Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 29 ( 1988) 173-204 North- Holland
ESS PROPERT
R
and National Bureau of Economic Research
In a recent paper ( ccallum, 1987) I described, and began to explore the properties of, a specific rule for the conduct of monetary policy- This rule, which reflects ideas expressed in earlier writings by Allan (1984) and myself (1984), prescribes settings for the monetary base that are intended to keep nominal aggregate demand growing smoothly at a noninflationary rate.
The policy strategy represented by this rule is one
that is not open to objections frequently expressed by opponents of monetary rules, as it is fully operational and is designed to be insensitive to regulatory
changes
and
technological
innovations
in
the
payments
and
financial industries. The investigation begun in my previous paper is intended eventually to indicate whether above.
in fact the rule has the robustness properties claimed
In McCallum (1987) it was suggested that the rule would, if it had
been in effect, have kept nominal GNP for the United States close to a smooth target growth path over the period 1954-1985 despite the regulatory and financial turmoil that occurred during the latter part of thaL ;rpriod. But evidence for that suggestion was based upon one extremely simple model of nominal GNP determination and the associated set of implied random-shot estinates. To establish robustness -- which
is important since no SatiS-
factory structural model of the economy is in existence or on t MB it
ould also have perfor
needs to be determined Ghelher the rule
ell during 1954-85 actor
*The Henderson, pdrticipants
author
is
Finn
Mydland,
Robert
helpful
criticism.
for
0 167 - 2231/88/$3.50
indebted
ss
to
Cagan,
Phillip
Lucas,
@ 1988 Elsevier Sciewp
John
Robert
laylot=,
Publishers
and
B.V.
Flood, other
Benjamin
Carnegie
(North-Holland
Friedman,
Rochester
Dale
Confereme
expressing
different
views concerning
The
macroeconomic relationships.
purpose of the present paper is to provide evidence of precisely that type. To that end, the paper begins in Section II with a review of princiThen in Section III
ples and previous work.
evidence concerning the rule's
performance is reported for a variety of vector-autoregression (WAR) models -- VARs with different sets of included variables. In Section IV, attention is shifted to models that represent the profession's attempts to develop structural representations of the economy's workings. In particular, models are specified that represent three competing points of view regarding the the real business cycle view, the
nature of macroeconomic fluctuations: Lucas-Garro
monetary
misperceptions
view,
and
a
more
Keynesian
Estimates of
involving Phillips-type wage adjustments and markup pricing. such
models
are
reported
and
used
indicate, as with the VAR models, effective over
1954-85,
as
the
basis
for
view
simulations
that
hether the policy rule would have been
Section V contains results of three additional
investigations, ones designed to shed light on issues relating to (i) the Lucas critique, (ii) initiation of the rule under unfavorable conditions, and (iii) an alternative rule proposed by Meitzer (1984).
Conclusions are
briefly summarized in Section VI.
D PREVIOUSRESULTS Let
us
begin
the
discussion
with
a
brief
review
of
strategic
principles concerning the specification of a monetary policy rule.' most
fundamental
of
the
four
principles
stressed
in
involves the current state of macroeconomic knowledge.
McCallum
The
(1987)
In this regard the
crucial point is that neither theory nor evidence points convincingly
to
any one of the many competing models of the dynamic interaction between nominal and reaP variables.
1
It
wi 1 I
he
presumed
monetary
pol ir
: according
average)
than
bo7uld obtain
no
less
Prescott
that to
As is illustrated by several recent survey
there
some rule, with
no
need
to
namely,
is
that
it
“discretionary”
period-by-period
emplOyWnt (1977)
review tc.r.ls
the to
rationale
result
in
conducting
inflation
decision-making
OrO~JtpUt. This tendency was recognized in the analysis whose wopk ‘“3s usefully extended by &r-r0 and Cordon (1983).
174
for less
-of
and
Kydland
(On with and
2 articles,
the
macroeconomics
profession
has
not
produced
a
reliable
quantitiative (or even qualitative) model of Phillips-curve or aggregatesupply behavior.
In other words, there
predictions concerning the way nominal GNP
ill be
divided
in
is very
little basis
for
any
hich quarterly or annual changes
between
real output growth
and
in
inflation.
Consequently, a policy rule's design should not be predicated
upon any
particular model of that division.3 At
the
same time, however, theory and evidence
validity of
the natural
rate
hypothesis,
Le.,
both
to
the
point
to
the
absence
of
any
permanent tradeoff relating inflation (or money growth) and output levels or growth rates.4 Over long spans of time, in other words, output and employment levels will be essentially independent of the averdqe rate of growth of nominal variables.5 The
combination
of
ignorance
and
knowledge
expressed
in
the
t
preceding paragraphs leads rather naturally to the first ingredient of my proposed policy rule, which is a target path for nominal GNP6 that grows steadily at a prespecified rate that equals the economy's prevailing longterm average rate of real output growth. For the United States, upon which the present discussion will focus, the figure is about 3X per year.
Since
that azgnitude will, according to the natural rate hypothesis, be virtually independent of vinetary policy over any extended period of (say) 20 years or more, keeping nominal GNP growth at the indicated 3% rate should yield approxirrrately zero inflation over such a period. Furthermore, there is some
2
These
include
3 his
feature
concerning
that
by Phillips
the
4The
present exists
(1957),
Dotsey
approach of
sets
it
monetary
a rich
literature
Bronfenbrenner
( 987),
and King
(1961),
apart
and McCallum
fron
much of It
policy
rules.
on that
subject
Fiscrlsr
the
previous
should
which
and Cooper
(1988).
be
includes
(1973),
ana 1ys
is
mentioned,
notable
Friedzqn
items (1975).
and many others.
hypothesis or
(1988),
properties
there
(1954)
(1981),
cons tant
of
stabilizing
nevertheless,
Tay or
Blanchard
does
not
of
past
independent
claim,
it
might
be
noted,
that
t-ate
,3turai
the
is
itself
conditions.
c
‘ik effects bel ieve than
inflation
to
be quite
by affecting 6
Some
i ncome, of
rl;.Sl if ier of
the
or
other final
present
‘Fesjeniiai cn
the
smal I, the
paper
alter
average
measure sales
-v iewe
ly9’ size
inserted the
output
level
of
is of
of
nominal
might that
allow
for
discrepancy
aggregate
activity
as a matter
175
of
possibility
--
actual such
(1935)
adliiinistrative
has
of
which
effects,
by changing between
as Go Ion
be ignored.
