2007) show that measures controlling for endogeneity of these variables for other data are robust to estimation methods accommodating potential endogeneity. We therefore did not pursue this further.

13. The World Bank’s Enterprise Surveys use either simple random sampling or random stratified sampling to ensure randomness of their sample. They also state that they “use both standardized survey instruments and a uniform sampling methodology to minimize measurement error and to yield data that are comparable across the world’s economies.”

22. The 24 industries in the data are identified in footnote 12.

14. The industries, distinguished by dummy variables (IndDUM) for estimation, are: Advertising and marketing, Agro industry, Auto and auto components, Beverages, Chemicals and pharmaceutics, Construction, Electronics, Food, Garments, Hotels and restaurants, IT services, Leather, Metals and machinery, Mining and quarrying, Non-metallic and plastic

23. The location category is based on the survey question: “Where are this establishment and your headquarters located in this country? (Enumerator, Please code as follows: 1 = Capital City; 2 = Other city of over 1 million population; 3 = City of 250,000–1million; 4 = City of 50,000–250,000; 5 = Town or Location with less than 50,000 population).”

21. See Cameron and Trivedi (2005) for more detailed information.

658

WORLD DEVELOPMENT

24. Acemoglu et al. (2001) use the mortality rate of European settlers in colonized countries as an instrument for institutional development during colonization in the post-1500 century. They argue that European colonizers settled in colonies where disease risk was lower, which was reflected in mortality rates. We do not have enough observations for settler mortality rates for the countries in our sample to use this approach.

29. We use Stata’s cluster command to estimate cluster-robust standard errors. See http://www.stata.com/support/faqs/stat/cluster.html. 30. Although this estimate is rather small, the impact is higher based on the IV results that comprise our “preferred model.” 31. We appreciate this suggestion from an anonymous referee.

25. The British legal origin dummy variable is equal to one if the country adopted their law from British common law and zero otherwise. Other legal origin dummy variables are defined similarly. 26. The Br variable is not available for all countries in our sample, so we do not include it in all regressions. To define this variable we use the results of the survey question: “We have heard that establishments are sometimes required to make gifts or informal payments to public officials to “get things done” with regards to customs, taxes, licenses, regulations, services etc. On average, what percent of annual sales value would such expenses cost a typical firm like yours?”

32. For further information see http://www.heritage.org/index/. Note also that in preliminary investigation we included a combination of these indexes to determine their relative significance. As some were too closely correlated to satisfy multicollinearity tests, we used a subset that was sufficiently different to include them in combination. We found the property rights index to be the most significant (at the 1% level), supporting the use of this index as our primary institution quality indicator. We also rescaled this variable to 10–60 to make its units comparable to the Legal variable. As expected with rescaling, the coefficients on the property rights index are similar to the coefficients on our Legal variable.

27. See Long (1997) for an excellent discussion of this issue. 33. Without clustered standard errors, the coefficient on the investment share of real GDP is statistically significant.

28. See Deaton (1997) for an excellent discussion of clustering.

REFERENCES Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 949–995. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401. Aitken, B., & Harrison, A. (1999). Do domestic firms benefit from foreign direct investment? Evidence from Venezuela. American Economic Review, 89, 605–618. Aron, J. (2000). Growth and institutions: A review of the evidence. World Bank Research Observer, 15(1), 99–135. Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 893–921. Bowen, H. P., & Clercq, D. D. (2008). Institutional context and the allocation of entrepreneurial effort. Journal of International Business Studies, 39, 747–767. Buckley, P. J., Clegg, J., & Wang, C. (2002). The impact of inward FDI on the performance of Chinese manufacturing firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(4), 637–655. Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2005). Microeconometrics. Methods and applications. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Castellani, D. (2001). Export behavior and productivity growth: Evidence from Italian manufacturing firms. Mimeo. ISE-Universita` di Urbino. Caves, R. E. (1974). Multinational firms, competition and productivity in host country markets. Economica, 41, 176–193. Coe, D. T., & Helpman, E. (1995). International R&D spillovers. European Economic Review, 39, 859–887. Deaton, A. (1997). The analysis of household surveys: A microeconometric approach to development policy. Baltimore, London: Johns Hopkins University Press. Delios, A., & Henisz, W. J. (2003). Political hazards and the sequence of entry by Japanese firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(3), 227–241. Depken, C., & LaFountain, C. (2006). Fiscal consequences of public corruption: Empirical evidence from state bond ratings. Public Choice, 126(1–2), 75–85. Dixit, A. (2009). Governance institutions and economic activity. American Economic Review, 99(1), 5–24. Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002a). The regulation of entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 137. Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002b). The new comparative economics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 595–619. Doh, J., Rodriguez, P., Uhlenbruck, K., Collins, J., & Eden, L. (2003). Coping with corruption in foreign markets. Academy of Management Executive.

