ELSEVIER
Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
Journalof BANKING & FINANCE
The benefits from international diversification for Nordic investors Eva Liljeblom a,*, Anders L~Sflund a, Svante Krokfors b Swedish School of Economics and Business Administration, P.O. Box 479, 00101 Helsinki, Finland b Euli Securities Ltd.. P.O. Box 1081, 00101 Helsinki. Finland
Received 22 March 1995; accepted 4 September 1996
Abstract In this paper, we investigate the magnitude of the benefits from international diversification from the Nordic point of view. Special attention is paid to whether potentially increased co-movement of stock markets together with more volatile Nordic currencies have resulted in decreased benefits from international diversification towards the end of the 1980s. Moreover, the paper presents evidence on the benefits from international diversification for a currency which has recently started its free float, the Finnish markka (FIM). We find significant increases in stock market co-movement. Both unhedged ex ante strategies as well as strategies hedged for exchange rate risk are investigated, revealing substantial benefits from international diversification for the Nordic countries. However, we obtain mixed results concerning the question of the optimality of hedging. JEL classification." GI1; G15 Keywords: International diversification; Stock market co-movement
1. Introduction A large n u m b e r o f studies for U.S. and other mostly large capital markets have demonstrated that the c o - m o v e m e n t s b e t w e e n different national stock markets are
* Corresponding author. Phone: (358)-0-43131, fax: (358)-0-431 33 393, e-mail:
[email protected], and
[email protected]. 0378-4266/97/$17.00 Copyright © 1997 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII S03 78-4266(96)0005 3-2
470
E. Liljeblom et aL / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
of a magnitude low enough to induce significant benefits from international portfolio diversification. 1 For a time period ending in 1988/mid-1989, similar results have been obtained also for the Nordic stock markets in Haavisto and Hansson (1992) 2, and for Finland in Haavisto (1989). In general, the studies show that benefits occur even in the presence of currency risk, although additional benefits are likely to occur at least in the case of large foreign holdings if one hedges for exchange rate risk. 3 In the early studies, the focus was on the performance of ex post efficient portfolios, while in subsequent studies, also the ex post performance of portfolios formed on ex ante grounds have been investigated, with estimation risk taken into account. The conclusion of large benefits as compared to domestic portfolio holdings remains unchanged in these more refined studies. However, recently an increase in the co-movement between national stock markets after the crash of 1987 has been reported in many studies, see e.g. Bertero and Mayer (1990), Jeon and yon Furstenberg (1990), Le (1991), Arshanapalli and Doukas (1993), and Longin and Solnik (1995). A higher degree of international dependence can also be expected especially for the Nordic capital markets (Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden) because a number of steps towards integration has been taken. The Nordic countries (particularly Sweden and Finland) faced severe legal restrictions for capital movements across national borders until the beginning of the 1980s. These restrictions included barriers for corporate international investment as well as for portfolio investments. These restrictions were subsequently removed during the 1980s, a time period during which many Nordic firms also became much more internationalized. By now, many large companies could be regarded as diversified portfolios of international activities through exports and foreign investment. Thus their stock price should be expected to be more correlated with that of other firms around the world. Such an increase in the international stock market co-movement would suggest decreased benefits from international diversification. In addition, increased exchange rate volatility may also have reduced diversification benefits of unhedged international portfolios. The early 1990s was a turbulent period on the markets for foreign exchange, particularly in Finland and Sweden, as well as in Norway, three
I See e.g. Grubel (1968), Levy and Sarnat (1970), Solnik (1974), Lessard (1973, 1976), Solnik and Noetzlin (1982), Logue (1982), Jorion (1985), and Grauer and Hakansson (1987). 2 In their paper, only diversification within the Nordic stock markets was investigated. 3 The empirical evidence on the benefits of hedging is, however, mixed. Whereas hedging produced an improvement e.g. in Eun and Resnick (1988) and in Jorion (1989), in Jorion (1991) the improvement was shown to be much more modest for equity portfolios as compared to bond portfolios, and not always statistically significant - perhaps due to the blurring effect of the generally large volatility of stock portfolios. Mixed evidence was also reported in Levy and Lim (1994), and in Eun and Resnick (1994).
E. Liljeblom et aL / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
471
countries which finally ended with floating exchange rates. On the other hand, if national risks in terms of stock market volatility also have increased in the Nordic countries, the benefits of international diversification may still be reasonably large despite the increased interdependence between national stock markets. The main purpose of this paper is to study the magnitude of the benefits from international diversification from the Nordic point of view during the time period of 1974-93, and to investigate whether significant changes have occurred in the time period 1987-93, i.e. after the liberalization of the Nordic capital markets. W e extend the work of Haavisto and Hansson (1992) by examining diversification outside of Nordic countries and by evaluating ex ante diversification strategies. Moreover, since the Finnish markka (FIM) started its float towards the end of our study period, we present early evidence of the situation under a free float. The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, the data used in the analysis will be described. In Section 3, we will study changes in volatility and the correlation structure of both international stock markets as well as currency returns, and the relative contribution of these two sources of risk for Nordic investors. Next, in Section 4, ex post efficient frontiers for different Nordic countries are computed. In Section 5, the ex post performance of different ex ante strategies, unhedged as well as hedged, are reported for Finnish and other Nordic investors. A summary and conclusion are given in Section 6.
