The demand of liquid assets with uncertain lumpy expenditures

The demand of liquid assets with uncertain lumpy expenditures

Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Monetary Economics journal homepage: www.elsevi...

647KB Sizes 0 Downloads 62 Views

Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Monetary Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jme

The demand of liquid assets with uncertain lumpy expenditures Fernando Alvarez a, Francesco Lippi b,n a b

University of Chicago, United States University of Sassari and Einaudi Institute for Economic and Finance (EIEF), Italy

a r t i c l e i n f o

abstract

Article history: Received 27 March 2012 Received in revised form 23 May 2013 Accepted 31 May 2013 Available online 15 June 2013

We consider an inventory model for a liquid asset where the per-period net expenditures have two components: one that is frequent and small and another that is infrequent and large. We give a theoretical characterization of the optimal management of liquid asset as well as of the implied observable statistics. We use our characterization to interpret some aspects of households' currency management in Austria, as well as the management of demand deposits by a large sample of Italian investors. & 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Money demand Liquid assets Lumpy purchases Inventory theory

1. Introduction This paper studies some implications of uncertain lumpy purchases for the management of liquid assets in the context of inventory theoretical models. By lumpy purchases we mean large-sized expenditures that must be paid with a liquid asset. The paper accomplishes three objectives. First, it shows that some of the theoretical predictions of this problem are in stark contrast compared to those of canonical inventory models. In particular, a novel feature introduced by the lumpy purchases is the possibility that liquidity gets withdrawn and spent immediately. This feature changes the relationship between the size of liquidity withdrawals and the average liquidity holdings compared to canonical models. Equivalently, this affects the relationship between the average cash holdings and its “scale variable”, e.g. the average expenditures in a period. Second, our analysis of the optimal policy breaks some new ground on the mathematical analysis of inventory models, as the solution of the model with jumps turns out to be non-trivial. For instance, we show that the standard boundary conditions used to characterize the optimal policy are necessary but not sufficient, for an optimum. Third, the paper brings new evidence to bear on the model predictions concerning households' liquidity management. We use two novel datasets of Austrian and Italian households to summarize the main patterns in the data concerning the management of currency and of broader liquid assets. We show that our model can explain some empirical regularities that traditional models cannot account for. Although this paper focuses on households, mostly because of data availability, our model has clear implications for the management of liquid assets by firms, and reserve management by banks, which we discuss in the concluding section. The standard inventory model solves the problem of an agent trading off the holding cost of an inventory with the cost of adjusting the inventory. In simple models the inventories are assumed to be needed to finance an exogenous consumption flow (for households), or net sales (for firms). These models are typically set up in continuous time and the uncontrolled dynamics of inventories is described by a process with continuous paths. The classic examples of this set up when applied to households are Baumol (1952), Tobin (1956), where the process describes the household's consumption that needs to be n

Corresponding author. Tel.: +390647924836. E-mail address: [email protected] (F. Lippi).

0304-3932/$ - see front matter & 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2013.05.008

754

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

paid with currency. When applied to firms, as in Miller and Orr (1966), the process is the firm's net cash revenue. In this case one cost of the inventory is the low return of the liquid asset. This paper studies the implications for cash-management of having lumpy uncertain purchases: thus we explore the consequences of departing from the assumption that net cash consumption has continuous paths, allowing the unregulated inventories to follow a jump process. The ideas in this paper can be sketched in the context of a simple model. Suppose that in each period the agent must finance a consumption in cash of size c per unit of time and also that with a probability κ per unit of time the agent must make a cash payment of size z. In this case the expected consumption to be financed with cash is e ¼ c þ κz per unit of time. One strategy for the agent is to withdraw enough money so that, at least if this happens soon after the time of the withdrawal, all payments can be financed with the cash at hand. This strategy has the advantage of saving on the adjustment cost, but it has the disadvantage of incurring a holding cost on the inventory of cash. The inventory cost increases with the purchase size z, since the agent has to withdraw more money. An alternative strategy is to withdraw money when the purchase z happens. This strategy saves in holding cost, since the agent spends the money right away, but it involves paying the adjustment cost more frequently. This strategy is preferred when the probability κ is small. Thus, as the size of the large purchases z increases, and/or as they become infrequent (κ small), the optimal policy is to withdraw every time a large purchase occurs. In this simple extreme case the expected value of large purchases κz has no effect on the average cash holdings (M). The size of the withdrawal (W), when triggered by a large purchase, increases by the amount of this purchase, and an amount z of cash is spent immediately. These results, in some sense, turn the logic of the classical inventory model up-side down: cash is not spent slowly and adjustment is not triggered by the crossing of some sS bands. Instead, it is the arrival of a large purchase that triggers an adjustment and a simultaneous withdrawal and large use of cash. While κz has no effect on the average cash holdings, its magnitude affects the average size of withdrawals, and hence W/M is increasing in κz. The high value of W/M also implies that the number of withdrawals per unit of time n is small relative to the benchmark of the Baumol–Tobin model for an agent financing the same consumption e. The economics is simple: the withdrawals that are triggered by large purchases account for a large share of cash expenditures e and contribute nothing to average money holdings. Additionally, if every random large expenditures triggers a withdrawal, agents on average hold cash at the time of withdrawals, a behavior that can be described as “precautionary” and which is clearly apparent in the data. There is a large literature on inventory models applied to liquid assets. Most of the literature assumes that the cumulated net cash consumption has continuous path, hence not allowing for lumpy purchases or sales. Examples are Baumol (1952), Tobin (1956), Miller and Orr (1966) among many others.1 One exception is the work by Bar-Ilan et al. (2004). The set up of that paper includes lumpy purchases and sales using a more general specification than the one in this paper. They compute the value of selected policies, but do not characterize the nature of the optimal decision rules. In this paper, instead, we give a characterization of the optimal policy which, from the technical point is view, is not a trivial matter since it has to address two issues: (i) the form of the inaction set, i.e. whether it is a single interval or the union of disjoint ones; and (ii) whether the necessary boundary conditions are also sufficient, which turns out not to be the case for this problem. Additionally, the focus of our paper is different, we concentrate on the implications for the cash management statistics and on the differences with standard models. We present two empirical applications of our model. The first one uses two surveys on currency management, from Italian and Austrian households. Both surveys contain information on the patterns of cash management: the average consumption paid with cash per period e, the average cash holdings M, average withdrawal size W, average number of withdrawals per unit of time n, and average cash holdings at the time of withdrawal M. Besides that, the Austrian dataset contains information on the patterns of purchase size, recorded in a consumption diary held by the same individuals to whom the survey was administered (see the description in Mooslechner et al., 2006). The diary data show that, for a non-negligible fraction of individuals, the assumption that large purchases are paid in currency is realistic. We use the diary and survey information to investigate some of the predictions of our model by comparing individuals that differ in the importance of the lumpy component of their expenditures paid with currency. In Section 4.1 we present evidence on several statistics, such as the frequency and size of withdrawal relative to the average currency holdings, that is supportive of the mechanism highlighted in the model. The second application, in Section 4.2, focuses on a broader liquid asset, close to M2, using data from a sample of Italian customers of a large commercial bank described in Alvarez et al. (2012). We argue that accounting for the lumpy nature of purchases, as in the case of e.g. durable purchases, seems important to understand the management of liquid assets. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the main idea of the paper using a simple deterministic model. A stochastic version of the model is discussed in Section 3, where various specifications are explored. Section 4 illustrates two empirical applications of the model. Section 5 has conclusions and directions for future research.

2. A deterministic model with lumpy purchases This section develops a simple version of the Baumol–Tobin (BT) model where the consumption paid in cash has two deterministic components, one continuous at the rate c per unit of time and the other discontinuous, with jumps of size z, 1 Other examples are Eppen and Fama (1969), Constantinides (1978), Constantinides and Richard (1978), Frenkel and Jovanovic (1980), Harrison et al. (1983), Harrison and Taskar (1983), Bar-Ilan (1990), Duffie and Sun (1990), Abel et al. (2007), Baccarin (2009), Bensoussan et al. (2009), and Alvarez and Lippi (2009).