Dunning, J. H. (2004). An evolving paradigm of the economic determinants of international business activity. In J. Cheng, & M. Hitt (Eds.). Managing multinationals in a knowledge economy. Advances in international management (Vol. 15, pp. 327). Oxford: Elsevier. Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (2003). Tropics, germs, and crops: How endowments influence economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(1), 3–39. Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (1996). Trade in ideas: Patenting and productivity in the OECD. Journal of International Economics, 40, 251–278. Feinberg, S. E., & Majumdar, S. K. (2001). Technology spillovers from foreign direct investment in the Indian pharmaceutical industry. Journal of International Business Studies, 32(3), 421–437. Friedman, E., Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Zoido-Lobato´n, P. (2000). Dodging the grabbing hand: The determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 459–493. Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth?. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 271–303. Globerman, S. (1979). Foreign direct investment and spillover efficiency benefits in Canadian manufacturing industries. Canadian Journal of Economics, 12, 42–56. Hall, R., & Jones, C. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83–116. Hejazi, W., & Safarian, A. E. (1999). Trade, foreign direct investment and R&D spillovers. Journal of International Business Studies, 30(3), 491–511. Henisz, W. J. (2004). Political institutions and policy volatility. Economics and Politics, 16(1), 1–27. Henisz, W. J., & Williamson, O. E. (1999). Comparative economic organization within and between countries. Business and Politics, 1(3), 261–277. Hillman, A., Rodriguez, P., Siegel, D., & Eden, L. (2006). Three lenses on the multinational enterprise: Politics, corruption and corporate social responsibility. Journal of International Business Studies, 37(6), 733–746. Jaffe, A. B. (1986). Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: Evidence from firms’ patents, profits, and market value. American Economic Review, 76(5), 984–1001. Kane, T., Holmes, K. R., & O’Grady, M. A. (2007). 2007 index of economic freedom. Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation. Data retrieved from . Keller, W. (2002). Geographic localization of international technology diffusion. American Economic Review, 92, 120–142. Klein, P. G., & Luu, H. (2003). Politics and productivity. Economic Inquiry, 41(3), 433–447.

PROPERTY RIGHTS INSTITUTIONS AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: A CROSS-COUNTRY ANALYSIS Kraay, A. (1999). Exports and economic performance: Evidence from a panel of Chinese enterprises. Revue d’Economie du Developpement, 1–2, 183–207. Kwok, C., & Tadesse, S. (2006). National culture and financial systems. Journal of International Business Studies, 37(2), 227–247. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. Journal of Finance, 52(3), 1131–1150. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15(1), 222–279. Lamoreaux, N. R., & Rosenthal, J. L. (2005). Legal regime and contractual flexibility: A comparison of business’s organizational choices in France and the United States during the era of industrialization. American Law and Economics Review, 7(1), 28–61. Lederman, D. (2007). Product innovation by incumbent firms in developing economies: The roles of research and development expenditures, trade policy, and the investment climate. The World Bank, Development Research Group. Li, H., Xu, L. C., & Zou, H. F. (2000). Corruption, income distribution, and growth. Economics and Politics, 12, 155–182. Liu, X., Siler, P., Wang, C., & Wei, Y. (2000). Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment: Evidence from UK industry level panel data. Journal of International Business Studies, 31(3), 407–425. Loayza, N. V., Oviedo, A. M., & Serven, L. (2005). The impact of regulation on growth and informality: Cross country evidence. World Bank Working Paper 3623. Long, J. S. (1997). Regression models for categorical and limited dependent variables. Advanced Quantitative Techniques in the Social Sciences, Vol. 7. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712. Murphy, K., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1993). Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth?. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 83, 409–414.