2. The data The analyses are performed on equity returns in 18 national stock markets using monthly data provided by Morgan Stanley Capital International. The countries include 17 OECD countries plus Hong Kong. The stock market returns include capital gains as well as dividend payments, and are based on value-weighted indices formed from mainly major companies (based on market capitalization) on the national stock markets. 4 Descriptive statistics for the different national indexes 5 (in local currencies) reveal negative skewness for all but three cases, and a somewhat high kurtosis. Average monthly logarithmic returns range from 0.007 (Austria) to 0.019 (Hong Kong). Hedged strategies are constructed by means of a short-term money market hedge based on one-month interest rates, or a close substitute. 6 The time period is
5 Descriptive statistics are not reported here but can be obtained from the authors. 4 For further details of the data set, see e.g. Ferson and Harvey (1994), where a similar data set has been used. The index tor Finland has mainly been constructed at the Swedish School of Econ. and Bus. Admin. in Helsinki, Finland, and includes all stocks listed on the Helsinki Stock Exchange, with weights corresponding to market capitalization. 6 This hedge corresponds to a forward hedge, assuming covered interest parity holding, i.e. assuming forward rates being based on the interest rates used in this study. The interest rate definitions and data sources are reported in Appendix A.
472
E. Liljeblom et a L / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
1974-1993, thus starting approximately from the collapse of the fixed exchange rate system. Two subperiods, 1974-1986 and 1987-1993, are investigated separately. The cut-off point was selected based on two criteria. First, 1987 was suggested by international evidence of generally increased stock market volatility as well as co-movement after the crash of 1987.7 Secondly, around that point in time, the capital market restrictions were being removed in Finland, which was the last of the Nordic countries to fully liberalize its capital and foreign exchange markets. 8 When total returns from foreign investment are analysed in local Nordic currencies, the translation of the international returns have been performed using month-end exchange rates for the different currencies. Returns are measured as logarithmic differences of indexes measuring the stock market returns, or the total foreign portfolio returns.
3. Changes in risk and co-movement of stocks and currencies In order to study whether the co-movement between international stock markets (measured in local currency), and foreign exchange rates has increased during the period, correlation coefficients between monthly stock returns during two subperiods 1974-86 and 1987-93, and monthly exchange rate changes during these subperiods were estimated. The stock returns are measured in local currency (i.e. as if all currency risk was eliminated), and the exchange rate changes in FIM. These correlation coefficients are reported in Table 1 for stock returns, and Table 2 for exchange rate changes. A comparison of the upper and lower diagonals in Tables 1 and 2 indicates an overall increase in both stock market co-movement as well as currency co-movement during the second subperiod. Of the 153 correlation coefficients between local stock markets, and the 136 correlation coefficients for exchange rate changes, only two and five, respectively, are lower during the latter subperiod. 9 The average stock market correlation increases from 0.256 to 0.521 over the two subperiods whereas the average exchange rate correlation increases from 0.280 to 0.594. The equality of the correlation as well as covariance matrices was tested using
7 See e.g. Bertero and Mayer (1990), Jeon and von Furstenberg (1990), Le (1991), Longin and Solnik (1995), and Arshanapalli and Doukas (1993). s Free foreign borrowing and direct investment (for nonfinancial companies) was possible in 1987 and 1988, respectively, whereas virtually unrestricted household foreign investment was allowed as late as in 1990. 9 The lower ones for the stock markets measure the co-movement of the Japanese market with either Germany or the Netherlands. The lower ones for currencies are between CAD and the three currencies of ITL, ESP, and GBP, and finally the coefficient between USD and ITL.
E. Liljeblom et al./ Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
d S d d d d g d ~ d d S ~ d
t d S d
473
o
.6 o II
~d II
II d d ~ d d d S g d --
I d d ~ d d d d 5 m ~ l ~ b m ~ b
d d d d d d d d
II
%
2
~ ~ d ~ 6 d d d ~ E
i-
3 d d d d 5
I d d d S d d d d S d d d
E ~
t dd
~ d d d d ~ d d d d ~ d d d
II
e e e
~d
I d d d d d S d d d d S d d d
I 5 d & d d d d d d d d d d d d
~.6 .~
e
o
"
II
~ o-'6
t d d d d S d d d d d d d d d S d
~ ~~ ~ ~ ~ I d d S d d d d d d d S d d d d S d
IL
474
E. Liljeblom et al./ Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
gg
~
~ 1 1 ~
g ~
1
~ @
~
1
=
II
~
~ p~
II
~ 6 6 6 6 6 6 1 6 ~ 1 6 6 6 6 6 °
~a
~
o ..~ =
~
~
o
~ e e ~ e e e o
t
l
o
l
l
l
. . . . . .
. . . . . . . l
o
o
o
~
o
o
o
o
~o
~
~
>~ I
E
~g
dd
b d d 6 d d d o o d d d d d o
ft..z"
I d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d
I
0a ~k9
©
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
475
the Jennrich (1970) test of equality. The equality between the covariance matrices could be rejected at the 1% level both for local stock markets as well as for currency returns. The equality of the currency correlation matrices could be rejected at the 1% level for currency returns ~0, while local stock market correlations were significantly different only at the 15% level. These results suggest reduced benefits from international diversification given unchanged Nordic stock market volatilities. The increased co-movement between currency returns from the F I M point of view can be attributed to two large devaluations/depreciations of F I M in the 1990s, which produced simultaneous increases in all the foreign exchange rates at the same time. 11 A similar explanation is likely also for Sweden and Norway, which too have suffered from large changes in the external value of their currency during the 1990s. 12 In order to investigate the relative contribution of stock market and currency risk, a decomposition of the volatility of the total return (measured in the domestic currency) from the investment in one single foreign market was performed in a way similar to that in Eun and Resnick (1988). Assuming a small cross-product between stock return and exchange rate change, the domestic return of a single foreign investment can be approximated by Ri.d,,m = R i -[- e i
(1)
and the variance of the domestic rate of return as Var( Ri,do m) = V a r ( R i ) + V a r ( e l ) + 2 Cov( R i , e i )
(2)
where Var(Ri) is the variance of the foreign stock market return (i.e. in local currency) and Var(e i) is the variance of the exchange rate for the country of investment. The decomposition was performed from the perspective of all the four Nordic countries. Detailed results are reported here only from the Finnish perspective for the two subperiods in Table 3, panels A and B. Table 3 clearly shows that currency risk stands for only a small part of the total risk of a foreign investment. The pure stock market volatility contributes between 60% (Japan) and 98% (Norway) of the total risk during the first subperiod, and
t0 The same rejection of equality applies for currency correlation matrices measured from the Danish, Norwegian and Swedish point of view (results not reported here but can be obtained from the authors). ~l Although several de- and revaluations of F1M also occurred during the first subperiod, the devaluations during the latter subperiod were much larger. When correlation coefficients between FIM and the rest of the currencies are measured using USD as the benchmark, no large change in the correlation structure is detected. The average correlation coefficient is 0.57 for subperiod 1, and 0.59 for subperiod 2, indicating that the larger foreign currency co-movement from the FIM point of view indeed is due to stronger volatility in the external value of the FIM itself. 12 From the USD point of view, no large increase in general foreign currency co-movement has occurred. Only 83 (61%) of the 136 correlation coefficients between pairs of foreign currencies have increased during the latter subperiod.