the
These
stock.
and employment the
be preferable, Iscue
to
capital
natural-rate
T&in
nominal
suggested. det3i
I that
analysts
values
and natural-rate ab
(1!%5i
most
GDP,
rather values. personal
The discussIon can
Initial\y
reason to believe that the prevention of fluctuations in nominal GNP growth would help to prevent swings in output away from its natural-rate path.7
In this case, steady growth of nominal GNP at 3% per year would help to reduce cyclical fluctuations in output as well as to prevent inflation. Our specification of a smooth, noninflationary target path for nominal GNP is of course related to policy proposals for "nominal GNP targeting" that have been put forth in recent years by Gordon Taylor
(1985), Tobin
(1985), Hall
(1983),
The present proposal
(1983), and others.
differs
significantly from these earlier suggestions, however, in its emphasis on an operational -mechanism for achieving the specified targets--i.e., keeping nominal GNP ciiose to the 3% target path.
for
Thus the present proposal
conforms to the third of the strategic principles referred to above, which is that a policy rule should specify settings of an instrument variable The
that the monetary authority can control directly and/or accurately. rationale for this principle is entirely straightforward:
to specify the
behavior of some magnitude
(such as PO1 or M2, for example) that controllable is to leave the rule seriously incomplete.8
is not
A fourth principle is that the rule should not 1d.y upon the absence of regulatory change and technical innovation in the payments and financial industries. turmoil
While these processes are perhaps unlikely to produce as much
in the
future
as
they
have
in the recent
past,'
it would
be
unreasonable and unnecessary to presume that they will not be present again to a significant extent, In light of the last two principles, it is rather natural to adopt as an operating instrument the monetary base, which is a variable that can be accurately
‘In the
particular,
1954-85
greater
8The
9
to
One
lead escape
on
a day-to-day basis 3y the central bank of any
quarterly
(seasonally
than
different
that
set
rates data
cf
real
for
thL
and nominal U.S.,
GNP are
the
hiahly
correlated.
In
correlation
is
contemporaneous
0.80.
use
of
Ml
type
of
strategy.
reason to
growth
adjusted)
for
inflation,
Lcr+nin
or
MZ 2s
this
conjecture
which
regulaf’ons.
an
raises lhis
“indicator”
is
that
nominal point
variable,
the
processes
i-terest has
been
among others.
176
rather
rates stressed
than
are and
in
a
part
thereby by
target,
Brunner
induct?
enhances
represents
b‘; the
and Meftzer
Y?: ;cieS +rbcentive (1983),
a
nation.lo l1
Thus in my 1984 paper it was suggested that a desirable rule
ould adjust the base growth rate each month or quarter, increasing the rate if nominal GNP is below its target path, and vice versa" (1984, p. 390). After
an unfrrtunate delay,
begun recently. eltzer
led
investigation of
that suggestion was
A brt of experimentation and some discussions with Allan a slightly modified version of the rule, 12 which was
to
proposed in concrete quantitative form in McCallum (1987). of the monetary base, xt'
of
bt = log
xt = target-path value
Then the proposed rule for quarterly base growth rates can be
as:
written
O-00739 - (1/16)[xt l-xt 17-bt l+bt_L7] + ~(x; I-~t ,),
=
abt
xt = log of nominal GNP, and
Let
(1)
with x non-neg.itive, In expression (1) the constant term 0.00739 is simply a 3% annual growth rate expressed in quarterly logarithmic units, whrle the second term subtracts from this the average growth rate of base velocity
‘°Controllabilit7 advocated the
Fed
banks’
can
figure
taken
the
base
“There to to
of
interest
not
rate
indicate
that
the
direction
extremely
unclear
specify
settings
12
The
alqebraical
experimentation form would ru;2
in be
interest
(1).
unsatisfactory
oroposed
by Meltzer
rate
suggestion a!
,
+
that
that It and
this
should that
(1984)
be the
and
are
rate, the
rule
than
form
more
noted
that
first
two
if
a
can
the
be
level
of
interest
increased
rate,
nominal
feasible objection
seems to be
below
(for
rates,
would
take
if
the
which
Consequently,
discussions.
as
principle
is
W’
reported interest
below)
in
An important
to
those
available
lar
it
it
is is
were
to
an aggr;Ldte.
i3
pap”r
with is
action
thus
be sini
below.
(1)
and
Then
keep
and
connection
to
that
outstanding
sheet.
Fed can
would
to
long
is
a month.
some other
policy
1984
my
I-~t_l),
(1987).
in
the
controllable
by
who has
open-market
(e.g.1
analogous
(anafwous
rather
of
described
be enhanced
pre sumed
own balance
aggregate or
one
(19691,
rely own argument on currency
its
manner,
quantitative
would
in
A(x;
this
Regressions
GNP growth a simple
=
funds
that
on
periods that
Meltzer
a corrective
some reserve from
base.
form
an
Abt
is
the
usually
indicated
equation
rule
effect
what of
as
federal
for
qualitative ly
the
nominal of
variables
different
instrument than
in over
by
instrument.
frequently,
items
value,
path
of
an
more
are
operating
otner
as
even
which
desired
adoption
Use of
a very
complex
the
The
or
of
discussed
base
rule-prescribed
course,
base.
require
much more base)
of
the
daily, both
the
to
briefly
use
By continually close
are, the
would an
day.
was
that
Fed,
from
instruments.
use
but
the
differs
extremely
potential
base
observations
with
next
the
procedures
collect
deposits
day’s the
of
operating
s;mbols susceptible
Lindsey term-,
tn
in
might
,-luation
to dynamic
(1986) (1)
thd i
one as
conjectured
correspond
to
be
(1) ;-+taL;lity that the
expressed Brief
below. than the
1984
infldtioc-tdrget
the form
Finally, the third term adds a feedback
over the previous four years. l3
adjustment in response to departures of GNP from the target path. The value of
should be large enough to provide adequate responsiveness of base
x
growth to target misses but small enough to avoid dynamic instability of the type that can obtain when feedback responses are too strong. In my 1987 a
paper,
value
of
0.25
was
tentatively
suggested
as
an
appropriate
compromise. To determine whether equation (1) -- with
A set at 0.25 or some other
chosen value -- would perform well, one needs to experiment with a quantitative model, one
that
is subjected to random
shocks of the magnitude
experienced in actuality. The difficulty in this regard is, of course, that there is no agreement as to the appropriate model. expressed in ell
ith a
cCallum (1987), is that rule (1) with
But my conjecture,
A = 0.25 would perform
ide variety of quantitative models pertaining to developed
market economies. It is important to be clear, in this regard, about what IS
meant
here
by
the
term
"perform well."