659

North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. North, D. C. (1994). Economic performance through time. American Economic Review, 84(3), 359–368. Paul, C. J. M., Johnston, W., & Frengley, G. (2000). Efficiency in New Zealand sheep and cattle farming: The impacts of regulatory reform. Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(2), 325–337. Peng, M. W. (2002). Towards an institution-based view of business strategy. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 19, 251–267. Peng, M. W., Wang, D. Y. L., & Jiang, Y. (2008). An institution-based view of international business strategy: A focus on emerging economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 39, 920–936. Rodrigue, J., & Kasahara, H. (2004). Does the use of imported intermediates increase productivity? Plant-level evidence. In Econometric society North American summer meetings. Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165. Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R. E., & Peng, M. W. (2005). Strategy research in emerging economies: Challenging the conventional wisdom. Journal of Management Studies, 42(1), 1–33. Yasar, M., & Paul, C. J. M. (2007). International linkages and productivity at the plant level: Foreign direct investment, exports, imports and licensing. Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 373–388. Yasar, M., & Paul, C. J. M. (2008). Technology transfer and productivity: Evidence from a matched sample. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 26(1), 105–112.

APPENDIX See Tables A1–A4.

Table A1. Correlation matrix of independent variables considered for the empirical model specification

Legal Age Exp FDI Imp CU SL ln RD ln GDP OP INV PR Br

Legal

Age

Exp

FDI

Imp

CU

SL

ln RD

ln GDP

OP

INV

PR

1 0.026 0.037 0.015 0.076 0.102 0.023 0.010 0.203 0.058 0.192 0.225 0.115

1 0.087 0.006 0.005 0.013 0.091 0.134 0.099 0.015 0.035 0.080 0.052

1 0.248 0.195 0.038 0.039 0.184 0.088 0.004 0.063 0.048 0.014

1 0.224 0.012 0.049 0.096 0.074 0.020 0.060 0.017 0.003

1 0.040 0.033 0.078 0.106 0.087 0.079 0.142 0.029

1 0.063 0.004 0.277 0.043 0.202 0.100 0.123

1 0.014 0.098 0.181 0.056 0.007 0.024

1 0.044 0.049 0.013 0.022 0.011

1 0.091 0.711 0.706 0.231

1 0.021 0.037 0.018

1 0.622 0.173

1 0.143

660

WORLD DEVELOPMENT Table A2. Tests of multicollinearity: variance inflation factors (VIF) and tolerance

Variable

Legal Age Age2 Exp FDI Imp CU SL ln RD

VIF

Tolerance

Panel A Model with firm-level variables 1.040 5.230 4.960 1.200 1.170 1.210 1.140 1.140 1.130

0.958 0.191 0.202 0.833 0.854 0.829 0.878 0.879 0.885

Mean VIF

3.860 Panel B Model specification with both micro- and macro-level variables 1.060 5.280 4.990 1.250 1.180 1.160 1.130 1.180 1.180 2.220 1.370 1.760

Legal Age Age2 Exp FDI Imp CU SL ln RD ln GDP OP INV Mean VIF

0.941 0.189 0.201 0.799 0.848 0.865 0.888 0.850 0.851 0.451 0.731 0.576

2.470

Note: the “rule of thumb” in the econometric literature is that a VIF > 10 or a tolerance level < 0.1 are signs of severe multicollinearity problems.

Table A3. Parameter estimates with macro variables [dependent variable = natural log of labor productivity] Independent variables

Ordinary least squares (OLS) bFS p

OLS Legal system (Legal) Age of the firm (Age) Age squared (Age2) Exporting dummy (Exp) Foreign direct investment dummy (FDI) Import share (Imp) Capacity utilization (CU) Skilled labor share (SL) Natural log of 1 + R&D (ln RD) Natural log of real GDP per capita (ln GDP) Openness (OP) Investment share of real GDP per capita (INV) Observations R-squared F-statistic of instruments (P-value) Sargan statistic (P-value)

***

0.013 (0.003) 0.010 (0.004)*** 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.166 (0.057)*** 0.567 (0.157)*** 0.148 (0.148) 0.010 (0.002)*** 0.451 (0.159)*** 0.076 (0.023)*** 0.903 (0.299)*** 0.017 (0.008)*** 0.039 (0.023)* 17,082 0.616

0.057 0.055 0.036 0.020 0.054 0.017 0.057 0.095 0.078 0.241 0.195 0.090

Instrumental variables (IV) bFS p

IV1 ***

bFS p

IV2 **

0.113 (0.029) 0.007 (0.004)* 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.263 (0.066)*** 0.350 (0.098)*** 0.307 (0.137)** 0.007 (0.003)*** 0.498 (0.137)*** 0.071 (0.021)*** 0.738 (0.296)** 0.019 (0.009)** 0.031 (0.024)