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

755

exactly every 1=κ periods of time. Thus, total consumption per unit of time is e≡c þ zκ, the sum of the cumulative consumption at the rate c plus the κ jumps in consumption, each of them of size z. These jumps on the cash consumption in the model are meant to be a simple representation of the fact that households' purchases varies in size. The objective function, as in BT, is to minimize the cost V given by V ¼ RM þ bn where M is the average cash balances, R is the opportunity cost of the cash balances, n is the number of withdrawals per unit of time, and b is the fixed cost paid for each withdrawal. It turns out that the optimal policy is of one of three types, depending on parameters. When κ is small, the agent withdraws every 1=ðiκÞ units of time, where i≥1. In this case, there are i withdrawals between jumps in cumulative consumption, and n 4κ. One of the withdrawals will happen just before the jump z, and hence financing the discontinuous part of consumption is done at no cost. If κ is large, the agent makes a withdrawal every j=κ units of time, where j≥1. In this case there are j jumps in cumulated consumption between successive withdrawals, or n oκ. Thus the agent will only “save” on the opportunity cost of the associated consumption z once every j jumps between withdrawals. For intermediate values of κ, withdrawals happen exactly every 1=κ periods of time, or n ¼ κ. We define two thresholds κ and κðzÞ, which determine the patterns of cash management: qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi rffiffiffiffiffiffi Rz þ ðRzÞ2 þ 8bRc Rc κ≡ : ≤κðzÞ≡ 2b 4b Note that κ ¼ κ ð0Þ and that κ is strictly increasing in z. To simplify the description we will assume that a certain combination of parameters takes on integer values. Define u as follows: (rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi) Rc κ2 2b : u≡max ; 2 Rðc þ κzÞ 2bκ For the description of the optimal policy we let W be the average withdrawal size, so W/M is the ratio of average withdrawal to average stock of money. We have Proposition 1. Assume that if u 41, then u is an integer. Then the optimal decision rules and the value of the objective function V are given by rffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Rc W=M c þ κz If κ o κ : n ¼ ¼ ; and V ¼ 2Rbc; 4 κ; 2b 2 c W=M c þ κz Rc If κ ≤κ ≤κðzÞ : n ¼ κ; ¼ and V ¼ þ bκ; 2 c 2 rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Rz Rðc þ zκÞ W=M c þ κz If κ 4 κðzÞ : n ¼ ¼ and V ¼ 2Rbðc þ κzÞ− : o κ; 2b 2 c þ zðκ−nÞ 2 Using the accounting identity Wn ¼ c þ κz and the expressions in the proposition one can find the values of W and M separately. The interpretation of this proposition is as follows: when κ is small relative to what determines the frequency of withdrawals in BT, then the jumps can be made coincide with one of the many withdrawals. In this case, the agent will withdraw the extra amount z and spend it immediately. Thus the cash expenditure associated with the jump does not incur into any opportunity cost since that cash is held only for an instant. Also, the agent does not incur any extra fixed cost b, since it has to withdraw to finance the continuous expenditure anyway. As a consequence, the decision for the agent on the number of withdrawals n is exactly as in BT, but it is as if the consumption to be financed is c, instead of c þ κz. This can be seen from the expression for n and V. The expression for W/M is larger than 2, since at the time of a jump in consumption the agent withdraws an extra amount z, which is spent immediately and does not contribute to the average money holdings M. On the other hand, consider the case where κ is large, so that the agent will like to withdraw several times between jumps. In this case, only the first of the jump, the one that occurs immediately after a withdrawal will have no opportunity cost associated with it. Otherwise, the decisions are as if the agent has to finance c þ κz in the BT model. This can be seen in the expression for n, which is the same as in BT, and in the one for V, which is identical, except that it subtracts the “savings” in the opportunity cost for one jump per period. The ratio of W/M depends on how large this jumps are, i.e. on z. The following extreme case may help to understand the model for large κ. Assume that κ is very large, but z is very small, so there are very frequent jumps of small size, keeping the product zκ ¼ γ positive and finite. As the jumps become very small, the model is identical to BT, with total consumption c þ κz. This can be seen in the case where κ 4κðzÞ, and taken the limit to z to zero. We now develop comparison pthe ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ffi with BT in detail. Let us denote by nBT ¼ Rðc þ zκÞ=ð2bÞ the optimal decision if one were to measure the total cash consumption c þ zκ and assume that it is continuous as in BT. Also we recall that in BT the ratio W=M ¼ 2 since cash consumption is constant per unit of time (z ¼0). We then compute two ratios, n=nBT and ðW=MÞ=2, as functions of κ. These are useful to compare the prediction with BT. We have rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi n c W=M c þ κz ; ¼ ; If κ ≤κ ⇒ ¼ nBT c þ κz 2 c sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi n κ2 2b W=M c þ κz ≤1; ¼ ; If κ oκ o κðzÞ⇒ ¼ nBT Rðc þ κzÞ 2 c

756

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

If κ≥κ ðzÞ⇒

n ¼ 1; nBT

1≤

W=M c þ κz c þ κz qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi o ¼ : 2 c RðcþκzÞ c þ κz−z 2b

Notice that in terms of the statistics W/M and n=nBT the implications of the model when κ oκ depend only the value of zκ, and not separately on κ and z, a feature that will be shared by the model in Section 3.2.1. There are two extreme cases that are useful to highlight. Keeping the product zκ ¼ γ 4 0, strictly positive and finite, we have lim nnBT ¼ 1;

k→∞

n ¼ k→0 nBT

lim

lim W=M ¼1 2

k→∞

rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi c ; cþγ

lim k→0

W=M cþγ ¼ : 2 c

The first line describes the case of an economy in which all consumption is continuous (i.e. no jumps ever occur). In this case the model coincides with BT. The second line describes the limiting case of an economy in which the lumpy expenditures is concentrated in a single jump (the probability of a jump per unit of time is thus zero). In this case the number of withdrawal is smaller, and the W/M ratio higher, than in BT. Finally, note that the money demand M as function of R=b, the interest rate relative to the fixed cost, is decreasing (keeping the other parameters c; κ; z fixed). The shape of the money demand as a function of R=b depends on the value of the interest rates. For this purpose we divide the values of the interest rates R=b into three segments, using two cut-off points defined as follows: RðκÞ solves κ ¼ κðRÞ and Rðκ; zÞ solves κ ¼ κðR; zÞ, where κ and κ are the thresholds defined above, which we now write as functions of the interest rate. Since κðRÞ o κðRÞ, and since both are increasing in R, starting at 0 and going to ∞, the thresholds RðκÞ oRðκÞ are well defined and are both decreasing in κ, and R is decreasing in z. Using these thresholds, Proposition 1, and the accounting identity Wn ¼ c þ κz we have 8 1 1 zn > > if 0 o R oRðκ; zÞ > where n o κ >− − ∂ log M < 2 2 c þ zðκ−nÞ ð1Þ ¼ 0 if Rðκ; zÞ o R oRðκÞ where n ¼ κ > ∂ log R > > > :−1 if RðκÞ o R where n 4 κ 2

Thus the elasticity of the money demand is non-monotone on R. For small values of R is more elastic than 1/2, for intermediate values it is inelastic, and for high values of R the elasticity is 1/2. 3. A stochastic model We consider a model where consumption has three components: one is deterministic at a constant rate c per unit of time, – as in our previous model. The second component represent large purchases: we assume that the jump process occurs with probability κ per unit of time, and that when it happens cumulated consumption increases by an amount given by the parameter z 40. With this parameterization, expected consumption per period, say per year, equals e ¼ c þ κz. The third component introduces random variation in the net cash consumption, with variance s2 per unit of time. This is to capture, as in the seminal model of cash management of firms by Miller and Orr (1966), income that is received in cash, a feature that is mostly associated with firms' cash flows. Moreover this gives rise to cash deposits as well as withdrawals. If we denote cumulative consumption paid in cash by C(t) we assume that dCðtÞ ¼ cdt þ zdN þ sdB, where N(t) is the poisson counter, and B(t) is an standard Brownian motion. If we interpret dC as the consumption during a period of length dt, we note that, when s 40, it can be negative. We also assume that with a Poisson arrival rate p per unit of time, the agent has an opportunity to adjust her cash balances without paying the cost b. We introduce the free adjustment opportunities as a way to model the possibility of cash replenishment due to the ATM network, an feature that we have explored in Alvarez and Lippi (2009). The reason to include it here is that it shares some implications with the model with large purchases. Specifically, as shown below, that cash management data alone (such as frequency and size of withdrawals, average cash holdings, etc.) cannot identify separately p from κ. On the other hand, having data on the size distribution of cash purchases can help identify these parameters. The introduction of the large purchases is useful to explore the implications of an alternative reason for “precautionary” type of behavior. In this model, there are three types of withdrawals, those that occur when m reaches zero, those that occur at the time of a jump in consumption if m o z, and those that occur if the agent has a free withdrawal opportunity. The idea is that at times when cumulated consumption jumps (i.e. a large purchase occurs), if the money balances at hand m are not large enough to pay for the sudden increase in cash consumption, i.e. if m oz, then the agent will withdraw cash, even if cash has not reached zero. Otherwise, the nature of the optimal policy is the same, after withdrawal agents set their cash balances to the optimal replenishment level mn. The standard inventory model has unregulated inventory following a process with continuous paths.2 Yet there are several exceptions. Milbourne's (1983) model is set up in discrete time and makes no special assumptions about the process 2 If we let C be the cumulated unregulated process, we have that CðtÞ ¼ ct for constant c 4 0 as in Baumol (1952), Tobin (1956), Jovanovic (1982), Alvarez and Lippi (2009); or CðtÞ ¼ sBt for constant s 4 0 and Bt a standard BM in Miller and Orr (1966), Eppen and Fama (1969); or CðtÞ ¼ ct þ sBt for

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

757

for net cash-holdings. If we let C be the cumulated unregulated process, and we let N be the counter of a Poisson process, we have that dCðtÞ ¼ zdN from state dependent Fðx; zÞ in Song and Zipkin (1993) (where the state x is a finite Markov chain) and in Archibald and Silver (1978). A paper with a closely related, but more general, set up is Bar-Ilan et al. (2004), which u d assumes dCðtÞ ¼ μdt þ sdB þ zu dN −zd dN and where B is a standard Brownian motion, zi ≥0 are the up and down jumps, i and N are the counters of two Poisson processes with possible different constant intensities, and where the jump sizes have general distributions which include the exponential distribution. Their paper also has a more general adjustment cost, including fixed and variable cost, that differs for deposits and withdrawals, for which the authors present an analytical solution for the value of following a type of sS policy.3 We show below that solving the Bellman equation is more involved than in the standard case where the unregulated inventory (cash in this case) follows a process with continuous path. This requires to solve a delay-differential equation, as opposed to an ordinary differential equation. While in Section 3.1 we present an algorithm to solve for the parameters that fully characterize the Bellman equation, we do not have a simple closed form solution for the thresholds that describe the optimal policy ðmn ; mnn Þ, as we did for the case with no jumps in Alvarez and Lippi (2009). Of course if the jumps were small, i.e. if z was small, the statistics of interest would not be affected. In particular, we show that in the limit as z-0 while keeping κz constant, the model reduces to the one with continuous consumption. Thus, in Section 3.2.1 we will concentrate on the case of large but infrequent jumps, i.e. large z and small κ, which echoes the deterministic case of κ o κ. We will describe the nature of the optimal policy for this case, as well as the implications for several cash management statistics.