In particular,
it must
be
emphasized that, according to the principles expressed above, the criterion should involve only the time path of nominal GNP.
Since we do not know how
changes in GNP will be divided between inflation and output growth, the rule's performance should not be evaluated on predictions in that regard.
the basis of any model's
conjecture, then, was that simulations with
rule (I) used in place of actual historical policy would, in a variety of models, result in nominal GNP paths that are smoother than those actually experienced and
also
nominal demand.
Confidence in the rule would be enhanced if this type of
et-e
noninflationary
in terms of the average growth of
obtained with models that are constructed along both Keynesian
and classical lines. The preliminary results reported in my previous paper were based on o
"model" that is simply an atheoretic regression relating
versions of a and ith
13 resulting enough
As
the from
to avoid
purpose
past
values of
seasonally
of
this
term
regulatory
and
dependence
on ryciical
itself.
adjusted
is
tc
technological
take
The
quarterly
-1vmjnt -_ sources,
conditions
178
of
first of these equations, United States
possible
the period of (which are reflected
changes
in
data
weloc i ty
for
growth
averaging should be in the third term).
long
1954.1-1985.4, is as follows:14
AXt
= 0.00740+ 0.262bxt 1 + 0.488dbt + e2t (.0020) (.079) (-120)
R2= 0.23
(2)
SE = 0.010
Here
denotes the estimated disturbance or shock realization for e2t quarter t. Using this equation and policy rule (13, simulated values for bt and
xt
were calculated for 128 periods beginning with initial conditions
pertaining to 1954.1 and with e2t values fed in each period as estinates of shocks that hit the economy during
1954-85.The result of this simulation
exercise (with a = 0.25) is shown in Figure path and LX the simulated values for
1, where TAR denotes the target
xt. Evidently, the rule induces xi. t.3
follow the target path rather closely, according to model (2). While plots such as Figure
1 are quite informative, they are much less
compact than some summary statistic reflecting the overage "closeness" of Xt to x;.
In what follows, consequently, the discussion will emphasize the
root-mean-square control error. This statistic, denoted RMSE, is the square root of the mean (over the 128 simulation periods) of (xt-xi)2. value for the path shown in Figure
The RMSE
1 is 0.0197, a value that is about 2.0%
in percentage terms. Beforz turning to analogous values based on other models, it will be useful to nut the 0.0197 RMSE value in perspective. One hay of doing that is to compare it with the RMSE va?ue actually experienced--i.e., the value obtained with actual historical &bt valzes for 1954-85 used instead of rule (I). For that case the RMSE Ils 0.771, over 30 times as large as with rule (1) and x = 0.25. Another relevant basis for comparison, since a large part of the foregoing actual value reflects inflation, is the extent nominal GNP variability about its (inflationary) trend path.
of
actual
Consequently,
relative to a fitted trend line has also been 15 is over Cour calculated. The resulting number, about 0.0854 (or 8.5%), the RMSE value for
xt
times as large as the value obtained with policy rule (I), suggesting that
’ 4Here, while
SE
and
denotes
Durbin-Watson becaur;c
“ln
of
II,
what
the
estimated
statistic. datd
the
follows, The
t ig!rres
standard figures
in
in parentheses
jevIti*ion (2)
differ
of
the
s!iqhtly
are
est imated
disturbance frm
those
revision.
McCallum
(1987)
the
figure
was Incorrectly
179
reported
as 0.0616.
standard
term in
and
errors,
DW is
McCallum
the
(1987)
I
2
A=
aI
180
0.25
the rule
ould
have provided
actually occurred, 16 The
smaller fl
ell as zero inflation.
second version of model
includes
Abt_l
Lions 7
rather than
in nominal
(2) considered previously
Abt
G
is one that
as an explanatory variable for
bxt. One
purpose of considering that variant is to eliminate thc2 possibility that estimated effects of monetary policy on nominal GNP are actually due co a reverse-causation response of
Ab, to Axt,
as suggested by King and Plosser
(1984) and other real-business-cycle theorists.
The estimates
with
this
change are as follows:
= 0.0078 + 0.198 dxt 1 + 0.549 Abt 1 + e3t (.0019) (.083) (.125) -
Ax
t
R2 = 0.248
SE = 0.0099
(3)
D
Clearly, the estimated coefficient values are almost the same as in (2), but the additional lag between target departures leads to
a
slight deterioration
simulation usin
and corrective
in performance:
(3) and rule (1) is 0.0212.
the RMSE
effects
value for a
That deterioration
is not
readily visible in the plot for this case,,which is therefore not included. It r's clear that these preliminary results are open to two major types of criticism, namely, that the "models" used to depict GNP determination are too
simple and
that they are unlikely
to
be policy
invariant.
To
respond to those potential criticisms is the main purpose of the present paper.
To that end, we now turn to experiments analogous to those just
described
but
conducted with
a
variety
of multivariable
models
of
the
economy utilized in place of regression equation (2) or its variant (3).
“Finn
Kydland
when measured fil+er
or
is only
depend
in
fiuctuations. theories, 17
0.028.
part
But the
The
pointed to
d ciigner-CrW-der
RMSE value wi I I
has
relative
the
.
In
values
are
not
most wroth
polynocirial
in
An analyst’s his
mean
judgment
inflation
described
fluctuations
of
of
provided
the
time.
type
Relative
choice
reported
entailed
cases
that path
figures
variability
simulated
quarter
on
out
a smoothed
copzerning
rate below,
to
the
indicate
(1)
is not
with the
rule mean
reportrng.
181
GrdP are
in
of
time, of
!.ivaI
whatever
much smaller
l-todrick-Prescott
measures
merits that,
norninal by the
a cklbic
among alternative
below
by rule
actual
for actual
the
variability
theories
one’s
(1980)
example,
of
judgment
CyCl ical concerning
large. (1) inflation
and
X rate
=
0.25 is
is
3nTy
SO c!OSe
t0
3.05% ZerO
Per that
e begin our robustness investigation with a number of vector autoregression
(VAR)
models.