476
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
¢q
~a
8
°
I
~oo
~
E. LiIjeblom et al./ Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
%
.= e-,
e,. e.o
E
8 N
4
477
478
E. Liljeblom et al./Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
between 53% (Canada) and 96% (Sweden) during the second subperiod. On the average, approximately 84% of the total risk can be addressed to local stock market volatility during both subperiods. The results are similar for the three other Nordic countries. ~3 These results are in contrast to those generally obtained using a USD numeraire ~4, and in line with those of Haavisto and Hansson (1992), who on the basis of more indirect evidence (portfolio weights, efficient frontiers) concluded for all four Nordic countries that "exchange rate risk was negligible". In general, these results are in line of what could be expected when using a fixed currency as a unit of measurement instead of a freely floating (and highly volatile) currency such as the U.S. dollar. ~5 Especially for investments within Nordic countries, exchange rate risk does not seem to be very important. Stock market volatility stands for most of the volatility of e.g. Finnish investments in the other Nordic countries (between 91% and 98% for investments in Sweden and Norway, respectively, during the first subperiod, and between 91% and 96% for investments in Denmark and Sweden during the second subperiod). However, a separate investigation (not reported here) revealed that the results of the decomposition are dramatically changed by the float of FIM. 16 Also for intra-Nordic investments, the contribution of the local stock market volatility to overall risk goes substantially down during the floating FIM period, to values between 55% and 74% (Finnish investments in Denmark and Sweden, respectively). Next we focus on the question of increased risks. Table 3 also shows that the stock market volatility has increased in 11 cases out of 18, is approximately equal in 1 case, and smaller in 6 cases during the latter subperiod. A non-parametric Wilcoxon signed rank test taking into account both the sign and the magnitude of the difference between the second and the first subperiod stock return volatilities yields an approximately normally distributed test statistic z = 2.156 and hence supports the overall increase in stock market volatility on the 5% level of significance. The exchange rate volatility has increased in 14 cases of 17 and is
13The proportion of the total risk which can be addressed to local stock market volatility is, for subperiods one and two, 84% and 86% for Danish investors, 83% and 94% for Norwegian investors, and 82% and 86% for Swedish investors. 14See e.g. Eun and Resnick(1988). In their study, the relative contributionof the stock market risk is approximately 50% or below, and the contributionof exchange rate volatilityby itself above 30% for all countriesexcept France and Canada. ~5During the investigationperiod, FIM was mostly fixed with respect to a currencybasket of nearly 20 differentcurrencies, with weights based on the countriesshare of Finland's foreign trade. A similar system was in use in Norway and Sweden, while Denmarkbecame part of the ERM. Although parity adjustmentsoccurred, the analysisclearly shows that exchange rate risk is not as largelypresent as for U.S. investors. 16When a similar decomposition was made for the rather short period of the float of FIM (in September 1992, which leaves us with 15 monthlyobservationsof the float), on the average 44% of the total risk could be addressed to local stock market volatility,61% to exchange rate volatility,and 5% to the cross component.These results can be obtainedfrom the authors.
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
479
approximately equal in 1 case (Wilcoxon z-statistic is 3.195 clearly rejecting the null hypothesis of constant currency risk). For the Nordic countries specifically, an increase in both risks have occurred with the exception of stock market volatility for Norway, which in fact was reduced from 0.85 to 0.71 (monthly variances, multiplied by 102). Finally, the relative contribution of exchange rate risk is larger during the latter subperiod in 10 cases out of 17, approximately equally large in one case, and smaller in 6 cases (Wilcoxon z-statistic between the two sets of relative contributions is 0.853 and hence insignificant). In summary, the results reported in this section show significant increases in local stock market covariances during the latter subperiod of 1987-93. Also the co-movement of foreign currencies has significantly increased from the Nordic perspective. These increased co-movements would indicate reduced benefits from international diversification, if not also the risks themselves had increased on the Nordic markets. However, some although weaker evidence of increased stock market risks was also obtained.
4. Ex post efficient frontiers Ex post efficient frontiers were computed using data for the complete time period, as well as for each of the two subperiods. Separate frontiers were computed using each of the four Nordic currencies as a numeraire currency. The four Nordic stock markets were then superimposed on the plot separately along with an equally weighted Nordic portfolio and the value-weighted market index (from Morgan Stanley Capital International). These frontiers are based on total returns 17 (i.e. no risk-free interest rate is deducted), and a short sale restriction is enforced. Results for the second subperiod 1987-1993 are reported here in Fig. 1, clearly showing that substantial benefits from international diversification were obtainable also during the second subperiod for all the Nordic countries with the exception of Denmark. The results also show that although the equally weighted Nordic index (EQW NORDIC) comes rather close to the world market index (WORLD), some additional benefits (above all during the first subperiod, not reported here) could have been obtained by extended diversification outside the Nordic countries. A comparison of subperiod results for 1974-86 (not reported here) and 1987-94 reveal that for several Nordic countries, in fact larger benefits from international diversification seems attainable during the latter subperiod in the
~7 We also computed frontiers based on excess returns (with the monthly risk-flee interest rate deducted) in the four Nordic currencies. These frontiers can be obtained from the authors.
