World Oevelopmsm
Vol. i ho. 7July
1
1973
Regional integration of trade among less developed countries* FELIPE PAZOS, IDB, Washington D.C.
INTRODUCTION
In the last twelve years,
several groups
Latin America, the Caribbean into arrangements to integrate or less rapid at different formed economic common
of countries
in
and Africa have entered their economies at a more
pace. Most of the groups stages of industrialization,
include while
countries some are
by nations with relatively homogeneous some groups have adopted a structures; externai tariff and others not; some have relied
mainly on across-the-board tariff reductions and others on product by product negotiations; some have attained a relatively
close
had only moderate themselves. These
degree
of integration
and others
success in increasing different experiences
have
trade among show the
evolution of integration among less developed countries under different settings, circumstances, and economic policies, offering empirical evidence that permits a factual study of the process. In the case of some the empirical evidence makes it important issues, possible to test the alternative hypotheses that have been
in a recent report.’ Four of the groups have been in existence for a long enough time to show already their effects while two were formed in the late sixties and have had time to influence only the last two years for which figures are given in the Table.2 Of the four ‘old’ groups, in the
two had a phenomenal rate of intra-trade eight-year period 1960-68. Intra-trade
Central American Common compound rate of 28.8 per
Market cent per
growth in the
expanded at a year durmg the
eight-year period, having increased more than seven times, from US$ 33 million in 1960 to US% 247 million in 1568. In 1960, exports to other countries of the area represented 7.5 per cent of total exports from Central America and in 1968 they had increased to 26.0 per cent of the total.3 In the Central African Customs and Economic 23.2 US$
Union,
intra-trade
grew at a compound
rate of
per cent per year, from US$ 3 million in 1960 to 16 million in 1968. Exports to other members of
the group amounted to 1.7 per cent i960 and 4.0 per cent in 1968.
of tota! exports
in
debated, and are still debated, in academic circles. This paper examines the experience of the last twelve years with a view to elucidating the following issues: (1) whether or not integration among less developed countries fosters the rapid expansion of trade within the group; (2) whether the expansion, as far as it occurs, reflects a process of ‘trade creation’ or of ‘trade diversion’; (3) what are the effects of integration on the trade of individual member countries; (4) what are the effects of integration on the growth rate of individual member countries; and (5) what are the main obstacles that hinder integration. The four initia! topics are discussed in the first part of the paper under the heading ‘Effects of Integration’ and the fifth, in a second part, under
the heading
Ways
to Overcome
‘Obstac!cs Them’.
to Integration
and Possible
The effects
of integration are studied ma&y on the hasis of’ the groups that have made substantial progress in integrating their economies,
especially the Central American Common lllarket; and the obstacies, on the experience of those groups that have not advanced substantially in that direction, especially
the Latin American EFFECTS
hpansion
of trade
Table 1 shows groups for which
Free Trade
Association.
*This paper has been written in a persona! capacity and the opinions expressed in it are the sole responsibility of the author. 1. UNCTAD. Trade Expantion, Economc Co-operation and Regional integratron Among DevelopGag Countries, Annex 1. Dot. TD/llO, Third Session, Santiago, Chile, February 1972. In addition to the six groups included in Table 1, the document gives figures for the Maghreb permanent Consultation Committee (Algeria, Morocco, Tunisia) and for tbe Reponal Co-operation for Development (Iran, Pakistan, Turkey), that may not be properly considered as integration groups. The document does not give figures for the Arab Common &Market (Egypt, Iraq, Jordan and Syriai. 2. Both LAFTA and CACM were formed in 1960. CACEU was formed in 1964 but had been preceded by the Federation of French Equatorial Africa; and the common market among EAC countries has existed since colonial times. CARIFTA was formed in 1963 and the Andean Group in 1969.
OF INTEGRATION
among
member
intra-trade IINCTAD’s
countries
figures for six integration Secretariat has given data
3. The eight-year period 1960-8 is chosen instead of 1960-70, for which figures are avaiIable, because in mid-1969 a grave frontier conflict between two members induced one of them to withdraw from the Common Market. 1969 and 1970 are not therefore comparable with the preceding eight years.
Regional integration of trade among less developed countries
1. Intra-Trade
Table
. Incegracion
of‘lntegratiorl
Value of exporrs to the area ($ million)
group
1960
1968
1969
1970
564
999
1206
1254
‘;;’
247 (60)
250 (84)
27
52
66
-
3 63
16 116
21 122
142
Larin America LAFTAl. (a) Andean Group2 CACM3 Caribbean CARIFTA4
(109) 286
Groups,
1960-
70
Share of exports to the area in rota1 exports (?&/o) 2960
1968
1969
1970
3.5 (2.5) 7.5
10.7 (2.2) 36.0
11.7 12.9) 25.7
i0.6 (3.3) 26.1
5.0
5.9
7.2
4.0 17.1
4.6 16.8
1.7 4.6
Annual exports
; 1960-68
growth race of to the area (%) 1969
1970
7.4 C5.2) 28.8
20.7 (40.0) 1.2
3.9 (29.8) l-F.4
-
8.6
26.9
-
17.3
23.2 7.9
31.2 5.2
16.4
1
Source. UNCTAD, Trade Expansion, Economic Co-operution and Regional Integration Among Deueloprng Couvtries, Annex 1, DOC. TD/llO, Third Session, Santiago, Chile, February 1972. The document gives rhe following sources: United Nations, Monthly Bulletin of Stutistics, June 1971; IMF-IBRD, Direction of Trade,various issues; United Nations, Yearbook of international Trade Statistics, 1968; El Proceso de lntegracirjn en lo Asociacidn de Libre Comercio dei Caribe (CARIFTA) (C/CN.l2i886) 10 LMarch 1971; Office Statistiquc des Communauc& Europiennes. Commerce Exte’rieur, 1970, Volume II; UAR, Foreign Trade. Cairo, July 1970; and Statistical Service of Barbados. Overseas Twde 1969. Barbados, 1970. Notes. 1. Latin American Free Trade Association: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Coiombia. Ecuador, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, Venezuela. 3_, Andean Group: Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru. 3. Central American Common Market: Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua. 4. Caribbean Free Trade Area: Barbados, Guyana, Jamaica, Trinidad and Tobago, Antigua, British Honduras, Dominica, Grenada, Montserrat. SC. Kitts-Nevis-Anguilla, St. Lucia, St. Vincent. 5. Central African Customs and Economic Union: Cameroon, Central African Republic, Congo, Gabon. 6. East African Community: Kenya, Uganda. United Republic of Tanzania. !a) Exports of Venezuela to Netherlands Antilles and Trinidad and Tobago are exciuded since they consist essentially of crude petroleum co be refined for subsequent re-export. (5) Figures for 1960 are nor directly comparable with those of 1968-70 due to improved reporting procedures.