3.1. Bellman equation We consider a trigger policy described by two thresholds: mn, the value of cash after an adjustment, and mnn , the value of cash that triggers a deposit. Non-negativity of cash triggers a withdrawal at m ¼0. After a deposit or a withdrawal, agents return to the value mn, so that the size of a deposit is mnn −mn whereas, due to the consumption jumps and the free adjustment opportunities, withdrawals have a random size. The Bellman equation in the interior of the range of inaction, given by 0 om omnn , becomes     s2 ^ ^ rVðmÞ ¼ Rm þ p min VðmÞ−VðmÞ þ V″ðmÞ þ κ min b þ min VðmÞ−VðmÞ; Vðm−zÞ−VðmÞ þ V′ðmÞð−c−πmÞ ^ ^ 2 m m

^ where π is the inflation rate. The term min½b þ minm^ VðmÞ−VðmÞ; Vðm−zÞ−VðmÞ takes into account that after the jump in consumption the agent can decide to withdraw cash, or otherwise her cash balances becomes m−z. We let ^ mn ≡arg min VðmÞ; ^ m

and

V n ≡Vðmn Þ:

ð2Þ

If the value function is differentiable, we have that V′ðmn Þ ¼ 0:

ð3Þ

Non-negativity of cash implies that VðmÞ ¼ V n þ b

for m ≤0:

ð4Þ

For the range 0 ≤m ≤z we look for a solution of the form of an Ordinary Differential Equation (ODE): ðr þ p þ κÞVðmÞ ¼ Rm þ ðp þ κÞV n þ κb þ V′ðmÞð−c−πmÞ þ

s2 V″ðmÞ 2

ð5Þ

since in this range every jump triggers a withdrawal. This feature is as in Bar-Ilan et al. (2004), who refer to it as adjustment triggered by downcrosses. Instead for the range z ≤m ≤mnn , we have a Delay-Differential Equation (DDE): ðr þ p þ κÞVðmÞ ¼ Rm þ pV n þ κVðm−zÞ þ V′ðmÞð−c−πmÞ þ

s2 V″ðmÞ; 2

ð6Þ

(footnote continued) constants c; s 40: Constantinides and Richard (1978), Constantinides (1978), Frenkel and Jovanovic (1980), Harrison et al. (1983), Harrison and Taskar (1983), Bar-Ilan (1990), and dCðtÞ ¼ cðxÞ dt þ sðxÞ dB in Baccarin (2009). 3 Apparently unaware of this work, Sato and Suzuki (2011) have recently obtained a similar set of equations for value of following an sS policy. Davis et al. (2010) show the smoothness of the value function in a very general set-up.

758

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

since in this range after a jump cash balances are positive. If cash reaches the value of mnn , then it triggers a deposit of size mnn −mn after paying the fixed cost b. Thus we have Vðmnn Þ ¼ Vðmn Þ þ b

and

Vðmnn Þ ¼ VðmÞ

for all m≥mnn :

ð7Þ

If Vð  Þ is differentiable at m ¼ mnn , then we get that V′ðmnn Þ ¼ 0;

ð8Þ

a condition typically referred as to “smooth pasting”. We notice that, in general, it will not be differentiable at this point if s ¼ 0. We can further characterize the Bellman equation for V for given policy described by thresholds ðmn ; mnn Þ by splitting the range of inaction in intervals of length z. The idea is that, at a given point m, the value function depends on the local evolution around m and on the value that it will take after a jump, i.e. at m−z. But since cash is non-negative, for m∈½0; z any jump will lead to a withdrawal, and hence, given Vn, the value function only depends on its local evolution, i.e. it is a second order (first order if s ¼ 0) linear ODE described by Eq. (5). Then, given the solution of the value function in the lower segment, one can construct the segments corresponding to higher values of m recursively, which themselves solve a system of ODE's described by Eq. (6). In the case of π ¼ 0 the ODEs have constant coefficients. The value matching Eqs. (2), (4), and (7) provide three boundary conditions. The continuity of the level, first derivative (and second if s 4 0) across each segment, provide additional boundary conditions. Proposition 2. Assume π ¼ 0 and s≥0. Given two thresholds 0 omn o mnn the value of following such a policy, i.e. the solution of Eqs. (4)–(7), can be described by J functions Vj: Vðm; mn ; mnn Þ ¼ V j ðmÞ

for m∈½zj; minfzðj þ 1Þ; mnn g;

ð9Þ

where V j ðmÞ ¼ Aj þ Dj ðm−zjÞ þ ∑

j

∑ Bkj;i eλk ðm−zjÞ ðm−zjÞi

ð10Þ

k ¼ 1;2 i ¼ 0

where λk is a solution of r þ p þ κ ¼ −cλ þ ðs2 =2Þλ2 for k ¼1, 2 and where the constants Aj , Dj , Bkj;i for j ¼ 0; 1; 2; …; J−1, i ¼ 1; …; j, and k ¼1, 2 solve a block recursive system of linear equations described in the proof. Note that for s ¼ 0 there is only one root λ and hence one set of coefficients fBj;i g, together with fAj ; Dj g. Using Proposition 2 we can write the optimality of the return point equation (3) and the smooth pasting condition equation (8) as 0 ¼ V′ðmn ; mn ; mnn Þ ¼ Djn þ ∑

jn

∑ Bkjn ;i eλk ðm

n

−zjn Þ

k ¼ 1;2 i ¼ 0

0 ¼ V′ðmnn ; mn ; mnn Þ ¼ DJ−1 þ ∑

J−1

nn

∑ BkJ−1;i eλk ðm

k ¼ 1;2 i ¼ 0

½λk þ iðmn −zjn Þi−1;

−zðJ−1ÞÞ

½λk þ iðmnn −zðJ−1ÞÞi−1 ;

ð11Þ

ð12Þ

where jn is the smallest integer such that mn oðjn þ 1Þz, and where Eq. (12) applies only if s 40. Since Proposition 2 shows that, for the case of s 4 0 the constants fAj ; Dj ; Bkj;i g are a function of ðmn ; mnn Þ, we can regard Eqs. (11) and (12) as a system of two non-linear equations determining ðmn ; mnn Þ. Instead if s ¼ 0 the constant fAj ; Dj ; Bj;i g are a function of mn, so we can regard Eq. (11) as a one non-linear equation determining mn. Intuitively, when s ¼ 0 cash balances can only go down and cash deposits never occur, so that the threshold mnn drops out of the problem. The value function Vðm; mn ; mnn Þ is then simplified to Vðm; mn Þ, i.e. it is indexed by only 1 parameter (the optimal return point mn). Notice that for given arbitrary values of the thresholds ðmn ; mnn Þ a stochastic process for m is completely determined. Given this process, one can use straightforward computer simulations to derive the statistics of interest on the cash management, such as the frequency of withdrawals n, the average money holdings M, the withdrawal size W, the money holdings at the time of a withdrawal M, which will obviously depend of the chosen thresholds. The optimal values of ðmn ; mnn Þ have to satisfy two non-linear equations, namely Eqs. (11) and (12). The ultimate objective of course is to compare the statistics implied by the optimal policy with the same statistics from actual data, such as the ones discussed in Section 4. The one caveat, discussed below in Section 3.2.2, is that the conditions implied by Eqs. (11) and (12) are necessary but not sufficient, so that care must be taken in ensuring that the values that are chosen are the ones corresponding to a global minimum for the value function, and not just a local extreme. This can be done, for instance, by simple inspection of the known value function evaluated at a fixed value of m, e.g. mn, as a function of the ðmn ; mnn Þ thresholds, as we do in Fig. 1. Next we present a proposition showing that the limit of small and frequent jumps is the case with continuous consumption. Proposition 3. Consider the solution of the value function as z-0 and 0 o γ≡limz-0 z  κ o ∞. This solution coincides with the one without jumps, i.e. κ ¼ z ¼ 0 but with continuous consumption at the rate c þ γ. The logic of the proof of this proposition is straightforward, so we only sketch the argument here. First, notice that path for the cumulative consumption accounted for jumps zNðtÞ goes to γt with probability one. Second, notice that the

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

759

Fig. 1. Value function under policy threshold rule mn evaluated at m ¼ mn . The parameters for this problem are z ¼20, k ¼ 60, c¼ 365, p ¼15.