AS
SUC!T
make
~~tiels
no
pretense
of
being
structural, there is no good reason to believe that their parameters would be
the
same
under
starting point,
alternative
policy
for
nevertheless,
regimes.
consideration
They of
provjde
a
useful
issues such
as
the
effect of including or excluding certain variables. And in practice it may be that parameter responses to regime chirnges are not large.'* Accordingly, exercises analogous to those described above for models
In each case
(2) an:: (3) have been conducted with a variety of VAR systems.
tk
1954.1 - 1985.4
procedure was to estimate parameters and residuals over
fw a VAR system that irzludes hbt as one of
Then a 128.
Jriables.
.
period simulation was conducted, based on initial conditions pertainir;g to
1954.1,
ith estimated
explaining Abt,
shocks fed
equations
except
the one
values of the latter being generated by pol?~y rule
rather than the VAR equation. used in (l),
in for all
Four values of the feedback para,leter A
(1) were
ith each VAR specification, to obtain evidence concerning the
desirability of x values larger or smaller than the 0.25 figure mentioned alJove. In most of the systems nominal GNP was not itselt included as one of the variables, but logarithms of real GNP and the GNP price deflator were. Consequently, simulated values of xt could easily be obtained and compared with the xt target path.
Results of these comparisons are summarized by Such statis!--&
means of the RSME statistic, as discussed in Section II. are reported for seven VAR systems in Table
Ai+
The
SmalleSt
and
A+
1.
VAR system considered includes the three variables Abt,
where pt and yt denote logs of the GNP deflator and real GNP, Four lagged values were
included for each variable?
The
SE values for this system are reported in the first row of Table 1. There ill be seen that the
SE with x = 0.25 is 0.0217, almost the same as
reported in Section II for regression model (3) -- a model
‘$hat is stu;
of
Taylor
in
of
“The
principle
a! .crnative
(l~d4)
change
; s implicitly
position
correct
has
Octcbner
but -onetary
examined
taken
unimportant policies the
for
all
has
parameter
1979 and found
same i ~j true
by many economists, quantitatively.
of
significant
the
been
stability but
VAR systems
182
who argue That
explicitly of modest
suggested
a
VAR model adjustments.
discussed
in
that
VAR models
thib
the can
by across
section.
Lucas be
used
Litterman the
Fed’s
critique for
the
(!982). pal icy
Table I ation Results with VAR E Values for 1954.1 - 1 --
Value of x in Policy Rule (1)-
Variables in VAR System
0.0 --
01 L
0.25
0.5
1.
Wt,tpt,Abt
.0414
.0257
-0217
.0244
2.
Ayt'Apt,Rt,Abt
.0479
.0216
.0220
.1656
3.
AytJq+Rg,Agt,Abt
4.
(a)
AC& gehaeratedby VAR
.0477
.0216
.0225
JO70
(b)
Actual Agt values
.0465
.0216
.0226
.1217
(c)
Actual Agt-Ayt
.0466
-0215
-0226
.0364
L?YtJPt,Rt,Ast,Abt
.0404
.a0253
-0265
1.2407
course, a two-variable VAR with only one lagged value. The other entries in
row 1 pertain to the alternative values of x that were considered:
0.19and
0.5.
0.0,
From the RMSE figures reported, it appears that ?. = 0.25 is
superior in this particular system.
The differtnces are not great uit31
respect to x = 0.1 and A = 0.5, RMSE values close i;o0.025 being obtak& in each of these cases. Performance in the absence of feedback (A -:0.0) is significantly worse, however. The second VAR model adds the 99-&y to the variables of the previous
Treasury bill
system.
rate, denoted
ith this change
Rt,
the results
become noticeably different, as can be seen from TnbTe 1 and also Figure 2, which presents simulatio:, plots for all four values of the smaliest RF%E results from A = 0.1, 0.1656 occurs when
x
x.
In particular, SE value of
and a very Kg
is set at the value 0.5.
:ke
reason
unsatisfactory performance in this 1 are encountered, as can be seen in parts (a) and (b), corresponding to
A =
aspects of positive feedback can be seen. 2(c) and from the
SE statistic, t
st as
183
0.0 and
A = kl,
t
for t
FIGURE2
(A)
A =
-.
LX
0.00
...*...
(8)
A =
184
0.1
7
I
6175 6I I 25
6I 5x
LX
7s0 ?825 7. a 6,45
. .. . . . .
Ml
consider a five-variable VAR system in which the additional
Next :‘:!
variable Bs Agt,
where gt denotes the Tog of real government purchases of
goods and se;-vices (at all levels of government).
In this case there are
various ways in which Agt can be trpaied, to reflect the notion of "other things equal," in the simulations that use policy rule (1) to generate Abt. Here three treaiments were considered
the first of which uses Agt values
generated by the Agt equation that was estimated as
the second treatment uses actual Agt values in the simulation,
By contrast, while
the
art of the VAR system.
third
uses
purchtisesto real GNP. slightly better
actual
values
for
the
ratio
of
real
government
With all three treatments, results with x = 0.1
than with
x = 0.25,
and results with
A = 0.5
are
are the
poorest by a considerable margin. The difference between these results and those
obtained
with
the
four-variable
VAR
is
negligible
for
the
intermediate x values of 0.1 and 0.25. The final VAR experiment involves a five-variable system in which an exchange-rate
measure
is
used
instead
of
government
purchases.
Since
figures on the trade-weighted value of the United States dollar (denoted St) are available only for periods beginning with 1967.1,
figures for 1954-
66 had to be constructed from series pertaining to jndividual currencies. The procedure adopted was to estimate
a least squares regression of St on
United States exchange rates relative to Canada (SE), the United Kingdom (StK),
the Netherlands (Sf), Italy (S:), and Belgium (SF).
For the sample
period 1967.1 - 1986,3 the estimated relation is
St = 14.00 Sk + 42 59 SF” + 18.70 StN + 0.00329 StI + 0.3930 5; + eqt
(4)
wit5 a~ R2 value of 0.9900. Formula (4) was then used to generate estimated values of St for 1953-66. Letting st = log St, the variable included in the VAR system is Ast. In both estimation and simulation steps, the actual ASt values are used for 1954.1 -
1971.3 and VAR-generated values for 1971.4 -
1985.4, the difference pertaining to periods of fixed and floating exchange rates. Results are reported in row 4 of Table 1. There it will be seen that the
SE values are
plosive oscillations
larger than with
the other systems, and highly ex-
are encountered with x = 0.5.