Intra-trade
in the other two ‘old’ groups
showed
only
a moderate rate of growth that was, however, significantly higher than the rate of growth of total trade. Intra-trade in the Latin American Free Trade Association increased at a rate of 7.4 per cent per year during tie
period,
from
US$ 564 million
million in 1968. Since total of 4.4 per cent per year, the increased from 8.5 per cent lC.i per cent in 1968. In the exports
to member
countries
pee cent per year, from 116 million
in 1960 to USS 999
exports increased at a rate share of intra-group trade of total trade in 1960 to East African Community, increased
at a rate of 7.9
US$ 63 million
in 1960 to US$
in 1968. Total exports
expanded
at a slower
rate and the share of intra-trade increased from 14.6 per cent to 17.1 per cent of total trade. The Caribbean Free Trade Area removed, on 1 May 1968, the custom duties to all trade among its members, except for a reserved list of goods that in the preceding year had a value amounting to 9 per cent of trade in the area. Immediately, trade jumped from US$ 40 million in 1967 to US$ 52 million in 1968, an increase of 22.8 per cent, which compares with an average annual increase of
Cartagena
Agreement
was signed
in May 1969, the first
two measures of trade liberalization were not taken until one year later, in April 1970. From 1960 to 1968 trade among the countries that were to become members of the group increased at an average annual rate of 5.2 per cent; and jumped to 40.0 per cent in 1969 and 29 8 per cent in 1970. The increase in 1970 can be attributed to trade liberalization, but not the increase in 1969 which as said before, is not easy to explain. In the second half of the fifties, when the Latin American Free Trade Association and the Central American Common Market were in process of negatiation, most economists outside Latin America shared Kindleberger’s view that the small amount of commerce among countries of the area indicated the limited possibilities of reallocating production activities in a Latin American union and, hence, the poor prospects for intra-trade expansion.4 Balassa objected that the argument took as given the structure of the economies and added that the existence of excess capacity in various industries of the area gave promise to the race of enlargement of trade. 5 The extraordinary
5.8 per cent in 1960-67. In 1969, intra-trade surpassed its newly-gained high rate of growth, increasing by 26.9 per cent. The Andean Group also experienced a big jump in trade among its members in the year in which the group
4. Cf. C. P. Kindleberger’s restimony before Congress Foreign Economic Policy: Hearings before the Subcommittee Foreign Economic Policy of the Joint Econonn’c Committee the Economic Report (84th Congress, 1st sess.) p. 521.
was formed, but this increase cannot easily be attributed to the formation of the group because, although the
5. Bela Baiassa, The Theory of Economic George Allen and Unwin, 1962).
in on on
integration (London:
W&d
Develon.ment
Vol. 1 No. 7 July 1973
3
expansion of intra-trade in the Central American Gammon Market and in the Central African Customs and r’conomic Union fully supports Balassa’s reasoning.
have reached a much higher stage of development than the countries belonging to the two former groups, the slow expansion of their inn-a-trade is clearly due to the
The lack of rapid expansion of intra-trade American Free Trade Association and
maintenance tions, and
African
Community
does
not
refute
in the Latin in the East the
articles
argument,
which
to trade.
Furthermore
the fact that
among themselves. The extremely quick pace at which trade started to expand in CARIFTA and in the Andean immediately after they were constituted, is Group,
almost free trade existing at the beginning of the period, in the form of authorizations to the two less developed members of the group to protect some specific new industries. Since the countries in these latter two groups
Classified
with
of protective restricof capacity to produce
members of EAC carry almost one-fifth of their total trade within the area proves that they are able to trade
because in neither group has there been a significant degree of trade liberalization. In LAFTA, the agreed program of tariff reductions was only partially applied and in EAC there were departures from the situation of
Table 2. Central American
(or intensification) not to their lack
further
proof
of the capacity
to trade among
Common
Market:
by Tariff Sections,
Trade Among 1960-
of less developed
countries
themselves.
Members,
1968
(in US$ million)
1960
1968
Total increase Annua! iate during period of increase
0. Foodstuffs 1. Beverages and tobacco 2. Crude materials, inedible 3. Fuels and lubricants 4. Lard and edible oils (Sections 0 to 4) 5. Chemical products
Source. lnstituto para la Integracibn de Amkrica Latina. Ei Proceso Amkrica Latina, 1968-71, Buenos Aires, 1972.
Table
3. Central American
Total trade among members Percentage of total trade Rate of increase from previous year
Common Market: Totai Trade Among Members, (in US% million)
1 1962
1961
32.7
36.8
50.8
72.1
I
6.4
7.4
9.2
11.0
1 I
16.7
12.6
38.2
41.8
Latina, El Proceso
Table 2 shows that the buik of the increase in intratrade in the Central American Common Market was formed by manufactured goods. Of the total oxpansion in trade during the period, amounting to US$ 226 million, 74 per cent of the goods traded can be classified as manufactures and only 24 per cent may be considered or mineral
products.