contribution of these jumps to the value function, given by κðVðm−zÞ−VðmÞÞ when m 4z can be written as κðVðmÞ− V′ðmÞz þ oðzÞÞ. Assuming that we can permute the limit of the derivative with the derivative of the limit, we obtain that in the limit the contribution of this term is −γV′ðmÞ, a term analogous to the contribution from c. The contribution of the segment m 4z is negligible as z goes to zero. This result can be useful to make contact with the data. The issue is not whether consumption transactions occur as discrete events or not, which of course they do. The previous result states that small frequent purchases can be approximated by the continuous model. The issue is whether the continuous consumption model is a good approximation given the observed size of purchases. Thus, if the purchases using cash are small and frequent, the model with a continuous path may be a good idealization. On the other hand, intuitively, a model with infrequent and large purchases, will be the most different case, a set up to which we will turn in Section 3.2.1. We briefly discuss the empirical counterparts and interpretations of the model with s 4 0 vs. s ¼ 0. Notice that for s ¼ 0 the model predicts no deposits and only withdrawals: the inaction region is given by ½0; mn , and cash inside this region only moves down, either at a constant rate per unit of time, or with jumps of size z and frequency κ. Consistent with this behavior notice that Table 1 shows that Italian households whose head is not self-employed make very few deposits relative to withdrawals: the average ratio of the number of deposits to the number of withdrawals is less than 10%, with a large fraction of households with exactly zero deposits. Thus for the non-self employed households a model with s ¼ 0, which generates the extreme case of no deposits, seems a reasonable approximation. In contrast, consider the statistics for the self-employed households, which appear in square brackets in the table. Their deposits are more frequent than for the rest of the households: the average ratio of number of deposits to the number of withdrawals of about 66%. The model with s 4 0 accounts for this fact. Moreover we think that it does so for the right reason: these households look like firms in the sense that their net cash consumption can be negative (i.e. they receive income in cash). We believe that this is the first empirical direct evidence on the prediction, implied by Miller and Orr (1966) models, that deposits are larger but less frequent than withdrawals. We finish this section with a brief comment on the optimality of the class of trigger policies considered here. First, in the case where s ¼ 0, it is easy to show that the ergodic distribution of m lies in ½0; mn , whose interior contains the inaction region. Second, in the case with no jumps (κ ¼ 0), s 40 and p ¼0, it has been shown by e.g. Constantinides and Richard (1978) that trigger policies of this type are optimal. The extension to the case of p 40 should be relatively straightforward. The third, more subtle, case is the combination of jumps (so that κ 40; z 4 0) and a Brownian motion (so that s 40) for cumulated net cash consumption. The potential complication comes about when there are discrete changes in the unregulated state, i.e. discrete changes in m in our case. This case has been studied in discrete time with finite but arbitrary horizon by Neave (1970). He showed that the decision rule will, in general, have an inaction region close to the optimal return point, that outside the inaction region there is a set of intervals where either adjustment or inaction is optimal, and that for large values there is an open ended interval for which adjustment is optimal. Bar-Ilan (1990) has also produced a counterexample in the case of two periods two jumps, one up and one down. More recently Chen and Simchi-Levi (2009)

760

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

Table 1 Currency management statistics in Italy and Austria. ATM Card Expenditure share paid w. currency Currency: M=e (e per day) M per household Currency at withdrawalsg: M =M Withdrawalh: W/M Withdrawal/depositj,j: W=D # of withdrawals: n (per year)k Normalized: n=nBT ¼ n=ðe=ð2MÞÞ (e per year)k # of deposits / # withdrawalsi: nD =n Fraction of households with W=M 42 Fraction of households with n=nBT ≡n=ðe=ð2MÞÞ o 1 # of observations

Italy (2002)

Austria (2005)

w/o w. w/o w. w/o w. w/o w. w/o w. w. w/o w/o w. w/o w. w. w/o w. w/o w.

a

0.65 0.52a 17c 13c 410e 330e 0.46 0.41 2.0 1.3 0.66 [0.66] 1.10 [0.99] 23 58 1.7 3.9 0.09 [0.66] 0.25 0.13 0.50 0.19

0.96b 0.73b 15d 15d 332f 206f 0.22 0.26 2.4 1.6 n.a. n.a. 21 68 1.4 5.4 n.a. 0.29 0.19 0.57 0.31

w/o w.

2275l 3729l

153m 895m

Entries are sample means. The unit of observation is the household for Italy; for Austria, the subject of the survey are men and women 14 years and older, not households. Only households with a checking account (both Austria and Italy) and whose head is not self-employed (Italy) are included, with the exception of data in square brackets ½  , which are computed only for households whose head is self-employed (approximately 17% of all households with a bank account). Notes for Italian data. Source: Bank of Italy – Survey of Household Income and Wealth. Notes for Austrian data. Source: Austrian National Bank – OeNB. a Ratio of expenditures paid with currency to total expenditures (durables, non-durables and services). b Numerator and denominator of the ratio are based on transactions collected in a diary kept for 7 days. The diary excludes automatic payments and likely misses large transactions (a broader measurement would produce smaller values for the ratio). c Average currency held by the household during the year divided by daily expenditures paid with currency. d Average currency carried by the individual (sum of currency with them and currency available at home; items 18 and 18a in questionnaire), divided by daily expenditures paid with currency. Respondents keep a large fraction of currency balances at home; The average of the ratio of currency at home to total currency held is about 60%. e In 2004 euros. f In 2005 euros. g Average currency at the time of withdrawal as a ratio to average currency. h Average withdrawal during the year as a ratio to average currency. i Sample average over 1993–2000. j Computed for households reporting D 4 0. k The entries with n¼0 are coded as missing values. l Number of respondents for whom the currency and the currency-consumption data are available in each survey. Data on withdrawals are supplied by a smaller number of respondents. m Number of respondents with a bank deposit account and non-zero values for M, W, e, n. This accounts for about 87% of the sample.

have a slightly fuller characterization of this case and an analysis of a more general case. Hence, the issue in our continuous time model with jumps, which make the model mathematically very close to a discrete time model, is whether there could be several inaction and adjustment regions. Thus, while the form of the optimal policy for a model where the state follows the sum of a diffusion and a more general jump component, such as in the specification of Bar-Ilan et al. (2004) has not been characterized, our set-up is special enough so that the decision rules, in the ergodic set for m, are of the “sS” form considered above. The features that make our problem special are that the jumps are all downwards and of the same size (i.e. z 40) and that the state is non-negative. In our case, if the state reaches mnn then it is controlled to be set at mn. Importantly, since the jumps in net cash consumption are all downwards, the state can only reach mnn at time t ¼ τ if it was below, but very close, at times arbitrary close to τ. On the other side, the boundary at m¼0 follows from non-negativity of cash and from the fact that the period return function attains its minimum at m ¼0. Thus, the value of mnn is defined as the smallest strictly positive value of the state for which adjustment is optimal.4 4 We can write a discrete time version of our model in the notation of Neave (1970) and Chen and Simchi-Levi (2009) as follows. To simplify we write the version with p ¼0. Let Δ be the length of the time period. The period return function is lðmÞ ¼ þ ∞ if mo 0 and otherwise lðmÞ ¼ ΔRm. The i.i.d. process pffiffiffiffi for unregulated cash, ξ ¼ −Δc þ Δss−z dN, where s is a symmetric binomial with zero mean and standard deviation one, where dN¼ 1 with probability κΔ

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

761

3.2. Solving for M, W, n in the case of no Brownian shocks: s ¼ 0 In this section we concentrate on the special case of the model where the net cumulated cash consumption is the sum of a deterministic constant consumption per unit of time and random jumps, i.e. we set the Brownian component to have zero variance or s ¼ 0. We concentrate on this case for two reasons. The first is that our datasets for Italy and Austria focuses on households whose head is not self employed for whom, as discussed above, the case of s ¼ 0 is more appropriate. The second reason for using s ¼ 0 is its simplicity. In particular, when π ¼ s ¼ 0, the linear equations for the coefficients in Proposition 2 simplify considerably, and since the range of inaction becomes ½0; mn , there is one non-linear equation in one unknown (see online appendix for the relevant equations for this case). Remember that, as discussed above, when s ¼ 0 the value function Vðm; mn ; mnn Þ simplifies to Vðm; mn Þ, i.e. it is indexed by only 1 parameter (the optimal return point mn). First, and for completeness, we consider the case where the large purchases are frequent. As in the deterministic case, if for a given size of the purchases z, the frequency κ is high enough, it is optimal to increase the size of the withdrawal and finance -in expected value- several purchases with each withdrawal. Proposition 4. Let π ¼ s ¼ 0, z 40, c≥0, p≥0 and b=R 40. There exist κðzÞ, which is increasing in z, and r 40 such that for any κ 4 κðzÞ and r or, the optimal threshold satisfies mn ðp; κ; z; cÞ 4 z. The logic of this proposition is the same as in the deterministic case, so the proof is omitted.5 Next, we further specialize the problem to the more tractable case in which the primitive parameters are such that the size of the jump z is larger than mn, so that in this case every jump in expenditures will trigger a withdrawal. 3.2.1. The case of infrequent large purchases: z 4 mn We continue with the analysis of the case of no inflation and no Brownian component, i.e. π ¼ s ¼ 0. Furthermore we solve the model and the cash holding statistics M; W; n; M for a configuration of parameters that corresponds to the case of small κ, (i.e. smaller than κ) in the deterministic model of Section 2 and large value of z. We found this case instructive for two reasons: first, based on the result in Proposition 3, the case where z is large and κ small presents some interesting differences compared to the problem where consumption expenditures are continuous. Second we think that the parameters for which this case applies, which concern size and frequency of the large purchases, seem to be empirically appropriate for modeling the currency management behavior for households in Austria, as argued below. Abusing notation, we let Vðm; m′; p; κ; z; cÞ denote the value function of the model analyzed in Section 3.2 when current cash is m and the return point for cash is m′ for the parameters ðp; κ; z; cÞ. We also let mn ðp; κ; z; cÞ be the value of the optimal return point for these parameters, and let Mðp; κ; z; cÞ; Wðp; κ; z; cÞ; Mðp; κ; z; cÞ and nðp; κ; z; cÞ be the corresponding cash-management statistics, described in Section 3.2. For future reference we let V n ðm′; p; κ; z; cÞ≡Vðm′; m′; p; κ; z; cÞ