Effectiveness of the
policy rule is, nevertheless, entirely satisfactory with x equal to 0.1 or
0.25:
the
SE values are
ell below the 0.085 referb>nce
figure that per-
tains to actual variability (relative to trend) for the U.S. during 195485,
186
IV, RESULTS ITH CLASSICALA e now turn to models that are "structural" in the sense that they pertain to specific alternative theories concerning the nature of businesscycle fluctuations. These models are extremely small in scale and are not here rationalized by explicit maximizing represent
the
theoretical
principal
positions.
analysis, but are specified
characteristics
Three
of
important,
such positions
are
and
considered:
to
competing, the
real
business cycle position, the monetary misperceptions position, and one of a more Keynesian slant. AS suggested by the first principle set forth in Section II,
the main
difference among these theories concerns the aggregate-supply or Phillipscurve portion of the macroeconomic system, Consequently, the same specification is used in all three cases for the aggregate demand portion of the model --
i.e., for the relation describing
the quantity of output that
would be demanded at a given prfce level for consumption, investment, and government purposes together.
In order to keep the model small, a single
aggregate-demand relation is here used, instead of sectoral relations for consumption of
nondurables, consumption of services, investment in fixed
plant and equipment, investment in inventories, and so on.
The principal
determinants
are
of
demand quantities
in such
a
relationship
taken to be real money balances and government purchases.
typically
For our purposes
it is appropriate to utilize real quantities of the monetary base instead of the former variable, thereby implicitly incorporating into the specification banking sector relations reflecting the connection between the monetary base.
P and
The resulting relation is estimated in first-differ-
enced logarithmic form, with one lag of each variable included to reflect dynamics. Least squares estimates for the sample period 1954.1 - 1985.4 are as follows:
%Yt
= 0.0045 + 0.2591. ~y~_~ + 0.2795 (abt-apt) (.127) (.OOl) (.083)
+ 0.2731 (abt_l-apt_l) + 0.1476 agt - 0.1675 agt_l+ egt (.062) (.061) (.131)
Y2 \ =
0.276
SE = 0.00916
187
(5)
The point estimates
in (5) were
adopted for use in all simulations de-
scr%ed
in this section, with the residuals e5t being used as estimates of 20 shocks to aggregate demand. Next, consider
the
aggregate-supply
portion of
the three competing
theories. In the case of the RBC approach it is not necessary to estimate That convenient property stems from the
any relations in addition to (5).
exogeneity postulated by the RBC hypothesis of real variables with respect to nominal variables -- and therefore to monetary policy actions -- plus the assumption that any fiscal effects on output work through an inter21 Thus we take real output mediate impact on nominal aggregate demand. movements to be exogenous, which implies that the role of (5) is simply to determine
level. Since
the price
results
reported above
in lines
(3a),
(3b), and (3~) of Table 1 indicate that different treatments regarding Agt have
little
exogenous.
quantitative
importance,
we
In sum, the simulation exercise uses
Agt
values
to
be
(1) and (5) to generate
set at their actual historical
sequences for bt and pt with gt and yt values.
take
also
Values of xz are then calculated as xt=pt+yt and can be
compared
with target-path x1 values for the purpose of RMSE computations. The second of the three structural models is designed to represent the monetary misperceptions theory, developed by Lucas (1972) (1973).
As the
leading attempts to implement this approach empirically are those of Barro (1977) (1978), our formulation is based to a considerable extent on his. particular,
money-growth
surprises
-- measured
empirically
In
as residuals
from an equation designed to explain fluctuations in money growth rates -?re
taken
to be
**It
might
instrumental difficulty
endogenous
that
same
estimate squares
hand,
and
equation 21
of
tend
least
This
f?f3C proponenrs
is
the to
(5)
might
are
a relation true
for the
truly
therefore
In
this
least
so
(5)
is
are
estimated
disturbance
about
power
of
four policy
conservative, regard,
from the
to
times
rather
than
some
stems
from
no
forced with
to is
individual as
in
as
with
the
to
values much
of lagged
of
Ay,,
larger
parameters.
large
perspective
variables
turn
lagged
operatrons
discussion
base,
answer
variance
the
present
The
probably
is
one
attached
For
squares
bias.
There
errors is
iring
by
output.
in the monetary
simultaneity
estimated
standard
seems
preferable.
estimated
to
real
movements
exogenous,
on Abt-Apt stabil
of
instruments.
the the
coefficient
is
reduce
similar
instruments,
increase
estimates
probably (9)
as
why
that
that If
used
the
asked
surprise
appropriate
significance
Agt
would
be
finding
variables.
and
to use
estimator
in
accordingly point
naturally
variable
macroeconomic
Abt ,
important determinant
it is useful
pwgsses
the
an
in
(51,
Abt. of
the
paragraph
and The
a result
To use
the
issue
at
following
is relevant. is
a simplification, to technology
but shocks
one as the
that
seems just
source
188
of
Ificd
cyclical
in view
of
fluctuations.
the emphasis
given
by
instead of
the
1 money
stock considered by Barro.
For the first-step
regression used to represent the systematic component of base growth, the following autoregression was adopted:**
Abt = 0.0016 + 0.4679 Abt- 1 + 0.0426 Abt -2 -I0.3372 Ab (.OOl) (.082) (.093) (.083) t3
R2 =
0.651
SE
from
(6),
Residuals
n
0.00463
=
denoted
-+ Ab t
(6)
I= 2.07
ibt , were
then
employed
as
explanatory
variables in the "aggregate supply"'equation with estimates as follows:
= 0.0048 + 0.3028 ibt + 0.3776 ibt 1 + 0.3281 Ayt 1 + e7t (.OOl) (.193) (.191) (A83) -
AYt
R2
0.150
=
SE
=
0.00978
BW
=
2,lO
In the latter, it should be emphasized, standard errors associated with the coefficients attached to Abt technical reasons.
values are larger than in Barre's work for
Thus the yt variable appears in first-differenced form
and the specification includes Ayt_l as an explanatory variable, thereby tending These
to
attribute
surprises
considerable
less explanatory power
continue
to
influence of Abt
Since the policy rule
have
to the monetary
sizeable
coefficients,
surprises.
however,
so
a
irregularity on' output is implied by (7).