1963
1960
Source. lnstituto para la lntegraci6n de Amirica Buenos Aires. 1972.
as agricultural
de Integracibn
Trade
in manufac-
tured cent, high that from that
en
by Years, 1960-1968
1964
1965
1966
1967
1966
106.1
135.5
174.7
214.0
258.3
13.8
15.2
18.6
20.8
47.3
27.6
29.0
22.4
de Integracih
en Amhica
Latina,
I I
24.7
f ’
I
20.7
IY68-71,
products expanded at an annual rate of 38 per and that in primary products at a rate only half as as that-though also extremely high. Table 3 shows the fast pace of expansion in intra-trade started the very beginning of the process, thus indicating industrial plants had unused capacity available.
Regional
integration
of trade among less developed
countries
Trade creation or trade diversion?
to obtain
Students of international trade theory may ask whether the enormous expansion in commercial inter-
trade within the area comes to substitute lower-cost products from abroad, or if part of it substitutes highercost national production. For example we may ask
change among members of the CACM has been the result of newly ‘created’ trade transactions or of imports ‘diverted’ from more efficient producers. The answer is not easy, for a variety of reasons. Viner’s concepts ‘trade creation’ and ‘trade diversion’6 are difficuit measure and, given their static character, appiicabie to rapidly changing economies.
not entire!y Furthermore
development involves, almost necessarily, the of trade from low-cost producers abroad to less
efficient
infant
at home.’
But without
Table 4. Central American
answers
we may inquire
if all additional
additional imports into Guatemala in El Salvador are displacing imports
of shoes from the
US or Guatemalan production. To the extent that this latter is the case we may further inquire whether Guatemala’s shoe industry is reducing overall output, or only the production of some types of shoes, e.g. highquality women’s shoes, and expanding other types, e.g. medium-price men’s shoes, which are exported to the other Central American countries.
of to
economic diversion
industries
whether produced
precise
trying
Common Market:
Change in Imports from Inside and Outside
the Area, Classified by Economic
Type of Goods, 1958-1968
(in CT!%million)
Imports from Area
i9S8 Non-durable consumer goods Durable consumer goods Fuels and lubricants Raw materials Building materials Capiral goods for agriculture Capital goods for industry Capital goods for :ransport Miscellaneous
9.0 0.7 0.1 7.1 1.2 1.1
z0.z
Toral
1968 114.6 15.0 4.0 99.2 20.0 2.9 5.0 0.1 -------252.0
Imports from Outside Area
Annual rate of change %
1958
29.0 36.0 47.0 29.0 32.0 20.0 13.5 10.9 -8.8 29.0
1968
Annual rate of change %
1958
89.2 66.8 32.1 156.3 31.3 15.1 61.9 9.9 2.2
97.6 86.9 16.3 348.1 38.6 22.9 136.0 45.5 2.2
0.9 2.7 -6.5 5.4 2.1 4.3 8.2 16.5 -
98.2 67.5 32.2 163.4 32.5 19.1 63.0 9.B 2.2
464.7
794.2
5.5
Source. Inoituto para la lncegracidn de America Latina, El Proceso de Integraci6n Buenos Aires, i972.
The answer
seems
to be that
additional
area trade
is
Total Imports
other
countries
of
484.9
212.2 101.9 20.3 447.3 58.6 25.8 141.0 45,6 2.2 1046.2
en A&&a
the
Annual rate of change 1968 % 8.0 4.2 -3.2 10.6 6.1 5.6 8.4 16.5 8.0
Latina, 1968-71,
area.
This
shift
explains
the
partly substituting outside imports and partiy substituting national production. Both types of substitution can be inferred from the figures of Table 4. In 1968 imports of non-durable consumer goods from outside the region
enormous increases, shown in Table 5, in the total volume of trade in shoes and textiles, that cannot be attributed to increases in consumption. Table 6 confirms
were only 7 per cent higher than in 1958, while the Gross Domestic Product of the five Central American countries was 71 per cent higher. Since total consumption of non-durable goods probably increased somewhat less-but not much less-than GDP, a large part of the potential increase of imports from outside the region was substituted with goods produced in the area. But since total imports of non-durable consumer goods, from outside and inside the area, increased by 116 per cent, much more than GDP, it is to be presumed that area
of cross-trade in the same products, presumably of different types. The figures indicate that integration has created competition among the producers of the five countries and has probably promoted industrial speciaiization by types of products, thus permitting larger production scales and lower costs.
trade has also displaced consumption of nationally produced goods. Part of the consumption that was formerly met by national production has come to be met by imports from the region; and part of the production that was consumed nationally is being exported to
the explanation
by showing
that there are large amounts
6. Jacob Viner, The Customs Union Issue (New Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 1950).
York:
7. For a discussion of trade creation and trade diversion in another Latin .4merican integration group, see Carlos F. DihzAlejandro, ‘The Andean Common Market: gestation and outlook’, Center Discussion Paper No. 85, Economic Growth Center, Yale University, New Haven. May 1970.
World Deve!oprnent
Vol. 1 No. 7 July 1973
Table 5. Central American
Common Market: Changes in Imports of Shoes and Textiles from Inside and Outside the Area, 1962-1965 (in US$ thousand)
Shoes Yarn, cloth and clothing
1,069
5,381
70
656
3,931
15,385
58
12,180
Source. Secretaria de1 Tratado de Integration Comercio Exterior, several issues.