E. Liljeblom et al. /Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
480 30%
...SWE
25% °''''''''-"
~
F
"
DEN
~. 20%
E ~
15%
;
L- / -
_D#
i
(~
~
,.,.
, \\Wf.ws < 10%
, \w,~ \ \*
Sssf
q3d
o*
+Ed
xxNs
_~f
",sa-
d
~d
,Fn -.
5% I
O% 0%
5%
i
10%
~
15%
I
20%
i
25%
I
30%
I
35%
Standard deviation p.a. Fig. 1. Ex post efficient frontiers January 1987 - November 1993. Total returns are measured in FIM, SEK, NOK and DKK. The figure includes four frontiers (computed for each of the four Nordic numeraire currencies), and includes six benchmark portfolios, i.e. the four Nordic domestics ones, the Nordic equally weighted portfolio, and the value-weighted world market index. Each portfolio is plotted four times (using each of the Nordic currencies as the numeraire currency). Definitions: • F" denotes the stock market index for Finland, as perceived by an Norwegian investor. Correspondingly for all other indexes (N = Norway, S = Sweden, and D = Denmark, d = Danish, s = Swedish, f = Finnish investor). • E d is the equally weighted Nordic index, as seen from the perspective of Danish investors. • W s is the value-weighted world market index from a Swedish point of view.
sense that the countries lie further away from the portfolio frontier, as well as from the simple rather well diversified proxies W O R L D and E Q W Nordic. The results in this section show that at least on an ex post basis, there seems to be substantial benefits from international diversification for the Nordic countries. The benefits are, in a relative sense, at least as good during the latter subperiod as compared to the first one. Interestingly, a large part of the benefits can be obtained simply by the use of an equally weighted Nordic portfolio.
5. The performance of ex ante strategies In this section, we analyse the performance of several ex ante investment strategies. These strategies will be analysed from the perspective of both Danish, Finnish, Norwegian, and Swedish investors. Excess returns are used throughout the analysis. 18
18 For the interest rates used when computing excess returns, see Appendix A.
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
481
The pure domestic portfolio is compared to several simple proxies: an investment in the U.S. market (USA), an equally weighted Nordic portfolio (EQW Nordic), an investment in the value-weighted world market portfolio (WORLD), and in an equally weighted world market portfolio (EQW World). A fifth strategy is to identify the weights in the ex post (historical) tangency portfolio, and to invest in a similar portfolio for the next period. In line with Eun and Resnick (1988), this strategy is called CET or the certainty-equivalence-tangency portfolio strategy, since it assumes no estimation risk. In the next strategy, we use the ex ante (historical) weights of the minimum variance portfolio (MVP). This strategy assumes that there is no useful asset-specific information in the vector of average returns because it is not required as an input to solve the portfolio problem. 19 Finally, in line with Jorion (1985, 1986), Eun and Resnick (1988), and others, a Bayes-Stein estimator is implemented. This estimator will take into account the estimation risk involved with historical mean returns, and by the use of a shrinkage factor bring the elements of the return vector towards the mean return for the ex post minimum-variance portfolio MVP. Thereafter, using the conventional unbiased estimator for the inverse of the variance-covariance matrix (see Jobson and Korkie (1981a)), the optimal ex ante tangency portfolio can be determined. This strategy is called BST. Results for hedged strategies are investigated as well. The actual ex post return on a hedged strategy is Ri,dom = [1 + E( R i ) ] ( 1 + f i ) + [ R i - E( R i ) ] ( 1 + ei) - 1
(3)
where R i and E ( R i) are the actual and expected local currency stock returns, J) the forward premium or discount (proxied by a money market hedge in our study), and e i the actual exchange rate change. However, in line with e.g. Eun and Resnick (1988, 1994) and Levy and Lim (1994), we assume a complete (100%) hedge, in which case the hedged return can be approximated by Ri. d.... = R i + ~ .
(4)
Since the CET, MVP, and BST return strategies require an estimation period, five years are reserved for that. Strategies are then implemented for holding periods of one month. A monthly window is used (next month, new strategies are formed based on an estimation period including the previous 60 months, and executed for the next month). This gives us 171 observations of returns on each investment strategy from September 1979 to November 1993. The out-of-sample performance of the unhedged strategies is summarized in
19The instability of sample means as comparedto variances and covarianceshas been demonstrated in several studies, e.g. by the striking results in Jorion (1985).