ð13Þ

the value of following a policy with return threshold m′ when cash is at this value. Recall that at the optimal threshold value V n ðmn ðp; κ; z; cÞ; p; κ; z; cÞ is the smallest value of the value function. The next proposition studies the effect of the presence of large purchases (i.e. whether or not C(t) jumps) in a model with free withdrawal opportunities. We note that if z¼0 or κ ¼ 0 the model with no jumps corresponds to a version of Baumol–Tobin where there are p free withdrawal opportunities per unit of time. We have characterized the solution of that model and estimated it for a cross section of Italian households in Alvarez and Lippi (2009). The free withdrawal opportunities of that model imply that, relative to the prediction in Baumol–Tobin, agents makes more withdrawals (say n=ðc=2MÞ≡n=nBT 41) and they are smaller in size (say, W=M o2). Also differently to Baumol–Tobin, that model implies that in average agents withdraw when they have strictly positive real balances, i.e. M 4 0. We use the notation mn ðp′; 0; 0; cÞ to denote the optimal return threshold for the model with no jumps, with a rate of p′ free adjustment opportunities per unit of time, and with consumption at a constant rate c. Proposition 5. Assume that π ¼ s ¼ 0, c 40, p≥0, b=R 4 0, z 4 0 and r 4 0. There exists κ 40 such that for any κ o κ and z 4 mn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ we have mn ðp; κ; z; cÞ ¼ mn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ; V n ðmn ðp; κ; z; cÞ; p; κ; z; cÞ ¼ V n ðmn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ; p þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ þ Mðp; κ; z; cÞ ¼ Mðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ; Wðp; κ; z; cÞ ¼ Wðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ þ

κb ; r

κz ; n

Mðp; κ; z; cÞ ¼ Mðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ;

(footnote continued) and zero otherwise, and where dN and s are independent. The discount factor is γ ¼ 1=ð1 þ rΔÞ. The cost function has K ¼ Q ¼ b, and no proportional cost, k ¼ q ¼ 0. In term of their notation we have, as we let Δ↓0, the decision rules satisfy: U ¼ T ¼ mn ; 0 ¼ t ¼ t þ , and u− ¼ mnn : 5 We believe that the assumption that r is small is not required for the results, but it simplifies the constructive aspect of the proof. Online appendix provides the algorithms to compute value function and several cash management statistics of interest for the case of s ¼ 0 and π ¼ 0 for any configuration of the lumpy purchase parameters: z; k. The logic is the same one used to solve for the value function in Proposition 2.

762

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

nðp; κ; z; cÞ ¼ nðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ: Moreover, the conclusion holds for the same value of κ for all z′ 4 z. Part of the proof of the proposition is straightforward. In particular, if it is optimal to set mn ðp; κ; z; cÞ o z, then the value of the threshold equals the one in a model with no jumps, i.e. with z¼ 0, but with p þ κ free adjustment opportunities, i.e. mn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ. In other words, it is always a local minimum to set the return threshold equal to mn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ. In the case of no jumps in consumption at each free withdrawal opportunity cash balances are set to mn right after the adjustment. The consequences of a free adjustment opportunity bear many similarities with those that follow a jump in consumption. Both cases occur independently of the cash balances, and in both cases cash balances go to mn after the adjustment. The difference is that upon a free withdrawal opportunity the agent does it because it saves the cost b, while upon a consumption jump the agent does it because of the binding non-negativity of consumption. For the exact equivalence we require that the rate at which the free adjustment opportunities arrives is p þ κ, so that the rate at which this type of adjustment occurs is equally likely. The two value functions differ only by a constant term measuring the present value of the cost saved by the free withdrawal opportunities. It follows that the average cash holdings, average cash at withdrawals and average number of adjustments are equal to the ones obtained in a model with z¼0, p þ κ free adjustment opportunities and consumption equal to c. The average withdrawal size differs, because the jumps creates an extra withdrawal of size z every κ=n withdrawals. Finally, to show that the threshold value mn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ o z is optimal provided that κ is small, we use an argument that is analogous to the one of the deterministic model of Section 2. To understand the hypothesis that z≥mn used in Proposition 5 it is useful to give a characterization of mn0 ≡mn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ. In Alvarez and Lippi (2009) we show that mn0 is the unique positive solution to #  n 2 "  n i ∞ m0 m0 b 1 ¼ ðr þ p þ κÞ 1þ ∑ ð14Þ cR ð2 þ iÞ! c c i¼1 which we denote by mn0 ¼ φðb=ðRcÞ; p þ rÞ. Clearly mn0 is a strictly increasing function of b=R, which goes from 0 to ∞ as b=R varies in the same range, and it is decreasing in p. The limit as r þ p þ κ↓0 is the familiar Baumol–Tobin expression pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi mn0 =c ¼ 2b=ðcRÞ. Finally, m0 is increasing in c with and elasticity between 1/2 and 1. Thus, for a fixed z, one of the hypothesis of Proposition 5 holds, for a small enough fixed cost relative to opportunity cost, i.e. small b=R. Also, since mn0 pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi is decreasing in p þ κ þ r, thus 2bc=R≥cφðb=cR; r þ p þ κÞ. Hence a sufficient condition for z≥mn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ is that pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi z≥ 2bc=R≥c. A direct implication of Proposition 5 is that data on M; W; M; n and e can not identify κ; p and z separately. These data can only identify κz and κ þ p.6 We now describe a condition that the ratios W/M and M=M must satisfy to be consistent with the behavior described in the hypothesis of Proposition 5. Additionally, we describe how to identify κz=e and κ þ p, as long as the previous condition is met. To do so, we first describe all the implications of the observable statistics M; W; M; n and e for the model's parameters under the hypothesis of Proposition 5. Proposition 6. Let the assumptions of Proposition 5 hold. Then model implies the following relationship between the five observable statistics ðM; W; M; n; c þ κzÞ, the four structural parameters ðc; κz; p þ κ; b=RÞ, and the threshold mn: n¼

κþp  n ; 1−exp −ðκ þ pÞmc

κ W þ M ¼ mn þ z; n

ð15Þ

ð16Þ

M ¼ κ þ p; M

ð17Þ

c þ κz ¼ nW;

ð18Þ

  mn b=c ;r þ p þ κ : ¼φ R c

ð19Þ

n

The proof of this proposition is straightforward. Eq. (15) follows by noting that the time between withdrawals is distributed as a truncated exponential with parameter κ þ p, truncated at time t ≡mn =c, the time it will take to deplete money holdings with continuous consumption. The fundamental theorem of renewal theory then implies that the frequency is the reciprocal of the expected time between adjustments. Eq. (16) follows by taking expected values of the cash flows at time of a withdrawal. It states that on average, after a withdrawal, an agent has balances mn, which is the sum of the average cash at the time of withdrawal (M) and the withdrawal size (W) net of the fraction κ=n of the withdrawals where a consumption jump of size z is financed. Eq. (17) follows by computing the average cash holding at the time of an 6 To see this, note that for any pair of κ þ p and zκ that are consistent with M; W; M ; n and e, there are several other pairs κ′ þ p′ and z′κ′, with κ þ p ¼ κ′ þ p′ and zκ ¼ z′κ′, with z′ 4z and κ′o κ that produce the same observations.