Total Imports
imports from Outside Area Annual rate of change 1962 1965
Imports from Area Annual rate of 1962 1965 change
Economica
1962
1965
Annual rate of change
1.725
5.761
49
16,111
28,146
20
-42
380
1.6
12,760
Centroamericana,
Anuario
Estadistico
Centroamericano
de
Table 6. Central American Common Market: Crossed Trade in Shoes and Textiles, 1965 (in US$ thousand) Guatemala Exports Imports Shoes Yam, c!oth and clothing Source. Comet&
Secretaria Exterior,
El Salvador Exports Imports
Honduras Exports Imports
1,511
851
2,181
883
371
1,589
5,739
4,624
8,848
3,386
( 104
3,227
de1 Tratado de lntegracibn several issues.
Econbmica
Centroamericana.,
-4 further indication of ‘trade creation’ is the small rise in average costs of living. Table 7 shows that costs of living in Central America have increased less than in the United States. Prices in the region have not increased in comparison with those in the country with which Centra! America mainly trades, in spite of the higher level of the new Common TarrifB and the increased amount of import substitution from outside the area. This is a most interesting phenomenon that deserves study; but in the absence of such study the maintenance of price stability seems to indicate that increased competition has not permitted producers to take advantage of the higher custom duties.9 Another factor that might possibly explain the maintenance of price
Anuatio
Estadiitico
Centtoamencano
de
stability in the presence of higher tariffs is the policy of tax exemptions as incentives to the establishment of new industries. This policy, justly criticized as excessive, has functioned as a subsidy to new industries that may have contributed to keeping down their prices. But if this is the reason it is not clear why the subsidy has worked. When several small industries have been established, competition would explain the effectiveness of the subsidy; but in the much more frequent case, when only one or two large (in relative terms) industries have been created, the maintenance of prices below the tariff margins is not easy to understand. As stated before, the problem requires study.
Table 7. Central American Common
Market: Annual Increase
in Consumer Prices, 1960- 1968
(in %)
Costa Rica El Salvador Guatemala Honduras Nicaragua United Stares
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1 0
3 -2 0 2 0 1
3 0 2 1 1 2
4 1 0 3 0 1
3 2 0 5 4 1
0 0 -1 4 314 214
2 -1 3 4
3 3
3 1 4 5 4 6
-2 -2 -2 1
Sotrrce. International Monetary Fund. international issues.
8. In a list of 83 tariff sub-items, selected as a representative sample of imports (excluding machinery), the new Common Tariff was found to apply rates of 70 per cent ad valorem or more to 34 sub-items, whereas an average of the old five national tariffs reached, or surpassed, the 70 per cent ieve! in only 15 subitems.
-1 -3 1 3
Financial Statistics,
several
9. In maintaining the thesis that integration in Central America has fostered comperition, I am closeiy following the ideas of Jose! A. Guerra, Senior Economist in the South America Departmat of the lntnnational Bank for Reconstruction and Development. who showed me his reports on the subject. and discussed them at length with me.
Regional integration of trade among less deveiooed countries
6
Trade, payments countn’es
balance and rate of growth of member
per cent
can be observed in Tables 8 to 11, all Central American countries increased their exports to the area at a very fast rate and all came to depend on the area for a large share
area absorbed
of their
exports.
17.1 per cent of Nicaragua’s
Table 8. Central American
Common
and
of Costa Rica’s, 39.8 per cent of Ei
in the area 19.8 per cent of its imports, Costa Rica 22.8 per cent, Nicaragua 24.9 per cent, Honduras 26.3 per
In 1968 the exports,
per cent
Salvador’s Correspondingly, all countries increased very rapidly their imports from the area and came to buy in it a large part of their supplies. In 1968 Guatemala bought
As
market
22.2 of Guatemala’s
of Honduras’s,
34.9 per cent
cent and El Salvador
17.5
30.4 per cent.
Market: Area Trade of Member Countries,
1960-
I968
(in US$ million) T
Guatemala Exp. Imp. Bal. 7.3 10.3
7.6 a.9
-0.3 1.4
2.2 1.1 3.6 6.9 21.2 23.6 28.1
13.4
11.2
20.8
19.7
30.0 38.4 55.1 65.7 77.5
26.4 31.5 33.8 42.1 49.4
El Saivador Exp. Imp. Bal. 12.7 14.4 18.5 28.7 35.2 46.2 57.5 75.2 84.9
13.5 14.6 22.0 27.9 39.2 42.4 52.0 54.5 65.2
-0.8 -0.2 -3.5 0.8 -4.0 3.8 5.5 20.7 i9.7
Source. lnstitwo para la lntegraci6n deAm&ica Buenos Aires, 1972.
Table 9. Central American
Exp.
Honduras Imp. Bal.
7.4 a.2 i3.8 14.0 18.3 22.2 21.5 23.5 31.3
5.3 2.1 6.3 1.9 8.9 “4.9 13.3 0.7 18.0 0.3 25.5 -3.3 34.0 -12.5 40.7 -17.2 48.7 -17.4
Lark,
Common
EI Proceso
ivarket:
Nicaragua Exp. Imp. Bal. 3.4 1.8 3.2 4.2 6.9 9.9 14.9 18.6 26.9
2.8 0.6 2.9 -1.1 5.3 -2.1 7.3 -3.1 14.3 -7.4 21.4 -11.5 31.7 -16.8 42.4-23.8 46.2 -19.3
f
1.9 2.0 1.9 4.4 15.8 18.9 25.8 31.0 37.7
I
3.5 -1.6 A.0 -2.0 3.3 -1.4 3.S 0.6 8.3 7.5 14.7 4.2 23.2 2.6 34.2 -3.2 48.8 -11.1
de Integrachz en Amdtica Latina, 1968-71.
Trade of Mtimbev Countries
with the Rest of the World, 1960-
1968
(in US$ million)
1960 1961 1962 1063 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968
Guatemala Exp. Imp. Bal.