482
E. Liljeblom et al. /Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
Table 4 for Finland and in Table 5 for the other three Nordic countries. The Sharpe ratio is computed using the average excess return for the monthly strategies, and its time-series standard deviation. The benefits of diversification for Finland are indicated by the average results in Panel A in Table 4. Only the Bayes-Stein strategy BST displays worse overall out-of-sample performance in terms of its Sharpe-ratio compared to the pure domestic portfolio FIN. The global minimum variance portfolio MVP has the best overall performance, followed by EQW World, CET 20, and EQW Nordic. This is consistent with Eun and Resnick (1988) who also find that the two dominating unhedged strategies are the equally weighted world index and the MVP strategy. The value weighted world market portfolio WORLD performs in turn rather badly. 21 The differences between the Sharpe-ratios was tested using the Jobson and Korkie (1981a) z-statistic (strategies against a 100% holding in domestic stocks), but no significant differences could be detected. The performance of the strategies was also tested separately for the two subperiods, and the short period of the float of the FIM, in Panels B to D. The performance of the MVP turned out to be quite robust, this strategy being always either the best or the second best strategy. Another observation from these subperiod studies is that the EQW Nordic was always almost as good as the EQW World (their Sharpe ratios differing only some points on the second decimals). A comparison of the weights (not reported here) for the Finnish investors certainty-equivalent tangency strategy CET, the minimum variance portfolio MVP, and the Bayes-Stein Tangency Strategy BST during the pre-float period and the float period reveal some rather large differences. Whereas during the pre-float period, Finland and Austria have large overall average weights of 31% and 24% in the MVP, the Netherlands obtains a high post-float weight of 63% on average. In general, besides an investment in the Finnish portfolio, of the Nordic countries only Denmark has a significant weight in the MVP. The BST strategy is the least diversified of the three strategies and obtains extreme weights in both subperiods. The results for unhedged strategies for the three other Nordic countries, reported in Table 5, are similar to those for Finland. In each case, MVP is the best strategy during the overall period, and among the two best strategies during all subperiods 22 but for Denmark, subperiod 2. Two other strategies which frequently occur among the two best are BST and EQW World. All these strategies
20 In fact, the performance of CET is surprisingly good. Several studies, such as those by Eun and Resnick (1984), Jofion (1985, 1986), and the domestic (U.S.) based simulations by Jobson and Korkie (1981b) found instead that CET does not perform especially well. 21 In light of results such as those in Harvey (1991), one would expect the value weighted world market portfolio to perform better. 22 Subperiod results for other Nordic countries are not reported here but can be obtained from the authors.
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
483
Table 4 Ex ante investment strategies for Finland Mean
Std. dev.
Sharpe ratio
Panel A. Sample period September CET 6.24 MVP 6.11 BST 2.70 EQW World 5.04 EQW Nordic 5.18 FIN 5.14 USA 4.91 WORLD 4.09
1979 - November 1993 19.17 0.33 14.10 0.43 23.92 0.11 15.46 0.33 17.35 0.30 21.12 0.24 19.5 l 0.25 16.25 0.25
Panel B. Sample period September CET 12.93 MVP 9.84 BST 4.78 EQW World 8.06 EQW Nordic 8.32 FIN 11.44 USA 5.79 WORLD 8.31
1979 December 1986 18.69 0.69 9.61 1.02 27.28 0.18 11.66 0.69 13.92 0.60 13.18 0.87 17.92 0.32 14.25 0.58
Panel C. Sample period January 1987 - November CE - 0.85 19.57 MVP 2.15 17.66 BST 0.51 19.90 EQW World 1.83 18.70 EQW Nordic 1.85 20.41 FIN - 1.54 27.08 USA 3.97 21.17 WORLD - 0.39 18.14 Panel D. Sample period September CET 33.26 MVP 38.37 B ST 41.54 EQW World 36.73 EQW Nordic 40.66 FIN 64.66 USA 34.50 WORLD 28.43
1993 - 0.04 0.12 0.03 0.10 0.09 - 0.06 0.19 - 0.02
1992 - November 1993 18.19 1.83 14.78 2.60 21.46 1.94 15.94 2.30 17.94 2.27 34.51 1.87 18.97 1.82 17.30 1.64
JK z-stat.
(prob.)
(I.286 0.803 - 0,420 0.286 0.228
(0.388) (0.211) (0.663) (0.387) (0.410)
0.024 0.026
(0.490) (0.490)
- 0.358 0.377 1.326 - 0.325 - 0.557
(0.640) (0.353) (0.908) (0.627) (0.711)
- 0.930 - 0.506
(0.824) (0.693)
0.034 0.520 0.203 0.392 0.472
(0.487) (0.302) (0.420) (0.347) (0.319)
0.525 0.084
(0.300) (0.467)
- 0.023 0.341 0.030 0.210 0.223
(0.509) (0.367) (0.488) (0.417) (0.412)
-0.028 - 0.125
(0.511) (0.550)
All returns are in excess of the 1-month domestic, in this case FIM interest rate (for interest rate data, see Appendix A). CET is the Certainty Equivalent Tangency portfolio, MVP the Minimum Variance Portfolio, and BST the Bayes-Stein estimation risk adjusted strategy. 60 previous months are used in estimating mean returns and the covariance matrix. EQW World and EQW Nordic stand for equally weighted portfolios of all 18 countries and 4 Nordic countries, respectively. FIN and USA represents 100% investment in Finland and the U.S., respectively. WORLD is the Morgan Stanley value-weighted world equity index return. Jobson-Korkie z-statistic (p-value in parentheses) tests the difference between Sharpe ratios for each strategy against 100% local stock market investment in Finland.
484
E. Liljeblom et al. /Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
Table 5 Ex ante investment strategies, the other Nordic countries Mean Panel A. Denmark, CET MVP BST EQW World EQW Nordic DEN USA WORLD
Std. dev.
September 1979 - November 6.94 18.12 6.84 13.77 7.74 18.83 6.25 15.45 6.40 18.26 5.87 19.09 6.12 19.43 5.30 16.43
Sharpe ratio 1993 0.38 0.50 0.41 0.40 0.35 0.31 0.32 0.32
Panel B. Norway, September 1979 - November 1993 CET 4.68 17.84 0.26 MVP 3.72 13.13 0.28 BST 3.71 22.44 0.17 EQW World 3.68 14.41 0.26 EQW Nordic 3.82 16.71 0.23 NOR 0.13 32.23 0.00 USA 3.55 18.51 0.19 WORLD 2.73 15.49 0. ! 8 Panel C. Sweden, September 1979 - November 1993 CET 7.91 17.47 0.45 MVP 8.58 14.61 0.59 BST 8.94 17.31 0.52 EQW World 7.50 15.14 0.50 EQW Nordic 7.65 17.79 0.43 SWE 11.90 23.89 0.50 USA 7.37 19.22 0.38 WORLD 6.55 16.34 0.40
JK z-stat.