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

763

adjustment. A fraction 1−ðp þ κÞ=n of the withdrawals the agent has reached zero cash holdings at the time of a withdrawal. A fraction ðp þ κÞ=n of the withdrawals the agents has strictly positive cash holdings, and since the occurrence of these adjustment are independent of the level of cash holdings, in these cases the agents has the average cash holdings. Eq. (18) is simply the budget constraint. Up to here the implications follow from the form of the optimal decision rules.7 Finally, Eq. (19), already presented and discussed in Eq. (14) ensures that the value of the threshold mn is optimal. Using Proposition 5 we have replaced here p by p þ κ. We use the expressions in Proposition 6 to solve for the fraction of expenditures that corresponds to jumps, i.e. κz=ðc þ κzÞ, the value of mn, which gives a lower bound to z in order for the proposition to apply, and the value of p þ k. We have 0 1 κz 1 @ M=M A; ¼1þ ð20Þ κz þ c W=M logð1−M =MÞ þ 1 M =M

κ ≤p þ κ ¼ n

M ≤n; M

0 n

z≥m ¼ M

1 logð1−M=MÞ @ A

ð21Þ



logð1−M =MÞ M =M

:

ð22Þ

The next proposition summarizes the implications for W/M and M=M of γ, b=ðcRÞ and p þ κ in the case where mn ≤z. To simplify the expressions we take the limit as r↓0, in which case, given γ all the other parameters combine in a single index to explain the effects on W/M and M=M. Proposition 7. Let r↓0 and assume that z; b=ðcRÞ, and p þ κ are such that mn ≤z. Define γ≡zκ=ðzκ þ cÞ. Then     W 1 b=c M b=c ¼ ω ðp þ κÞ2 ¼μ ðp þ κÞ2 and M 1−γ R M R

ð23Þ

where ω : Rþ -½0; 2 is strictly decreasing and μ : Rþ -½0; 1 is strictly increasing. The functions ω and μ depend on no other parameters. The proof uses the equivalence results of Proposition 5. Since every jump triggers a withdrawal when z 4 mn then the model is equivalent to the model with continuous consumption and no jumps, except that p (the arrival rate of free adjustments opportunity) is now p þ k, and the consumption scale variable is simply c, not c þ kz. Given this equivalence, the functions ω and μ are those described in Section 4.3 (namely in Proposition 6 and Fig. 1) in Alvarez and Lippi (2009). 3.2.2. On the first order conditions for mn We conclude with an illustration on the necessary, but not sufficient, nature of the boundary conditions for the optimal return point in our problem. Remember that when s ¼ 0 the value function Vðm; mn ; mnn Þ ¼ Vðm; mn Þ is indexed by only 1 parameter, the optimal return point mn. Fig. 1 helps to understand the different cases covered in Propositions 4 and 5 depending on the value of κ. The figure plots the value of following a policy characterized by a threshold mn, evaluated at m ¼ mn , for different values of this threshold. The best policy is given by the value of mn that minimizes Vðmn ; mn Þ. Interestingly this function is not single peaked. This example shows that simply adding the boundary condition V′ðmn ; mn Þ ¼ 0 does not insure the optimality of the given policy. Note the difference with models without the jump component, such as Constantinides (1978), where a verification theorem states that any function that solves the relevant ODE and boundary conditions is a solution of the problem. The parameter values considered for this figure correspond to an “intermediate” value for κ and z for which the optimal threshold has mn ≈354z ¼ 20. Note that while setting mn ¼ mn ðp þ κ; 0; 0; cÞ ¼ 15oz ¼ 20, so that every jump would trigger a withdrawal, is a local minimum of Vðmn ; mn Þ but it is not the global minimum. In other words, the values for this example do not satisfy the hypothesis that κ o κ of Proposition 5. Notice also that setting mn ¼ 51, which is the optimal threshold for the case of no jumps, but a larger continuous consumption equal to c þ κz is also not the optimal for the case with jumps, but it is also close to a local minimum. 4. Two empirical applications In this section we describe two applications of the ideas developed above. The first one applies the model to currency management using survey and diary data from a sample of Austrian households. In this case the relevant liquid asset is currency, and the relevant notion of expenditures are those paid with cash. The second investigation applies the model to the management of liquid assets using a panel of administrative records for the customers of a large Italian bank. 7 One can also add an expression that computes the value of average value of M, using n; mn and parameters, namely M=c ¼ ðnmn =c−1Þ=ðκ þ pÞ. Yet, this equation is implied by Eqs. (15)–(18).

764

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

In this case we take liquid asset to be a concept similar to M2, and the expenditures to include both durable and non-durable purchases.8 4.1. Currency management of Austrian and Italian households In this section we present evidence on the cash management of italian and austrian households, and then concentrate on the latter for which we also have data on the nature of their consumption paid with cash. We present evidence that there are some large expenditures paid with cash, and that the households for which these expenditures are more important exhibit some of the behavior predicted by the theory in terms of their frequency and size of withdrawals. Table 1 displays some statistics from two households surveys, one from Italy and one from Austria. We present all statistics splitting the sample between households with an ATM card and those without, as a rough way to control for the consequences of the “free withdrawals” opportunities, namely a large number of withdrawals relative to Baumol–Tobin, as explained above and in Alvarez and Lippi (2009). We display the mean across households (individuals for Austria) of several statistics: share of consumption that is paid using currency for both countries, the average amount of currency held M, the average amount of currency held at the time of a withdrawal M, the average size of a withdrawal W, the average size of deposits D, the number of deposits per year nD and number of withdrawals per year n. Several of the statistics are computed as ratios, which helps in interpreting them in terms of the model. For instance, we use M=e, the average money to daily cash consumption, W/M the average withdrawal size to average currency held, the ratio of the average size of deposits to withdrawals W=D, the ratio of n to nBT, where the latter is the frequency implied by the assumption that withdrawals occur when cash is zero and that W ¼ 2M, so that nBT ¼ e=ð2MÞ. The statistics displayed in Table 1 show that the Austrian and Italian households cash management is similar in several dimensions. The Italian survey data have been used in several paper studying cash management, such as Attanasio et al. (2002), Lippi and Secchi (2009), Alvarez and Lippi (2009). The Austrian dataset is smaller in size but includes some additional information concerning the size distribution of purchases that we are going to use below. Using the outcomes of the case in which s ¼ 0, analyzed in Propositions 5 and 6, we compute some statistics to measure the degree of large infrequent cash purchases for individuals in Austria. The data comes from two related sources: a diary of daily expenditures of the Austrian households and a retrospective survey of the same households, described in Mooslechner et al. (2006). The diary asked individuals to record all purchases made in the following week. The survey contains several questions on cash management, as well as on method and pattern of purchases. We split the sample between agents with and without ATM cards because, at least using only the cash management statistics M; W; M; e, the model does not identify separately p and κ. Yet the value of p should be related (positively) to the density and availability of ATMs.9 Thus, the split between those with and without ATM cards serves as a way to “control” for the value of p. Table 2 shows that the small size purchases are made using currency by almost all individuals, but that less than half of the individuals use currency as the usual means of payments for the large purchases (400 euros or more). These statistics are presented separately for those with ATM cards and for those without, which shows a clear difference. Almost all individuals without an ATM card use cash as the usual payments regardless of the size of the purchases, whereas the use of cash falls sharply with the size of the purchase for individuals with an ATM card. Table 3 displays some cash management statistics for individuals who use cash for large purchases (top panel) and for those that do not (bottom panel). These data are useful to compare our model with the canonical one with continuous consumption. These statistics are also presented separately for those with ATM cards. We display the ratio of the average size of withdrawals to the average cash holdings, W/M, as well as the ratio of the number of withdrawals relative to the one implied by Baumol–Tobin, n=nBT .10 We interpret the model as having implications for the comparison between individuals for whom currency is the usual means of payment for large purchases vs. those for whom it is not. For those that use currency for large purchases we expect W/M to be larger, and n=nBT to be smaller. Comparing the top and the bottom panels of Table 3 we find some support for this prediction for all the individuals and for those with ATM cards.11 With respect to nM=M recall that, from Eq. (21), this statistic equals p þ κ. So under the reasonable assumption that individuals with ATM cards have a higher value of p, consistent with the evidence in Alvarez and Lippi (2009), this statistic should be larger in this group. The last row of the first panel of Table 3 reports a statistic that shows how the threshold of 400 euros, chosen independently by the survey designers as a threshold for large purchases, is a reasonable approximation for the value of z which 8 While in this paper we focus on the implication of these large purchases for cash management, a related interesting literature, both empirical and theoretical, studies the choice of means of payments, especially in relation to the purchases size, as in e.g. Whitesell (1989), Bounie et al. (2007) and Mooslechner et al. (2006). The problem of the choice of means of payment differ across economies. In particular we conjecture that for developing economies and less developed countries, where alternative to cash are less prevalent, more people will be paying for large purchases using cash, and hence the issues discussed in this paper are more relevant. Preliminary work using panel data from rural Thailand in Alvarez et al. (2011) supports this hypothesis. 9 For empirical support of this hypothesis in a model with κ ¼ z ¼ 0 see Alvarez and Lippi (2009). 10 The accounting identity Wn ¼ e implies that the product of these statistics should be 2. We present both statistics because the identity does not hold exactly for each unit of observation. We interpret this discrepancy as measurement error. Consistent with this interpretation we find that the patterns of violation of the identity are symmetric and centered around zero (see Alvarez and Lippi, 2009). 11 The prediction is not verified when comparing across individuals without ATM cards. But notice that there are only 6 individuals w/o ATM who did not use cash as the payment method, so this statistic is likely noisy.

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

765

Table 2 Currency as the usual payment method for purchases of different size. % Individuals that use currencya

Purchases Purchases Purchases Purchases Purchases Purchases Purchases

between between between between between between between

½0; 10 euros ½11; 30 euros ½30; 50 euros ½51; 100 euros ½100; 200 euros ½201; 400 euros ½401; ∞Þ euros

All (1048 Obs.)

w/ATM card (895 Obs.)

w/o ATM card (153 Obs.)

95.6 83.3 70.4 58.1 47.6 43.2 45.9

94.9 80.6 65.6 51.5 39.2 24.2 27.4

100.0 99.4 98.7 97.7 97.7 96.1 96.1

Using survey of Austrian individuals described in Mooslechner et al. (2006). a Percentage of individuals that answer that currency is the usual method of payments for purchases for each different size. The alternatives are currency or other method. Based on 1048 responses for each purchase size.