El Salvador Exp. Imp Bal.
Exp.
110 103 105 133 138 149 171 132 145
104 104 117 125 143 143 132 132 128
56 65 67 69 77 105 122 131 148
130 125 125 151 176 198 173 205 200
-20 -22 -20 -18 -38 -38 -2 -73 -55
108 94 103 124 152 15P 168 170 I49
-4 10 14 1 -9 -16 -36 -38 -21
Honduras Bal. Imp 67 66 71 82 92 97 115 124 136
-11 -1 -4 -13 -15 8 7 7 12
Nicaragua Exp. Imp. Bal. 53 59 79 96 111 134 123 127 130
69 71 92 103 123 140 150 160 139
-16 -12 -13 -7 -12 -6 -27 -33 -9
Costa Rica Exp. Imp. Bal. 84 82 91 91 97 93 110 113 133
106 103 110 120 131 163 155 157 165
-22 -21 -19 -29 -34 -70 -45 -44 -32
Source. Tables 8 and 10.
In 1966-8 Guatemala and El Salvador had continuous export balances with the area; Honduras and Nicaragua, persistent import balances, and Costa Rica had a small surplus in 1966 and deficits in 1967 and 1968. Guatemala’s and El Salvador’s trade surpluses with the area permitted them to finance a large part of their
trade deficits with the rest of the world; conversely, Honduras financed most of its area deficit with its surplus with third countries; and both Nicaragua and Costa Rica had deficits with the area and with the rest of the world (except for the small Costa Rican sutFius with the area in 1966).
World Develcpmsnt Vo!. 1 No. 7 Jirly 1973
Table 10. Central American Common Market: Total Trade of Member Countries, 1960-1968 (in US$ million)
1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968
Honduras exp. Imp. Bal.
Nicaragua Exp. Imp. Bal.
Costa Rica Exp. Imp. Bal.
63 73 81 83 95 127 143 154 179
56 61 a2 100 118 144 138 146 157
86 84 93 95 113 112 136 144 171
72 72 80 95 102 122 149 165 185
-9 1 1 -12 -7 5 -6 -11 -6
72 74 97 110 137 161 182 202 185
-16 -13 -15 -10 -19 -17 44 -56 -28
110 107 113 124 139 178 178 191 214
-24 -23 -20 -29 -26 -66 42 -47 -43
Source. International Monetary Fund, Inremational Financial Statisrics, various issues.
Table 11. Central American
Common
Market:
Share of Area Trade in Total Trade of Members, 19GO and 1968 (in %)
, Share of Exports to Area in Total Exports
Guatemala El Salvador Honduras Nicaragua Costa Rica Ares
Share of Imports from Area in Total Imports
1960
1968
1960
1968
6.2 10.8 11.7 6.1 2.2
34.9 39.8 17.5 17.1 22.2
5.5 11.1 7.3 3.9 3.2
19.8 30.4 26.3 24.9 22.8
7.5
26.0
6.3
24.7
Source. Instituto para la lntegracibn de Amkrica Latina, EI Proceso de lntepcibn en Amhica Latina, 1968-71, Buenos Aires, 1972.
The sign and size of intra-trade balances are sometimes considered to be a good measure of the benefits from integration, but they are not. A country may expand its imports from the area more than its exports to it but, thanks to these latter, experience an increase in employment and income and accelerate its rate of growth. The negative element in integration is not the volume of goods imported from the area, but the higher price paid for those goods. The benefits from integration may thus be measured by the increase in national product induced by the expansion in exports to the region,l O minus the higher payments made for area imports as compared imported from third
to their level if the goods had been countries. Following this criterion
all Central American countries have received able net benefits from integration.
consider-
10. This assumes that the country has unemployment and idle capacity, as is generally the case in less developed countries, and that ir cannot readily expand its exports to the world market. The presence of this second condition is not as easy to determine as the fvst one. It may be argued that many less developed counties could expand their exports to the world market by following better policies in relation to exchange rates, taxation and level of protection; but better export policies would seldom bring about as quick results as integration. Furthermore, given the margin of excess capacity existing in most countries, integration does not hinder the promotion of exports to the world market. Far from hindering export promotion, it facilitates it by fostering specialization, economies of scale and lower costs.
Regional integration
Table 12. Celltral American Common ‘Market: Rate (in % increase
1
of Growth of Gross
from previous
year)
j
1966
1963
1
1964
1965
10.0
/
6.2
7.3
1960
1961
1962
2.7 2.4
2.9
El Salvador
3.1 4.2
Honduras
0.5
5.3
7.3
Nicaregua Costa Rica
1.1
6.5
10.6
10.3 9.7
5.5
2.8
10.4
8.1
Area
3.1
3.3
6.6
Guatemala
:1.s
’
1 i 1 ) / j
6.9
9.1
9.1
Source. Inter-American Developmenr Bank, So&-Economic
7.5
Table 13. Central American Common Rate ofExpansion
Domestic Product,
j
7.3
countries
1960-1968
1967
7.1
6.2
Progress in Latin America,
of trade among less developsa
/
5.3
,
I 4.1
1
6.0
6.9
1969
Market: Average Annual
of Exports and GDP, by Countries, 1960-1968 iin %)
Exports
to
Area Guatemala El Salvador Honduras Nicaragua Costa Rica
34 27 20 29 4s
3.6 2.7 12.9 11.8 5.9
Area
29
6.9
Source.
Table an average
Total Exporrs
1
,;:i
(
13.7 8.9 10.1
Gross Domestic Product 5.7 5.8 5.9 6.3 6.9
/
6.0
Tables 8, 9, 10 and 12.