(1) is deterministic, there will of course be no The latter uses equations
surprises occurring in the simulation exercise.
(I), (B), and (7) to generate values for bt, pt, and yt -- which permit calculation
of xt magnitudes
for comparison with the target path as
in
other cases. Finally, we turn to our specification more representative of
In particular, this specification was designed to represent .-- in
views.
22
Some readers
implies
that
component
study
the
Ab, that
is
decompos i ton
however,
Sargent’s
will
there
Here,
simply
Keynesian
our
that
(!976) is
policy
the
--
the terms,
that
the
identification
objective
implications
assume
recognize an
for
“observational is our
residuals that
absence
problem
not
to
policy from
is,
additional
that
rule
if
are
we assume
the it
Rarro-type
were
stirpricer
that
invariant.
189
(6)
is
explanatory
with problem
equivalence”
argue
(6)
of
associated
the
discussed model
appropriate.
variables
surprise is Given
vs.
in
by Sargent
(1976).
appropriate, that
but
purpcje,
2nd
i n~ec_tin,atc the consequences.
the
version
of
(6)
systematic
an autoregression
to we
In for
simplified form -- the wage-price portion of the well-known MPS econometric In that model, nominal wage changes are dependent
(via an expec23 and a tational Phillips relation) on a measure of capacity utilization
model.
measure of expected inflation. Prices then adjust gradually toward values implied by the prevailing
level of wages and "'normal" labor productivity
growth. In our implementation, the first of these two relations is represented by the following equation estimated by least squares over 1954.P85.4: bwt=0.004a + 0.1838 (yt-y,) - 0.1327 (yt_I-&I) (.042) (.OOl) (.042) R2
=
0.545
SE
DW
'- 0.00479
=
+ 0.7594 APE + eat (-072)
(8)
x1.81
Were wt denotes the log of the nominal wage in manufacturing while yt-yt
is
the logarithmetic deviation of real GNP from a fitted trend, and the expetted inflation rate A$
is proxied
by actual inflation rates averaged
over the previous eight quarters. As the coefficient on A$
is signifi-
cantly less than 1.0, the specification does not possess the natural-rate property of
steady-state
independence between
inflation and yt-yt.
This
makes the model more "Keynesian," and perhaps more favorable to an XtiViSt strategy, than if the coefficient equalled unity. The
second
new
equation
in
this
model
is
the
MPS-style
price
adjustment equation. Our version was estimated in first differenced form -in principle obviating
the need for a trend term to reflect productivity
changes -- as follows: = 0.0003 + 0.4929 Awt + o.m8 A$ 1 + egt (.0007) (.064) (.063) -
Apt
R2 =
SE
0.692
=
0.003%
D
=
(9)
2.43
ith (8), a slight departure from steady-state neutrality is implied by
23Actually, model presented currently has
an
itself.
been
inverse
rneti_;a’e
A description in
McCallum
used provided
by
the
of
a
(1979). research
by Brayton
based
More staff
on
streamlined at
and Mauskopf
the
recently, the
unemployment
version Board
(1987).
190
of
the
a
qualitative
of
Governors
rate
is
model’s
util
discussion of
the
ired
in
wage-price Federal
of
the MPS
sector the
Reserve
is
version System
the point estimates?
Thus this last model has quite different properties
from the RBC and monetary-misperception
representations.
Its simulations
use equations (l), (5), (8), and (9) to generate time paths for bt% yt, pt and wt, with xt and
RMSEvalues obtainable as in the other cases.
Before turning to the results of our simulation exercises, it will be useful
to
emphasize
the
relatively
innocuous
nature
of
econometric
weaknesses in the estimation of the three models. It is not crucial that least squares
estimates
of
(8) and
(9),
for
example,
are
subject
to
simultaneity bias or even that identification of (8) and (9) is dubious. The objective in estimating theFe models is not to build a case that any of the models is "true," but simply to 13htain numerical representations, which are consistent with United States data for 1954-85, of alternative theories of macroeconomic behavior. One could in principle simpiy assign conjectured parameter values so long as the shock estimates are based on those values. That parameter values are roughly consistent with the dirta, and that shock estimates are not too far from white noise, is guaranteed
by our approach.
Let us consider, then, results of the simulations using
(1)
with
tabulated,
each
of
these
three
structural
agciin for four values of x, in
models.
The
policy
rule
RMSEvalues
are
Table 2. It will readily be seen
that with each of these models the results are even more favorable to our
Table 2 Simulation Results with Structural Models RMSE Values for 1954.1 - 1985.4 Value of-
RBCModel Equation (5), actual yt Barro-Type Model Equations (5), (7) Phi 11 ips Curve Model Equations (5)‘) (8), (9)
24
imposition
a deterioration
of in
the
the
constraint
that
the
Policy Rule
0.00
0.10
0.25
O-50
.0281
.0200
AI160
-0132
.0238
-0194
A161
-0137
.0311
A236
,019l
Al74
coefficients
IIW statistic.
191
on Aw,
and Apt_,
sum to one
leads
to
policy rule than those obtained in Section III. in
each case the RMSE value declines
magnitude
policy
the
of
as
1 is increased9 to
response
feedback
Thus in contrast with
strengthened.
Also it bill be seen that i.e., as the errors
xt-x;
the VAR cases, no sign of
is
induced
dynamic instability is encountered for x values up to 0.5. There
are
two
features
of
these
models
that
responsible for these differences vis-a-vis the VAR
would
appear
to
systems. First,
smaller RMSE values reflect the possibility of better stabilization
be the
that
occurs when nominal GNP is dependent upon current-period values of bbt, as implied by equation (5).z5 Second, the danger of dynamic
instability
is
lessened both by this current-period response and also -- although this is not a logical necessity -- by the lower-order dynamics of the system that results from fewer lagged terms and shorter lags. Let us
conclude
this
section
by
exhibiting
plots
of
simulated
xt
values together with x; target paths for the Keynesian model (l), (5), (8), These plots, shown in Figure 3,
and (9) with A values of 0.0 and 0.25.
again illustrate the valun of the feedback term X(X:-~ -xt_l) in rule (1).