(prob.)
0.297 0.744 0.413 0.361 0.179
(0.383) (0.229) (0.340) (0.359) (0.429)
0.024 0.052
(0.490) (0.479)
0.890 0.958 0.520 0.986 1.169
(0.187) (0.169) (0.301) (0.162) (0.121)
0.634 0.588
(0.263) (0.278)
- 0.178 0.359 0.070 - 0.011 - 0.331
(0.571 ) (0.360) (0.472) (0.504) (0.630)
- 0.401 - 0.374
(0.656) (0.646)
All returns are in excess of the 1-month domestic interest rate (for interest rate data, see Appendix A). CET is the Certainty Equivalent Tangency portfolio, MVP the Minimum Variance Portfolio, and BST the Bayes-Stein estimation risk adjusted strategy. 60 previous months are used in estimating mean returns and the covariance matrix. EQW World and EQW Nordic stand for equally weighted portfolios of all 18 countries and 4 Nordic countries, respectively. DEN, NOR, SWE, and USA represent 100% investment in Denmark, Norway, Sweden, or the U.S. WORLD is the Morgan Stanley value-weighted world equity index return. Jobson-Korkie z-statistic (p-value in parentheses) tests the difference between Sharpe ratios for each strategy against 100% local stock market investment in the domestic country. are, h o w e v e r , s e l d o m s i g n i f i c a n t l y b e t t e r t h a n t h e d o m e s t i c p o r t f o l i o a c c o r d i n g to the Jobson-Korkie
z - s t a t i s t i c . 23
T h e r e s u l t s f o r s t r a t e g i e s h e d g e d f o r e x c h a n g e r a t e r i s k a r e r e p o r t e d in T a b l e 6.
23 However, rejections do occur at the 10% level for Denmark, the 1979-86 subperiod (MVP and EQW World) and for Norway (MVP, EQW World, and EQW Nordic), in the same subperiod.
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal o f Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 4 6 9 - 4 9 0
485
Since we investigate excess returns in domestic currency for fully hedged strategies, the results corresponds to an analysis based on data for local excess returns for the 18 countries. 24 Therefore, all the hedged strategies yield identical results in terms of means, volatilities, and Sharpe ratios for all the four countries. Only Jobson-Korkie Sharpe Ratio tests differ due to different comparison portfolios (the domestic ones) in each country. Since few significant values were detected, the Jobson-Korkie z-statistic is not reported in Table 6. 25 Missing from Table 6 is also the value-weighted world market portfolio WORLD. 26 The results concerning hedging are somewhat mixed. In Norway, hedging would generally (during both subperiods) have been beneficial. Also for Finland, the best strategy during the 1979-86 and 1987-93 subperiods can be found among the hedged ones. 27 Also for Denmark hedged strategies dominate unhedged ones in the 1987-93 subperiod. However, unhedged strategies generally dominate (with one exception, USAH subperiod 2) their hedged counterparts in the case of Sweden (both subperiods) and for Denmark (subperiod 1977-86). During the 1987-93 subperiod a 100% investment in U.S. equities with currency hedging would have been optimal for all Nordic investors. With hedged strategies included, the dominance of minimum variance portfolio (either MVP or MVPH) is somewhat less obvious. However, whenever strategies significantly better than the domestic portfolio are detected, the best strategy among the significant ones is always either MVP or MVPH. In this section, the ex post performance of ex ante strategies was investigated. In line with previous research, the historical minimum variance portfolio MVP stands out as one of the best strategies, especially among unhedged alternatives. Surprisingly, the value weighted world market portfolio, which includes 18 countries but admittedly may suffer in stability from not being equally weighted, is outperformed by an equally weighted Nordic index of only four countries. The
24 The domestic hedged total return was defined as Ri.aom = R i + fi. In logarithmic terms, the tbrward premium is defined as f i = In(F) - In(S), which in turn is, due to covered interest parity, equal to the interest rate differential rdom -- rfor. The hedged total return will then be Ri.dom = R i + rdom -- rfor, and the hedged excess return Ri.dom = ( R i + rdom -- rfor)-- rdom, which is identical to the local excess return. 25 Hedged portfolios with Sharpe-ratios significantly (at the 10% level) better than the domestic portfolio were detected in the following cases: Denmark, subperiod 1 (MVPH), Norway, complete time period (MVPH, EQW World H, EQW Nordic H, USAH), and Norway, subperiod 1 (MVPH, EQW World H, EQW Nordic H). 26 Since we do not have monthly Morgan-Stanley world market weights, we do not attempt to compute a hedged return for the value-weighted world market portfolio WORLD. 27 Within the groups of unhedged vs. hedged strategies, the best strategies for 1977-86 subperiod are MVP and MVPH, and for the 1987-93 subperiod USA and USAH. In each case, the hedged version dominates its unhedged counterpart. However, during the float, the unhedged MVP is best due to the post-float depreciation of the Finnish markka.
486
E. Liljeblom et aL / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
Table 6 Results from hedged (H) strategies for four Nordic countries Std. dev.