Table 3 Cash management and large purchases ( 4400 euros) in Austria.

Individuals who usually make large purchases in casha % persons that use cash for large purchases

Withdrawal to money: W=M # withdrawals relative to BT:b n=nBT Normalized cash at withdrawals:c nM =M Normalized size of cash expenditures:d z=mn

All (1048 Obs.)

w/ATM card (895 Obs.)

w/o ATM card (153 Obs.)

46%

37%

96%

Mean

Median

Mean

Median

2.0 3.5 13.4 5.9

1.1 1.2 4.5 1.7

1.9 4.4 17.5 5.7

1.0 1.5 6.3 1.8

Individuals who usually do NOT make large purchases in casha % persons that do not use cash for large purchases 54%

Withdrawal to money: W=M # withdrawals relative to BT:b n=nBT Normalized cash at withdrawals:c nM =M

63%

Mean 2.1 1.5 4.0 6.9

Median 1.3 0.7 2.6 1.2

4%

Mean

Median

Mean

Median

Mean

Median

1.6 5.9 20.6

1.0 1.9 7.8

1.5 6.0 20.8

1.0 1.9 8.0

10.4 0.9 3.8

2.1 0.7 2.9

Using survey of Austrian individuals described in Mooslechner et al. (2006). a Based on a question about how individual usually paid for items that cost more than 400 euros. Two options are available, either currency or other payment methods. Total number of respondents is 1048. b # of withdrawals n relative to Baumol–Tobin benchmark, nBT ¼ e=ð2MÞ Based on a diary of all transactions during a week. This the week is right after the month corresponding to the question on large transactions above. c The variable nM =M is the product of the number of withdrawals n and the ratio of the average cash at the time of withdrawal, M to the average cash holdings. d The statistics is computed for individuals with z 4 0, measured with the diary data (see footnote a), mn computed using Eq. (22) and the survey data on M =M.

satisfies z 4mn . The row reports the mean and median value of z=mn , where the variable z is measured using the diary data, computed for those individuals for whom z 4 0 in the diary data. The value of mn is computed using Eq. (22) and the observations on M=M. It appears that, for all the cases considered the value is greater than one, confirming the empirical appropriateness of the assumption z 4 mn . In Table 4 we use the diary expenditures data (recorded during a week). We first note that, given how infrequent are the large purchases in cash per month, there is not enough information in a week of expenditures to measure heterogeneity across individuals by using the 400 euros threshold. Therefore we measure the lumpiness of expenditures using the ratio of the average cash purchase to the median cash purchase both for those with and without ATM cards. This indicator is given by the ratio between the average and the median size of the household purchase, denoted as ea =em . Notice that in our model this statistic is ea =em ¼ ðc þ κzÞ=c so that it is increasing in the share of lumpy purchases.12 Additionally, we report a statistic

12 To see this it is helpful to consider a discrete-time version of the model, with a period of length 1 broken into small subperiods of length dt, so that 1=dt is the number of subperiods. In each subperiod there is exactly one “small” purchase of size c dt. Moreover, one large purchase of size z occurs with probability κ dt and no large purchase occurs with probability 1−κ dt. Large purchases are independently distributed across subperiods. In this discrete-time model there are exactly 1=dt purchases of size c dt in a period of length 1, and a number between 0 and 1=dt purchases of size z, with a binomial distribution. (There are 1=dt purchases of size c dt and a probability ðκ dtÞj ð1−κ dtÞ1=dt−j j! ð1=dt−jÞ!=ð1=dt!Þ of having exactly j “large purchases” of

766

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

Table 4 Statistics on the lumpiness of cash purchases in Austria (based on diary data). With ATM card

a

Purchase size: average/median: ea =em Average purchase size/income:b ea =y Number of purchases per week

Without ATM card

Mean

Median

Mean

Median

1.6 2.2 10

1.3 1.4 9

1.6 4.4 10

1.3 2.3 9

Regr. coeff. −1.01, t−stat −10.0

4 1

4 W/M

n / n_BT

Based on a diary of all transactions during a week (right after the month corresponding to the question on large transactions described in the survey). a The ratio uses the average and median transaction size paid with currency for each individual during the week of the diary. b Value of the average purchase made with currency (ea) divided by the monthly income of the individual (y).

1 .25

.25

Regr. coeff. 0.17 , t−stat 2.4

1

2

5

1

10

Ratio between average and median purchases in cash

M_low / M

Number of withdrawals relative to BT

regression

2

5

10

Ratio between average and median purchases in cash Avg Withdrawal to Avg cash holdings

regression

2 1 .5 .2

Regr. coeff. 0.001 , t−stat 0.001

.05 .01

1

2

5

8

Ratio between average and median purchases in cash Cash at withdrawals relative to Avg cash holdings

regression

Fig. 2. Austria: the inventory model statistics vs. ea =em .

for the number of purchases made with cash during a week. The table shows that the measure of lumpy purchases are essentially constant across ATM ownership. Next we use our proxy for the lumpiness of purchases, ea =em , and correlate it to patterns of cash-management statistics. We first present cash management statistics pooling all Austrian individuals. We find some patterns that are broadly consistent with what the model predicts as a consequence of variation of z across agents. Recall that, using the discrete time interpretation of the model outlined above, the skewness in the size distribution of purchases is increasing in z, so that we interpret ea =em as a proxy for z. We find that ea =em is negatively correlated with n=nBT and positively with W/M (see Fig. 2). We did not find any correlation between ea =em and M=M, which is consistent with the hypothesis that the ratio is determined by the variation of p þ κ rather than that of z, and that it is dominated by the variation on p. (footnote continued) size z for j ¼ 0; …; 1=dt). The average number of large purchases over a period of length 1 is κ, so that for sufficiently small time periods (i.e. 1=dt 4 κ) the median purchase size is em ≡c dt while the average purchase size per period is ea ¼ ðc þ κzÞ dt, so that ea =em ¼ ðc þ κzÞ=c gives a measure of the skewness of the size distribution of expenditures.

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

767

Regr. coeff. −1.03, t−stat −3.7 4

n / n_BT

n / n_BT

1

.25

Regr. coeff. −0.97, t−stat −9.1 4 1 .25

1

2

5

1

10

2

5

10

Ratio between average and median purchases in cash

Ratio between average and median purchases in cash

Number of withdrawals relative to BT

Number of withdrawals relative to BT

regression

regression

Fig. 3. Austria: normalized withdrawal frequency, n=nBT , vs. lumpiness, ea =em . Note: log scale. The vertical axis reports the normalized number of withdrawals n=nBT .

We now turn to a comparison of the cash management statistics across ATM ownership groups. Fig. 3 plots the normalized number of withdrawals, n=nBT against the skewness measure ea =em . The negative correlation displayed is consistent with what the model predicts as a consequence of variation of z across agents. 4.2. Management of liquid assets by Italian investors This section applies the lumpy-purchases hypothesis to the modeling of the household management of a broad liquid asset, close to M2, using data from a sample of Italian households. The information source is a panel of Italian households (investors), whose transactions were recorded in the administrative data of a large commercial bank. We document that following liquidations of high return asset into liquid asset, a disproportionate amount (relative to the frequency of adjustments) is spent early on, a pattern that is predicted by our model where lumpy expenditures triggers withdrawals. In Alvarez et al. (2012) we analyze a class of models where households must use a liquid asset to pay for all their expenditures and they face information and/or transaction cost to transfer money from high-yield illiquid assets to the low-yield liquid asset. In that paper we consider specifications with either non-durable consumption or durable consumption. In the specification where all the expenditures are in non-durable goods – a version of Duffie and Sun (1990) or Abel et al. (2007) – then the expenditures occur at a constant rate between the adjustments of liquid assets. This implies an average holding of liquid asset similar to the one in Tobin (1956)–Baumol (1952). Indeed in Alvarez et al. (2012) we found that the cross section distribution of the ratio of M2 times the frequency of financial trades relative to the rate of consumption of non-durables is totally at odds with this prediction. On the other hand, in the specification where all the expenditures are in durable goods – a variation of Grossman and Laroque (1990) – then the expenditures are lumpy and occur infrequently, implying that they can be paid without holding any liquid asset between adjustments. This implies that the average holdings of liquid assets tend to zero as the model time period shrinks. A more realistic model will have expenditures both in non-durable goods – so that they are continuous – as well as on durable goods – which with either transaction cost of indivisibilities, becomes lumpy and infrequent. The model in this paper analyzes such a set up. Hence while the model generalizes the one considered in Alvarez et al. (2012) by having both type of expenditures, it simplifies the set up in two dimensions: the process for expenditures is exogenous and the adjustment cost does not include observation costs. The analysis uses a panel data of administrative records from Unicredit, one of the largest Italian commercial banks. The administrative data contain information on the stocks and the net flows of 26 assets categories that investors have at Unicredit. These data are available at a monthly frequency for 35 months beginning in December 2006.13 Since the administrative record registers both the stock of each asset category at the end of the period as well as the net trading flow into that category, we can directly identify trading decisions, which would not be possible if only assets valuation at the end of period were available. One 13 See Appendix F in Alvarez et al. (2012) for a detailed description of the data. There are two samples. The first is a sample of about 40,000 investors that were randomly drawn from the population of investors at Unicredit and that served as a reference sample from extracting the investors to be interviewed in the 2007 survey. We refer to this as the large sample. We do not have direct access to the administrative records for the large sample; calculations and estimates on this sample were kindly done at Unicredit. The second which we call the survey sample has the same administrative information for the investors that actually participated in the 2007 survey. We do have access to the survey-sample data which can additionally be matched with the information from the 2007 survey. Since some households left Unicredit after the interview the administrative data are available for 1541 households instead on the 1686 in the 2007 survey. Notice that both the large sample and the survey sample are balanced panel data.