0.488 0.034 0.021 0.032 0.033 0.034 0.041 0.105 0.073 0.197 0.215 0.072

0.182 (0.093) 0.003 (0.004) 0.000 (0.000) 0.328 (0.098)*** 0.195 (0.154) 0.411 (0.155)*** 0.005 (0.003)* 0.529 (0.144)*** 0.068 (0.020)*** 0.629 (0.335)* 0.020 (0.010)** 0.026 (0.032)

17,040 0.923 0.000 0.053

0.315 0.074

17,082 0.878 0.000 0.582

0.786 0.018 0.009 0.040 0.019 0.046 0.031 0.111 0.070 0.168 0.229 0.060

Notes: (1) the OLS regressions reported in this table include dummy variables that control for size, year, and industry characteristics. The IV regressions include dummy variables that control for size and year. The coefficients for these dummy variables are not reported here in the interest of space, but are available from the authors upon request. (2) The standard errors are clustered by country and sector. The clustered standard errors are much larger, by up FS SY   to a factor of two. (3) bFS p are the fully standardized coefficients for Xp (bp ¼ rp bp =rY ¼ rp bp ). (4) IV1 denotes the instrumental variables results in which average levels of the Legal variable for other firms (j – i) in a firm’s industry and location category for each country and year are used as instruments. (5) IV2 denotes the instrumental variables results in which dummy variables for English, French, and German legal origin are used as instruments. Socialist legal origin is the omitted category. (6) When we rescale the PR variable to make it comparable to the Legal variable, the coefficients illustrated in the first row of this table are 0.090, 0.067, 0.085, and 0.067, respectively. * Significant at the 10% level. ** Significant at the 5% level. *** Significant at the 1% level.

PROPERTY RIGHTS INSTITUTIONS AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: A CROSS-COUNTRY ANALYSIS

661

Table A4. Parameter estimates using value added based labor productivity and total factor productivity Panel A: value-added labor productivity

Legal system (Legal) Age of the firm (Age) Age squared (Age2) Exporting dummy (Exp) Foreign direct investment dummy (FDI) Import share (Imp) Capacity utilization (CU) Skilled labor share (SL) Natural log of 1 + R&D (ln RD) ln M ln L ln K Observations R-squared F-statistic of instruments (P-value) Sargan statistic (P-value)

Panel B: TFP

IV1

bFS p

IV2

bFS p

IV1

bFS p

0.102 (0.023)*** 0.019 (0.005)*** 0.000 (0.000)*** 0.362 (0.107)*** 0.176 (0.133) 0.326 (0.135)** 0.009 (0.004)** 0.196 (0.144) 0.075 (0.013)***

0.503 0.109 0.064 0.043 0.019 0.041 0.061 0.044 0.076

0.199 (0.030)*** 0.010 (0.008) 0.000 (0.000) 0.441 (0.100)*** 0.009 (0.121) 0.542 (0.144)*** 0.001 (0.007) 0.179 (0.097)* 0.049 (0.022)**

0.979 0.057 0.017 0.053 0.001 0.068 0.007 0.041 0.050

0.120 (0.029)*** 0.006 (0.009) 0.000 (0.000) 0.289 (0.114)*** 0.064 (0.096) 0.233 (0.182) 0.007 (0.004)* 0.196 (0.042)*** 0.011 (0.016) 0.633 (0.059)*** 0.177 (0.050)*** 0.096 (0.035)***

0.508 0.030 0.007 0.039 0.007 0.027 0.038 0.036 0.013 0.660 0.070 0.095

16,917 0.967 0.000 0.509

16,959 0.972 0.000 0.790

1,946 0.981 0.000 0.291

Notes: (1) the OLS regressions reported in this table include dummy variables that control for size, year, and industry characteristics. The IV regressions include dummy variables that control for size and year. The coefficients for these dummy variables are not reported here in the interest of space, but are available from the authors upon request. (2) The standard errors are clustered by country and sector. The clustered standard errors are much larger, by up FS SY   to a factor of two. (3) bFS p are the fully standardized coefficients for Xp (bp ¼ rp bp =rY ¼ rp bp ). (4) IV1 denotes the instrumental variables results in which average levels of the Legal variable for other firms (j – i) in a firm’s industry and location category for each country and year are used as instruments. (5) IV2 denotes the instrumental variables results in which dummy variables for English, French, and German legal origin are used as instruments. Socialist legal origin is the omitted category. * Significant at the 10% level. ** Significant at the 5% level. *** Significant at the 1% level.

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com