Sharpe ratio
Panel A. September 1979 - November 1993 CETH 5.72 MVPH 4.78 BSTH 6.54 EQW World H 5.75 EQW Nordic H 5.78 USAH 5.85
Mean
17.32 12.70 20.15 14.02 17.02 15.45
0.33 0.38 0.32 0.41 0.34 0.38
Sharpe ratios, comparison portfolios: 100% Domestic hedged MVP (unhedged)
DEN 0.31 0.50
NOR 0.00 0.28
FIN 0.24 0.43
Panel B. September 1979 - December 1986 CETH 10.68 MVPH 10.85 BSTH 10.16 EQW World H 10.38 EQW Nordic H 10.81 USAH 5.39
15.79 8.75 22.34 10.56 13.20 14.76
0.68 1.24 0.45 0.98 0.82 0.37
Sharpe ratios, comparison portfolios: 100% Domestic hedged MVP (unhedged)
NOR 0.06 0.88
FIN 0.87 1.02
Panel C. January 1987 - November 1993 CETH 0.46 MVPH - 1.64 BSTH 2.71 EQW World H 0.85 EQW Nordic H 0.44 USAH 6.34
18.78 15.70 17.59 16.90 20.27 16.25
0.02 -0.10 0.15 0.05 0.02 0.39
Sharpe ratios, comparison portfolios: 100% Domestic hedged MVP (unhedged)
NOR - 0.07 - 0.07
FIN - 0.06 0.12
D. September 1992 - November 1993 (the float of FIM) CETH 28.99 MVPH 12.56 BSTH 29.40 EQW World H 22.60 EQW Nordic H 34.44 USAH 8.24
13.90 9.29 13.83 10.19 17.30 4.43
2.08 1.35 2.13 2.22 1.99 1.86
Sharpe ratios, comparison portfolios: 100% Domestic hedged MVP (unhedged)
NOR 1.58 2.45
FIN 1.87 2.60
DEN 0.47 1.50
DEN 0.16 - 0.04
DEN 0.58 1.28
SWE 0.50 0.59
SWE 1.04 1.34
SWE 0.08 0.15
SWE 1.34 2.67
E. Liljeblom et al./ Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
487
EQW Nordic was in fact very close to the EQW World during different subperiods. Moreover, this result is not likely to be a consequence of exchange rate risk, since the analysis in section three indicated that currency risk generally did not contribute much to the overall portfolio risk for the Nordic countries. These results therefore support intra-Nordic diversification as a first step on the way towards a more diversified portfolio.
6. Summary and conclusions In this paper, we study the magnitude of the benefits from international diversification from a Nordic point of view. Since it is likely that the co-movement of stock markets have increased towards the end of the 1980s, while simultaneously exchange rates for the Nordic countries have become more volatile, it is of interest to investigate whether the relative benefits from unhedged international diversification for these countries would have been reduced. Two subperiods, 1974-86 and 1987-1993 are separately investigated. A special focus is directed towards the period during which the FIM has floated. We present preliminary evidence of how the relative magnitudes of the different risks (local stock market risk, and exchange rate risk) have changed after the float, and investigate the performance of international diversification strategies, both hedged as well as unhedged, prior to and after the float of FIM. We find significant increases in stock market co-movement, only in two cases out of 153 has the pairwise correlation coefficient between two stock market indexes (measured in local currency) been reduced over time. Also the co-movement of foreign currencies has significantly increased for Nordic countries. However, also some weaker evidence of increased stock market volatility was obtained. The results of ex post as well as ex ante strategies indicate generally substantial benefits from international diversification for the Nordic countries. The benefits are, in a relative sense, even larger during the latter subperiod. While the value weighted world market portfolio does not demonstrate any especially good performance in the ex ante unhedged strategies, equally weighted World and Nordic indexes do rather well, and the global minimum variance strategy MVP shows the overall best performance. The results concerning hedging are somewhat mixed. For Norwegian, Finnish and Danish investors hedging would generally have been beneficial especially in
Notes to Table 6:All returns are in excess of the l-month domestic interest rate (for interest rate data, see Appendix A). CETH is the Certainty Equivalent Tangency portfolio, MVPH the Minimum Variance Portfolio, and BSTH the Bayes-Stein estimation risk adjusted hedged strategy. 60 previous months are used in estimating mean returns and the covariance matrix. EQW World H and EQW Nordic H stand for equally weighted hedged portfolios of all 18 countries and 4 Nordic countries, respectively, and USAH for a hedged 100% investment in the U.S.
488
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
the 1987-93 subperiod, while the case is the opposite for Sweden and Denmark, subperiod 1979-86. With hedged strategies included, the dominance of minimum variance portfolio is somewhat less obvious. However, whenever strategies significantly better than the domestic portfolio are detected, the best strategy among the significant ones is always the minimum variance portfolio in its hedged or unhedged form. All in all, our results indicate substantial benefits from international diversification for the Nordic countries in spite of significantly increased stock market covariance.
Acknowledgements We are grateful for comments received at the 2nd Annual Conference on Multinational Financial Issues in Philadelphia, the AFFI 1995 Conference in Finance, the FIBE Conference at the Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration, the European Finance Association Annual Meeting in Oslo, seminars at the University of Gothenburg, the Stockholm School of Economics, and the Swedish School of Economics and Business Administration. The paper has much benefited from the comments of two anonymous referees. Financial support from Osuuspankkiryhm~in tutkimuss~i~itii5 and the Finnish Academy of Sciences is gratefully acknowledged.