V, ADDITIONALRESULTS The results reported in Sections
III and IV indicate rather clearly
that performance of the policy rule (1)
has considerable robustness with
respect tc model specification, i.e., that its performance is good under a wide
variety of
specifications.
however, directly critique.
address
It does
not
the show,
That
issue
type
implied
:f demonstration
does
not,
by
the
Lucas
in other words,
reference that
to
performance
is not
seriously impaired for a given model specification by a significant change in parameter values. In
order
to
develop
a
bit
of
evidence
relating
to
this
last
possibility, one approach is to impose parameter changes on a given model and redo the simulation exercises values),
(while feeding
in the original
Results of an exercise of this type are reported in Table 3.
shock The
ith the simplified "model" reported in equation (3), for icients are as follows:
25
Also,
in
their
specific
models,
by equations
192
(7)
and
(8).
7
I
I
75
6I
LX
. . . . .. .
TMI
193
Table 3 Sensitivity Results -
-
Coefficient Valuesa --
Case Ib 2 3 4
J981,
-5489
.1981, .1981, .1981, .3981, .0981,
5 6
.0212 .0252
.34a9 .2489 -7489 .5489 .5489
.0291 .0202 .0274 .0193
-1 and abt_l, respectively
'Coefficients attached to bReference case
AXt
= 0.0078 + 0.1981 AXE 1 + 0.5489 Abt I + e3t.
(IO)
As described in Section II, the RMSE value for xt relative to XT is 0.0212 when
the value of
0.25
is used
for
the feedback
parameter
A, and the
equation (3) residuals are used as shock esr'imates in the simulation for bt and xt. The first variant on that simulation, reported as Case 2 in Table 3, repeats the simulation with everything unchanged except the coefficient in (lo),
attached to Abt_l
hich is reduced to 0.3489.
The resulting RMSE
value of 0.0252 is somewha
larger than in the reference Case 1, but not
enough to be disturbing. T
same can be said, moreover, for the four other
cases investigated -- in
1 of which
the RMSE
is less than 35% of
value pertaining to detrended actual experience (Le., Some analysts,
the
0.085).
Meltzer (1984) (1987) and Barro (1986), have
favored policy stra
her similar to the one here reco
designed to attempt to main
n a constant price level directly rather than
indirectly through
ationary
a
nonin
path 26 eltzer's preferred rule for Abt is as follows:
26 four.
Actual Here
ly,
Mel trer
we ignore
that
fecfxni~
, averaging
minor
terence
growth
over
for
the
194
the sake
previous of
clarity.
for
nominal
three
years,
GNP.
Thus
rather
than
hbt= (l/16)
w
[ (yt_l-yt_17) - (xt_l-xt_17-bt_l+bt_17) 1.
Here the -00739 term in our rule is replaced by the average growth rate of real GNP over the previous sixteen quarters, while the third term in our rule is omitted.27
(feedback)
To consider the properties of rule (II),
one needs to select a criterion.
The one most directly suggested by this
approach is the RMSE of a simulated pt series relative to a constant price level.
aan unwilling to adopt such a criterion, however, because to do so
I
would require rejection of the first principle adopted above in Section II: that we do not possess an adequate model of the way in which nominal CNP changes are split, on a quarter-to-quarter basis, between real growth and inflation. An nominal
alternative GNP
predicted
as
by
possibility
the
the
criteria,
most
is to continue but
recent
with
four
future
years'
to use real
experience
RMSE GNP
growth
rather
constant value of 0.00739 (i.e.* 3% pe: Jear) used above. case one would continue to be
values
for
rates
than
the
But in such a
interested in noninflationary
nominal GNP
growth, so the target-path xt values should also be adjusted to conform to the altered real GNP predictions. Consequently,
the target path in this
case is as follows:
fe %t
=
* + Xt-1
(12)
ww(Yt_l-Yt_17)'
One might guess that results target for L
nominal GNP,
based on
would
be
rule
(ll),
with
little different
x;* used as the
from
those
obtained
previously with rule (1) -- with x - 0.0 -- and the target xt. To check that conjecture, results have been obtained using the simple two-variable model (3) with
As it happens, the FWE
x = 0.0.
value of 0.0458 obtained
with rule (11) agrees to the third nonzero digit with that for rule (I)! Simulation plots for these two cases are provided in Figure 4. Finally,
let
us
turn
emphasized by Gordon (1985).
27 results
The for
effect (1)
of with
omirting
the
to
"start-up"
considerations
of
the
type
These refer to the possible undesirability of
feedback
term
A = 0.0.
195
has
alredy
been
explored
by
means
of
the
FIGURE4
.
7
I
5
6
I
I
25
LX
....... NRA
Rule (l),
A
= 0.0
hen a rule such
adjusting nominal GNP growth toward a 3% rate too rapidly
as (1) is adopted at a time at which recent growth rates *have been much higher
(or,
in principle,
much
lower)
than
that
value.
Under
such
circumstances a reasonable way to begin might be to move gradually toward the 3% rate over a period of (say) three or four years.
To investigate the
workings of our rule with this sort of modification, consider an experiment in which the simulatien period begins with the quarter 1972.3 rather than 1954.1.28
Since recent growth rates for nominal GNP had been closer to 11%
than to 3X, a gradual-adjustment approach would then involve a target path that features nominal GNP growth rates such as the following:
Quarter
Quarter
AX”
.02494 .02377 .02260 -02143 .02026 .01909 .01792 .01675
AX*
.01558 -01441 .01324 .01207 .01090 .00973 -00856 .00739
9 10 11 12 13 :z 16
At the same time, it might be desirable to start with a constant term in the base-growth rule that was greater than 0.00739 and adjusted toward that value over (e.g.) sixteen quarters.
In the single experiment that has been
conducted, however, policy rule (1) was retained in its usual form. 29
The
results of that experiment, shown in Figure 5, are better than might be expected. 0.0297,
Indeed, the RMSE for the 1972.3-1985.4 simulation period is only
which
is
not
much
worse
than
for
the
entire
period
despite
inclusion of the 1981-82 episode, which contributes a large portion of the target misses in all cases.