12 shows that the five countries annual
Exports Outside Area
rate of growth
of the area had
of 6.0 per cent during
the period under study. The average rises to 6.9 per cent if we take the period 196248, i.e. eiiminating 1960 and 1961, those years in which integration had not yet time to produce effects and in which also exports to the world market were practically stagnant. The rates of growth of individual Central American countries fell within a relatively narrow range from 5.7 per cent in Guatemala to 6.9 per cent in Costa Rica; and it was not those countries which experienced higher rates of growth that carried an area trade surplus, but rather those which grew more-though not much more-slowly. As may be seen in Table 13, Guatemala and El Salvador expanded their exports to the area at an extremely fast
rate, but their exports to the rest of the world increased very slowly, dampening down the rate of expansion of total trade and restraining somewhat the pace of overall economic growth. It might be argued that the growth of world exports of these countries was hampered by the fast expansion of exports to the area, but this could not have been the case because the products exported were different. It is possible, however, that efforts to promote world exports would have been stronger in these two countries if area markets had not been available. In any case the three deficit countries expanded their world exports relatively quickly (which explains their ability to import from the area more than they exported to it) and experienced a slightly higher rate of economic growth than the two surplus countries.
World Devel~p.wc?nt
9
Vol. 1 No. 7 July 1973
Table 14. Central American
Common Market: Rate of Growth of
Value Added in Manufacturing, (in % increase
1961 Guatemala El Salvador
Costa Rica
1 1962
1 1963
1 1964
5.8 7.7 13.1 7.9 10.6
1.0 8.8 6.0 14.5 10.6
13.5 9.2 2.0 14.5 9.6
12.6 13.1 16.3 12.7 4.4
8.0
7.8
12.3
12.1
Source. Inter-American Development Bank, Socio-Economic
Table 15. Central American Manufactures
12.7 15.2 12.2 12.4 16.1
Source. Inter-American Latin America, 1969.
Tables
14 and
15 show
1968
year)
) 1965
that all countries
13.0 15.1 12.6 12.7 16.8
Development
developed
1 1967
6.8 10.2 8.6 10.2 9.1
8.0
10.7
7.6
6.7
8.9
1969.
1964 11965 13.8 16.4 14.0 14.2 18.0
e
1960-1968
1966
14.6 17.7 13.9 12.8 17.7
14.6 18.8 14.4 14.6 18.3
Bank. Socio-Economic
Progress
in
OBSTACLES TO INTEGRATION AND POSSIBLE WAYS TO OVERCOME
their manufacturing industries very rapidly, which increased their contribution to the gross domestic product. in no country did competition from area
Fears of trade liberalization
imports industry.
appropriate
prevent
the
rapid
expansion
of
domestic
The rapid rate of economic growth of Central American countries in 1960-8 was not brought about by integration alone, but, as Table 16 Jhows, was to a large extent due to the boom experienced by their world exports in the years 1962 to 1965 inclusive, when they increased at rates above 10 per cent per annum. The export boom (experienced also by Guatemala and’ El Salvador) induced a rapid expansion of income in the five countries and softened the resistance of vested interests to integration, thus greatly facilitating the process. Integration, in its turn, helped to accelerate the expansion of income and, when the external boom ceased in 1966, the rapid increase in trade between member countries was able to maintain a high rate of income growth in the area.
AVerage 1960-68
5.1 6.5 8.4 9.6 7.1
Common Market: Share of
15.8 12.5 13.4 17.5
I
6.5 7.0 7.8 6.8 11.4
Progress in Latin America.
’ 13.1
1968
5.8 13.7 11.6 17.3 11.8
1
11961 11962 11963 13.2 15.5 12.7 12.3 16.0
1 1966
6.7 14.0 7.8 5.6 7.3
in the Gross Domestic Product, (in % of GDP)
1960
Guatemaia El Salvador Hon$uras Nicaragua Costa Rica
1960-
over previous
The experience
of Central
circumstances,
America the
THEM
shows that, under
elimination
of restric-
tions on the mutual trade of a group of developing countries brings about considerable expansion in their commercial interchange, fuller use of industrial capacity, specialization of production, economies of scale, increased industrialization and faster economic growth, without any rise in the number of industrial failures or in the amount of unemployment on account of the competition forthcoming from other member countries. But governments of developing nations are not generally confident that the positive results of across-the-board tariff elimination will be as large, nor that the negative effects will be so small; they are therefore reluctant to risk their protected industries or to renounce the possibility of creating new ones under protection. The short-term benefits of national protection are present
10
Regional
and certain,
whereas
those
of opening
new markets
in
neighbor countries are in the future and uncertain. In order to forego the short-term benefits of national protection, effects
countries
must have great faith in the future
of integration,
a firm conviction
or a strong
that
political
they cannot
own borders. Large developing countries motivated towards integration
motivation,
develop
within
or their
are not, as a rule, strongly because they believe that
their national markets are large enough to support industrial development; and small countries, generally less developed than the large, have strong motivations but are afraid to integrate with their bigger and more developed neighbors. Countries with high tariff wails fear
to expose
their
plants
to the
competition
of !ess
protected protective
industries; and those with low duties consider tariffs to be a status symbol of political and
economic resistance neighbors,
independence. For a variety of reasons, the made liberalization, even within a group of is srrong and widespread.