Appendix A. The interest rates used Interest rates are utilized in this study first of all for the computation of excess returns from the perspective of each of the four Nordic countries. Secondly, interest rates are needed for the money market hedge. We use for both purposes short-term interest rates, preferably 1 month interest rates, for the 18 currencies for the time period 1973-93. If monthly interest rates have not been obtained, the closest possible maturity has been used, and the interest rates are transferred to the monthly level assuming a flat short-end term structure. The interest rates are month-end interest rates, so the money market hedge for a monthly holding period of t + 1 is based on the month-end interest rate for the previous period t. The interest rates are obtained from OECD:s Main Economic Indicators (OECD), from the Bank of Finland (BoF), from the Bank of Norway (BoN), and the Research Institute of the Finnish Economy (ETLA). The interest rates (and their sources, in brackets) are: Austria - Official discount rate 1973-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Australia - 90 days commercial bills 1973-1988 (OECD), Short term money market rate 1989-1993 (ETLA); Belgium - 3month-Treasury bill rate 1973-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Canada - 3-month Treasury bill rate 1973-1990:02 (OECD until 1988, then ETLA), 1-month Eurorate 1990:03-1993 (BoF); Denmark - Official discount rate
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
489
1973-1988 (OECD), l-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Finland - Implicit FIM Eurorate (computed from F I M / U S D forward rates assuming covered interest parity) 1973-1986 (BoF), 1-month HELIBOR, i.e. interbank rate 1987-1993 (BoF); France - 3-month interbank rate 1973-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Germany - Frankfurt rate on 3-month loans 1973-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Hong Kong - U.S. 3-month Treasury bill rate 1973-1991:03 (OECD and ETLA), HKD Eurorate 1991:04-1993 (ETLA); Italy - Yield on long-term gvm bonds 1973-1975 (OECD), 6-month Treasury bill rate 1976-1988 (OECD), l-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Japan - Call money rate 1973-1977 (OECD), 3-month Gensaki rate 1977-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Netherlands - Rate on 3-month loans to local authorities 1973-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Norway - Implicit NOK Eurorate (computed from forward rates) 1973-1988:02 (BoN), 3-month interbank rate 1988:03-1988:12 (BoN), l-month Eurorate 19891993 (BoF); Spain - Official discount rate 1973:01-1973:05 (OECD), Call money rate 1973:06-1976 (OECD), Rate on 3-month loans 1977-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); Sweden - Official discount rate 1973-1981 (OECD), Rate on 3-month Treasury discount notes 1982-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate ! 989-1993 (BoF); Switzerland - ZUrich 3-month deposit rate 1973-1988 (OECD), l-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); United Kingdom - 3-month Treasury bill rate 1973-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF); United States 3-month Treasury bill rate 1973-1988 (OECD), 1-month Eurorate 1989-1993 (BoF).
References Arshanapalli,B. and J. Doukas, 1993, Internationalstock market linkages:Evidencefrom the pre- and post-October 1987 period, Journal of Banking and Finance 17, 193-208. Bertero, E. and C. Mayer, 1990, Structure and performance:Global interdependenceof stock markets around the crash of October 1987, European EconomicReview 34, 1155-1180. Eun, C.S. and B.G. Resnick, 1984, Estimatingthe correlation structure of internationalshare prices, Journal of Finance 39, 1311-1324. Eun, C.S. and B.G. Resnick, 1988, Exchange rate uncertainty,forward contracts, and international portfolio selection,Journal of Finance 43, 197-215. Eun, C.S. and B.G. Resnick, 1994, Internationaldiversificationof investment portfolios: U.S. and Japanese perspectives, ManagementScience40, 140-161. Ferson, W.E. and C.R. Harvey, 1994, Sources of risk and expected returns in global equity markets, Journal of Bankingand Finance 18, 775-803. Grauer, R.R. and N.H. Hakansson, 1987, Gains from internationaldiversification:1968-85 Returnson portfolios of stocks and bonds, Journal of Finance42, 721-741. Grubel, H., 1968, Internationallydiversified portfolios: Welfare gains and capital flows, American Economic Review 58, 1299-1314. Haavisto E., 1989, Kansainv~,ilistenosakesijoitusten mahdollisuudet, KOP Taloudellinen katsaus, 21-29. Haavisto, T. and B. Hansson, 1992, Risk reduction by diversificationin the Nordic stock markets, ScandinavianJournal of Economics 94, 581-588.
490
E. Liljeblom et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 469-490
Harvey, C.R., 1991, The world price of covariance risk, Journal of Finance 46, 111-157. Jennrich, R.I., 1970, An asymptotic X 2 test for the equality of two correlation matrices, Journal of the American Statistical Association 65, 904-912. Jeon, B.N. and M. von Furstenberg, 1990, Growing international co-movement in stock price indexes, Quarterly Review of Economics and Business 30, 15-30. Jobson, J.D. and B. Korkie, 1981a, Performance hypothesis testing with the Sharpe and Treynor measures, Journal of Finance 36, 889-908. Jobson, J.D. and B. Korkie, 1981b, Putting Markowitz theory to work, Journal of Portfolio Management 7, 70-74. Jofion, P., 1985, International portfolio diversification with estimation risk, Journal of Business 58, 259-278. Jorion, P., 1986, Bayes-Stein estimation for portfolio analysis, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 21,279-92. Jorion, P., 1989, Asset allocation with hedged and unhedged foreign stocks and bonds, Journal of Portfolio Management, 49-54. Jorion, P., 1991, Currency hedging for international portfolios, Columbia University working paper, 1-22.
Le, S.V., 1991, International investment diversification before and after the October 19, 1987 stock market crisis, Journal of Business Research 22, 305-310. Lessard. D., 1973, International portfolio diversification: Multivariate analysis for a group of Latin American countries, Journal of Finance 28, 619-33. Lessard, D., 1976, World, country, and industry relationships in equity returns: Implications for risk reduction through international diversification, Financial Analysts Journal 32, 32-38. Levy, H. and M. Sarnat, 1970, International diversification of investment portfolios, American Economic Review 60, 668-75. Levy, H. and K.C. Lim, 1994, Forward exchange bias, hedging and the gains from international diversification of investment portfolios, Journal of International Money and Finance 13, 159-170. Logue, D., 1982, An experiment on international diversification, Journal of Portfolio Management 9, 22-27. Longin, F. and B. Solnik, 1995, Is the correlation in international equity returns constant: 1960-90?, Journal of International Money and Finance 14, 3-26. Solnik, B., 1974, Why not diversify internationally?, Financial Analysts Journal 20, 48-54. Solnik, B. and B. Noetzlin, 1982, Optimal international asset allocation, Journal of Portfolio Management 9, 11-21.