28 was
One reason
a period 29
Effects
of
for
choosing
relatively of
the
altered
1954.1
little target
as the
inflation path
initial or
are
data
for
our
basic
simulations
is
that
unemployment. significant
197
for
base-growth
rates,
of
course.
it
FIGURE5
x = 0.25
'75 '76 '77 '78 '79 '8
'83 '$
Tt is clear that many
additional experiments could be conducted to
provioe additional infor ation concerning the apparent
(1)
for conducting monetary
models
policy, The
suita
ility of rule
use of more complex
is one obvious possibility; extension
of those
structural
IV to
in Section
incorporate exchange-rate effects and more detail in the determination of aggregate dcaand would be desirable. 30 ore experimentation with start-up reactions at varioub o&es is another possibility. 31 Enough different specifications and cases have been considered here, however, to suggest that a policy rule such as
(1) has considerable promise
as a device for obtaining improved macroeconomic performance. Specifically, our
simulation
results
indicate
rates specified by (1) would
that
adherence
to monetary
base-growth
yielded essentially zero inflation in the
hwe
United States over the period 1954-85, despite the financial and regulatory changes
of
that
period,
while
also
reducing
the
extent
of
cyclical
fluctuations in nominal -- and perhaps real -- GNP.
38
inclusion
variables
3’Several during
the
experienced probably
of
would
have
banking-sector
be another conference
1930s.
It
would
have
helped
linking
relationships
money
stock
and
monetary-base
possibility. participants seems called
considerably.
clear forth
raised that
a
massive I plan
to
the
issue
decline injections investigate
199
of i,I
how the nominal of
this
base
rule
would
GN? such money,
question
in
as s3
have
performed
that the
actual rule
a subsequent
ty
would study.
Barro, R-3. (1977)
Unanticipated
oney
Growth
States, American Economic (1978)
Unanticipated United States,
oneyp
and
Review,
Output,
Unemployment
in the
United
67: IOl-115.
and
the
Price
JournalofPoliticaT Economy,
Level
in
the
86: 549-580
Recent Developments in the Theory of Rules versus Discretion,
(1986)
EconomicJournal,
96, Supplement: 23-37.
and Gordon, 0.8. (1983)
A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Jownaioj Political
91: 589-610.
Economy,
Blanchard, 0-J. (1988)
Why Does Money Affect Output?
A Survey.
Friedman and
Economics,
Handbook of Monetary
F.H.
Hahn.
Amsterdam:
North Holland, forthcoming. Brayton, F. and (1987)
Structure and Uses of the MPS Quarterly Econometric Model of the United States, Federal Resente
Bulletin,
73: W-109.
Bronfenbrenner, (1961)
Statistical Tests of Rival
Economy,
(1983)
7)
of Political
69: l-14.
Strategies
Rochester
onetary Rules, Journal
and
Tactics
for
onetary
Conference Series on Public Policy,
Business Cycles.
The New Palgrave:
acmillan Press.
200
Control,
Carnegie-
28: 59-104.
A Dictionary
of Economics.
(1973)
Stabilization Policy and La
(1975)
Economic
StaMitation
Amsterdam:
oZitic& Economy, 81:
Policy:
ethoch
in
Optimization.
orth-Holland.
Gordon, R.J. (1985)
The Conduct of Domestic
Our
(eds.) A.
Times,
Suzuki.
onetary Policy.
Ando,
Cambridge, MA:
E.
one&u-y Policy
Eguchi, R.
Farmer,
in
and Y.
The MIT Press.
Hall, R.E, (1983)
Macroeconomic Policy Under Structural Change. IndustriaZChange and PublicPolicy,
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Hodrick, R.J. and Prescott, E.C. (1980)
Post-War U.S. Business Cycles: Working Paper, Carnegie
An Empirical Investigation,
ellon University.
King, R.G. and Plosser, C.I. (1984)
oney, Credit, and Prices in a Real Business Cycle, American
Economic Ratiew,
74: 363-380.
Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. (1977)
Rules Rather than Discretion: Plans, Journal of Political
Economy,
The Inconsistency of Optimal 85: 473-491.
Lindsey, D.E. (1986)
The Monetary Regime of the Federal Reserve System, Alternative
onetary Baltimore:
Regimes,
(eds)
C.D.
Campbell
and
Johns Hopkins University,
Litterman, R.B. (1982)
Optimal Control of the inneapolis,
oney Supply, Federal Reserve Bank of
uarterlyReview, F
201
Lucas,
R-E., Jr. Expectations and the Neutrality of
(1972)
Some
of Economic
4: 103-124.
Theory,
(1973)
oney, Journal
International Evident:
American
Economic Reviews
"8.iOutput-Inflation
Tradeoffs,
6::: ??5-334.
cCallum, B.T. (1979)
Monetarism, Rational Expectations, Oligopolistic Pricing, and the MPS Econometric Model, dourna2 of Political
Economy,
87: 57-
75. (1984)
onetarist Rules in the Light of Recent Experience, American
Economic Review Proceedings,
(1987)
74: 388-391.
The Case for Rules in the Conduct of Monetary
Policy:
A
Concrete Example, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic September/October, 10-18.
Review,
Also Weltwirtschaftliches
Archiv, 123: 415-429.
ww
Inflation:
Theory
Economics,
(eds.) B.M.
and
Evidence.
Handbook
Friedman and
of
Monetary
F.H. Hahn. Amsterdam:
North Holland Pub. Co., forthcoming. eltzer, A.H. (1969)
Controlling
eview,
(1984)
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, MonthZy
51: 16-24.
Overview.
P&e
Stability
and Public Policy,
Fecl,ralReserve Bank
of Kansas City.
or&Run
Stabilization
202
Policy,
Economic
Inquiry,
(1954)
Stabilization Policy in a Closed Economy,
(1957)
Stabilization Policy and the Time Forms of Lagged Responses,
conomic
Journal )
67: 265-277.
Economic Journal, Sargent, T.3. (1976)
The Observational Equivalence of Natural and Unnatural Rate Theories of
acroeconomics, Journal
of
Political
Economy,
84:
631-64% Taylor,
3.8.
(1981)
Accommodation, and Monetary Rules,
Stabilization,
Economic Review Papers and Proceedings,
(1984)
Recent Changes Series
Evidence,
Proceedings,
(1985)
in Macro
Policy
American
71: 145-149.
and its
Economic
American
Effects: Review
Some Time
Papers
74: 206-210.
What Would Nominal GNP Targetting Do to the Business Cycle? Carnegie-Rochester
Conference
Series on Pu.bZic Policy,
Monetwy Fol icy:
Rules, Targets,
22: 61-84.
Tobin, J. (1983)
Credit, and Banking,
(1965)
(IRK
oney and Economic
and Shocks, Journal of
15: 506-518.
Growth9 Econometrica,
203
33: 671-