Deficiencies
in joint
If integration
industrial
is defined
establishment
of a
rational division of !abor among a group of countries, can be theoretically attained by the coordination economic
plans,
thus
failures and increases elimination of tariffs
avoiding
the
of trade among less developed countries
among member countries and to eliminate trade resrrictions to articles originating in the country to’which production is assigned, while maintaining restrictions to those produced in other member countries and in the rest of the world. The monopolistic advantages granted by the agreements are, however, only temporary because trade restrictions within the group have to be eliminated not later than 1980, except for some tariffs to protect Bolivian and Ecuadorian industries that will be maintained until 1985. In August 1972 the Andean Group countries approved the sectoral program on metal-working industries, which is the first one subscribed. The program assigns 7 types of products compressors, pneumatic tools, drills); (e.g.,
airplanes,
harvesters, surgical
risk
in unemployment may bring about.
of
it of
industrial
that the general The theoretica
to Bolivia (e.g., 23 to Colombia
mills, centrifugal pumps, small instruments, toys); 22 to Chile (some
common
to
different, equipment,
like electric fixed-focus
those
assigned
to
Colombia
and
some
generators and motors, railway photographic cameras!; 11 to
Ecuador (machinery for the ment and control instruments,
planning
as the
integration
dairy industry, measureclocks and watches); and
25 to Peru (most of them common to those assigned to some other country and some exclusive to Peru, like packing
machinery
and
machinery
for
the
ceramics
industry). As said before, such assignments involve the commitment by other member countries to immediately grant
free
entry
to
the
products
originating
in the
plan-
assigned countries, while maintaining restrictions for those produced in other member countries and in the
ning, with tariffs reduced only for planned industries, has permitted governments to reconcile their desire for integration with their reluctance to liberalize trade. But,
rest of the world. Also, as said before, the advantage given to the assigned countries is only temporary. In the case of existing industries, the monopolistic position will
unfortunately, joint progressed far beyond
cover a period of 8 years (13 years for Bolivia and Ecuador) because tariffs within the group will have to be eliminated not later than 3 1 December lP80 (31 December 1985 for products assigned to Bolivia and Ecuador) and, in the case of non-existent industries, the advantage will be substantially shorter, since the installa-
possibility
recent
of pursuing
report,
opinion regional
the
integration
through
industrial the intention
UNCTAD
that little significant planning, attributing
joint
planning has not of applying it. In a
Secretariat
expresses
the
progress has been made its lack of success to
in
’ . . the great difficulty that even a single country experiences in deciding on a long-term industrial plan involving both political and technical judgements on the feasibility and desirability of any given schedule of priorities and locations for regional industries. The dovetailing of national industrial plans, which are themselves the product of complex internal compromises at the national level, into a coherent regional plan has so far eluded the planning bodies of the regional groupings. composed as they are of representatives of sovereign States, each with a veto right concerning decisions affecting its own industrial development. Moreover, the absence in most regions of sufficient entrepreneurial and financial resources to ensure the implementation of a hypothetical regional industrial plan reduces the incentive for striking a comp:omise, since countries are understandably unwilling to forego the option of establishing given industries for which external financial and technical resources might become available in exchange for the right to establish other industries for which no such support is assured.‘11 The Andean integration liberalization manufactures, programs chemicals, electronics,
Group
agreement
countries partly
are carrying through
ahead their
automatic
steel, aluminum, automobiles and trucks, etc. The joint sectoral industrial programs to distribute
the location
the assigned
article
within
two
years
(three
for Bolivia
and Ecuador) or do not inscaI1 the plant within an additional period of 3 years, the advantage is lost a,>:! the product automatically becomes a free-trade item within the group. Since the Andean fledged
development
sectoral plans
programs but
only
are not agreements
fullyto
distribute the location of future industries, the reasons given earlier to explain the difficulties in negotiating and implementing joint investment plans may not be fully applicable to them. Furthermore, the successful negotiation of the program on metal-working industries seems to show the feasibility of these agreements. But the task
trade
in a large number of items, mainly light and partly through joint sectoral on basic industries-metal-working, petro-
are agreements
tion of a manufacturing plant takes a number of year When countries do not notify their decision to produce
of production
11. UNCTAD, op. cit., p. 29. In a footnote to the paragraph quoted, the document cites Brewster, ‘Industrial integration systems’ (TD/B/345) and ‘Trade expansion and economic integration among developing countries’ (TDIB185IRev.l). United Nations publications, Sales No. 67.11.D.20, chap. V.
11
World Development Vol. 1 No. 7 July 1973
ahead will be very far from easy and the programs in other ‘sectors will probably face more obstacles than those in the first one. The difficulties of distributing future industries among countries will be greater the greater the number of industries already operating in the region-which in the metal-working sector are few-and the greater the savings in costs that can be obtained by integrating production in large industrial complexeswhich in many metal-working industries do not seem to be large. Future sectoral programs will, therefore, present difficult problems that may induce the Andean countries to try new formulas. To this effect the experience acquired in the preparation and negotiation of the agreements on metal-working industries, successfully completed, and on the petrochemical sector, still under discussion, will prove invaluable. In theory, integration can be attained through negotiated tariff reductions, but in practice trade liberalization has to be applied across the board. This does not mean, however, that the schedules of tariff removals should be the same for all’member countries; nor that a program of trade liberalization should be launched without the necessary preparations; nor that the promotion of new large industries in an integrated group of countries should be left to the free play of the market, any more than it should in individlual countries. in developing countries, new large industries are seldom established without the concession of official facilitiei and the assistance of government financial institutions, that usually anaIyze their costs and their benefits to the country’s economy. In integration groups, both national and regional financial institutions must examine the role &At new large industries will play in the region’s economy, check that they do not come to duplicate capacity and encourage their location in the relatively less advanced countries. Differences
in the !eve! of development
When there are considerabie differences in the level of development as between members of an integration group, a program of uniform trade liberalization would give undue advantage to more developed countries, whose manufactures might invade the marker of the less advanced members and stifle their industrial growth. This may not occur, owing to differences in wages and other costs not inversely related to plant size, but less advanced members believe firmly that it will, and are therefore reluctant to join programs of automatic trade liberalization, and are prone to withdraw once they have joined them As shown above, the Cennal American Common Market accelerated the industrial growth of Honduras, but this may not be a good example because differences in levels of development in the CACM are much narrower than in other groups. But even if industrial growth in Honduras was not adversely affected by the Common Market, she had the subjective feeling of not receiving a fair share of the benefits; and this sentiment probably strengthened her decision to withdraw, a decision that was provoked mainly by the border conflict with El Salvador. Liberalization programs
should therefore comprise schedules for delayed tariff reductions for less advanced members. In this respect, the Agreements establishing the Andean Group and the Caribbean Free Trade Area have set excellent examples. Differences
in level and structure of protection
Another two important obstacles that must be overcome, or neutralized, before the removal or significant reduction of intra-trade restrictions, are: (a) differences in the level and structure of protection; and (b) differences in the rate of inflation. Both types of differences are extremely pronounced among LAFTA countries. According to Balassa, l2 the ad valorem average rates of nominal protection in Brazil, Chile and Mexico, in the years stated, were as follows: Brazil
Mexico
Chile
(1966)
(1961)
(1960)
Primary products
59
28
6
Intermediate products Non-durable consumer goods
92
53
22
140
204
/
25
Consumer durables Machinery
108 87
@ 92
I !
42;
Given these large tariff differences, their removal among partners without their unification vis-24s the rest of the world would give an enormous competitive advantage to countries with lower external tariffs. Free trade associations are functionally possible among countries with low rates of protection, but not among highly protected countries, where differences in tariffs tis-24s third countries are generally very large and create great divergences in cost and price structures as between member countries. External customs duties must be unified before intra-trade tariffs can be lowered. The LAFTA countries did not even think in unifying tariffs, because unification would have external involved-would still involve-gigantic changes in the foreign trade system and in the structure of prices and costs of each member country. But the maintenance of the different external tariffs prohibited any significant reductions in restrictions on intra-trade among members from being made. The practical conclusion seems to be thar the LAFTA countries should work gradually, but steadily, toward bringing their tariffs down to a lower uniform ievel; this should ideally be that of the lowest effective tariff (i.e., the lowest tariff not supplemented by other types of import restrictions). Since the large LAFTA countries are now embarked in a policy of promoting the export of manufactures, and since such
12. Bela Balassa and associates, The Structure of Protection in Developing Counrries (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1971). For rate of protection in former years, see Santiago Macario, ‘Proteccionismo e Industrializaci6n en Amkrica Latina’, in Hncia ltnn Twifa Edema Con&n en Amkricn Lntina (Buenos Aires: INTAL. 1969).
Regional integration
IL
policy
makes
it
necessary
(and
possible)
to
reduce
protection, this same process could be used to narrow the differences in customs duties to third countries, thus preparing LAFTA
the
ground
for
their
elimination
in intra-
of trade among less devekocrd countries
bors. As in the case of gradual tariff reductions to third countries, measures to facilitate integration coincide entirely with measures to promote exports to the world market.
trade. Concluding remarks
Differences
in yate of inflation
In the last three years price countries were as follows: l 3
in
LAFTA
1970
1971
6 3 22 29 11 6
21 4
39 5 20 22 14 7
Colombia Ecuador IMexico
18 35 4 8 8 0
3 3 6
Paraguay .Peru
3 6 8
5 21 3
15 2
Uruguay Venezuela
36 3
With such differences in the rate of inflation the total eiimination of trade restrictions among these countries would bring utter chaos, unless their rates of exchange were varied simultaneously in the amounts necessary to neutralize
price
rises.
Such
neutralization
would
have
been unthinkable a few years ago, but is now perfectly within the realm of possibility. The experience of Chile from 1965 to 19701 of Colombia since 1967, and of Brazil
since
1968,
show
that
a ‘crawling
peg’
is a
perfectly feasible exchange system-by far the best for a country with chronic inflation. If all members of integration groups adopted flexibility, differences obstacle years.
to trade because
policies of complete in inflation would
liberalization.
not
all countries
are yet fully convinced exchange-rate adjustments,
Our study of recent integration arrangements among developing countries shows that some groups have overcome
1969 Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile
!
changes
exchange-rate cease to be an
This
may
with
chronic
take
a few
inflation
of the virtues of continuous but the delay will probably
the fears and obstacles
tion and commerce
have among
development Integration
of competition among member countries. not only facilitated import substitution from
third countries, but fostered and industrial efficiency.
mutual interests,
trade.
In addition
trade
obstacle schedules countries
is being met by the of trade liberalization, lowering
their
specialization have not been restrictions to
resistance
is
being
differences in levels of development, and rates of inflation among member
of vested
hindered
by
levels of protection countries. The first
application of different wirh the more advanced
barriers
at a faster
rate.
The
second is not being met by one of the groups, on account of the great disruptions that would be provoked by a rapid equalization of tariffs, but couid and should be attacked by a coordinated gradual reduction of the rate of protection; and the third would be neutralized if all member countries adopted a flexible-exchange-rate policy. Groups that are progressing towards integration are piacing themselves in a better position to trade with the rest of the world; and those making less progress would quicken their pace towards integration by following policies that would also serve to promote their worldwide exports. integration policies and world trade policies do not seem to be in conflict, but rather to
Stutistics, 25, 8 (August 1972).
their neigh-
to the
liberalization
than to facilitate
with
competition,
We have also seen that some groups entirely successful in eliminating the
reinforce
integration
trade liberaliza-
restrictions to mutual groups have experienced
a rapid expansion in their trade and a substantial acceleration in their rates of growth. Trade expanded at a much faster rate than overall consumption, thus indicating the
not be long. In any case, countries with chronic inflation need to adopt a flexible-exchange-rate policy in order to promote exports to the reSt of the world, even more economic
that hinder
eliminated them. These
each other.
13. International
Monetary
Fund,
International
Financial