768

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

Table 5 Liquidity and portfolio transactions by Italian investors. Dependent variable: change in the checking account in the month of the transaction Regressors Coefficient Standard error Flow of investment sales: β0 : current β1 : lag 1 β2 : lag 2 β3 : lag 3 β4 : lag 4 Flow of investment purchases: γ 0 : current γ 1 : lag 1 γ 2 : lag 2 γ 3 : lag 3 γ 4 : lag 4 Investor total assets: δ: N. observations R2

0.703nnn −0.23nnn −0.16nnn 0.002 −0.03

0.0057 0.0062 0.0065 0.006 0.0065

−0.65nnn 0.020nnn −0.076nnn 0.056nnn −0.011nn

0.0065 0.007 0.007 0.007 0.006

0.092nnn

0.0025

31,622 0.47

OLS regressions of the net flow into the checking account on the net flow of investments sales and purchases. Estimates include investors fixed effects. Three (or two) asterisks denote that the regression coefficients are significantly different form zero at the 1\% (or 5\%) confidence level. Source: Unicredit survey sample, monthly administrative records (35 months) of 26 accounts for each of 1541 investors.

of the 26 assets is the checking account. In what follows we distinguish assets into two categories: liquid assets, which we identify with the checking account, and investments the sum of the remaining 25 assets classes. We also experimented, with no change on the results, with a broader definition of liquid assets, and hence a narrower definition of financial assets. The data we are interested in concern the household flows of financial investment liquidations and purchases, and the changes in the liquid asset holdings (i.e. checking account). The key hypothesis to be explored is whether expenditures occur at a constant rate between liquidations, i.e. whether the liquid assets are depleted at a roughly constant rate, as implicit in inventory models with a continuous consumption process. For this we use the temporal patterns of asset sales and liquid asset changes in our panel data to show that the spending rate of liquid assets that comes from asset sales is at least twice as fast as the one consistent with a model with steady expenditure financed with cash and the observed frequency of asset liquidations. Next we illustrate the empirical exercise. We run a regression between Cjt – the net euro-flow of the checking account of investor j in month t, and the net investments flows Fjt distinguishing between the net flow of investment sales F Sjt and investment purchases F Pjt , also in euro amounts during the same month, as well as with lags. Empirically four lags are sufficient to characterize the dynamics. We notice that by construction F Sjt and F Pjt are either zero or positive. So for instance F Sjt ¼ 100 (or F Pjt ¼ 100) means that over that month there is a net investment sale (or purchase) of 100 euros. Thus F Sjt and F Pjt are never positive (at the same time) for investor j and are both zero if there are no trades with a net cash flow. The regression we run is 4

4

k¼0

k¼0

C jt ¼ ∑ βk F Sjt−k þ ∑ γ k F Pjt−k þ δW jt þ hj þ ujt where Wjt is investor j total financial assets, hj is an investor j fixed effect and ujt an error term. We use the estimated coefficients, shown in Table 5, to characterize the pattern of liquidity management by a household who sells an asset. The implied impulse response is readily computed using the point estimates of the βk coefficients. Following an investment sale, about 30 cents per dollar are spent in the same month. In the two months following the sale, approximately 60 cents per dollar are spent (the sum of (1−0.703)+0.23+0.16).14 To assess whether these patterns are consistent with a steady depletion of the liquid asset, such as the one implied by the models with continuous consumption described above, we need to use the information on the frequency of asset sales computed in our dataset, reported in Table 6. The table shows that the annual frequency of asset sales for the median household is around one sale per year. Hence, if assets sales were used mostly to finance a steady flow of consumption expenditures, one would expect that the liquidity obtained from the asset sale should be spent out at a rate of roughly 1/12 per month.15 This would imply that in the first month one should see an increase in the checking account of about 0.92 cents per euro of investments liquidation, and a negative effect of about 0.08 cents in the subsequent months. Instead, the 14 For comparison if we use a broader definition of liquid asset that includes time deposits (hence excludes them from financial investments) we obtain that the results are essentially the same. In particular the pattern of coefficients of the lags of investments sales on change in liquid asset account, i.e. of the coefficients βk for k ¼ 0; 1…; 4 are 0.70, −0.22, −0.16, 0.002 and −0.03 respectively. 15 An even 1/12 is an upper bound since our statistics are based on records of the balance of the investor's accounts at the end of every month. Thus, for example, if the sale of assets happens during the middle of the month the fraction of the sale of asset that should be consumed during the remaining period of the first month should be 1/24. This would imply an increase during the first month in the checking account of about 0.96.

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

769

Table 6 Summary statistics for the average annual number of asset sales trades. Asset sales ≥500

All asset sales NSj

Total sample Stockholders (total) Stockholders (direct)

Asset sales ≥1000

Median

Mean (sd)

Median

Mean (sd)

Median

Mean (sd)

1.03 1.71 1.71

1.40 (1.29) 1.81 (1.28) 1.97 (1.30)

1.03 1.37 1.37

1.17 (1.11) 1.53 (1.13) 1.69 (1.19)

0.70 1.02 1.37

1.06 (1.03) 1.40 (1.07) 1.55 (1.12)

Source: Unicredit survey sample, monthly administrative records (35 months) of 26 accounts for each of 1541 investors.

estimated pattern indicates a much larger liquidity reduction in the first month (0.7 vs. 0.9) than is implied by the steady consumption hypothesis. Likewise, the rate at which liquidity further decrease in the following two months is faster than the one predicted by the steady consumption hypothesis. Considering the mean frequency of asset sales, as opposed to the median, makes the picture a bit less striking, since the mean frequency of asset sales is higher (about 1.4 trades per year), though the observed dynamics of the checking account remain inconsistent with the steady consumption hypothesis (as e.g. the observed value of 0.7 is smaller than 1–1.4 /12¼0.88).

5. Concluding remarks We presented an inventory model for the demand of liquid assets that allows for the possibility that, in addition to a continuous (deterministic or random) component, the law of motion for the liquid assets might record a jump when left controlled. These jumps may be caused by lumpy expenditures, such as the purchase of durable goods by households. We showed that a key difference compared to canonical inventory models is that, since the liquidity used to finance these jumps has infinite velocity, then the lumpy expenditure component does not enter as the “scale variable” for the average demand of liquidity and only affects some cash managements statistics, such as size and frequency of withdrawals. We showed that accounting this phenomenon is useful to interpret cash management patterns in Austria and in Italy. Other applications of the ideas in this paper concerns models of liquidity management by firms and by banks. First, consider the case of firms which have large expenditures that must be paid with a liquid asset. Our model predicts that these expenditures will not affect the average firm holdings of liquid assets, for exactly the same reasons discussed in the model for households: these expenditures have an infinite velocity. This prediction is potentially testable by examining a panel data of liquid asset holding. We find some confirmation of our hypothesis in the existing literature. Bates et al. (2009) run several specifications of panel regressions to explain the ratio of liquid asset to total asset for of U.S. manufacturing firms from 1980 to 2006. After controlling for other determinants of liquid asset holding, they find a negative coefficient on the ratio of acquisitions to assets, which can be interpreted as a measure of large and infrequent disbursement of liquid assets. The second application is the management of reserves of banks in accounts at the Federal Reserve System. It has been documented that the distribution of payments made through Fedwire is highly skewed.16 Thus our framework, adapted to take into account some specific features of this market, would be suitable to study and interpret this data. We leave the investigation of these topics for future work.

Acknowledgments We thank the Editor Ricardo Lagos, an anonymous referee, and David Andolfatto, Avner Bar-Ilan, Cyril Monnet, and Julio Rotemberg for useful comments. Alvarez thanks the Templeton foundation for financial support. We are grateful to Helmut Stix for kindly providing us with the Austrian data, and to Luigi Guiso and Unicredit Bank for giving us access to the Italian investors' data. An earlier version of this paper circulated under the title “The demand for currency with uncertain lumpy purchases”.

Appendix A. Supplementary material Supplementary data associated with this article can be found in the online version at http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco. 2013.05.008. 16 In 2008 the median value Fedwire payments was about $24,000 and its average about $5.8 millions, see Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2012).

770

F. Alvarez, F. Lippi / Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2013) 753–770

References Abel, Andrew B., Eberly, Janice C., Panageas, Stavros, 2007. Optimal inattention to the stock market. American Economic Review 97 (2), 244–249. Alvarez, F., Pawasutipaisit, A., Townsend, R., 2011. Household as Firms: Cash Management in Thai Villages. University of Chicago, in preparation. Alvarez, Fernando, Guiso, Luigi, Lippi, Francesco, 2012. Durable consumption and asset management with transaction and observation costs. American Economic Review102 (5), 2272–2300. Alvarez, Fernando E., Lippi, Francesco, 2009. Financial innovation and the transactions demand for cash. Econometrica 77 (2), 363–402. Archibald, Blyth C., Silver, Edward A., 1978. (s,S) Policies under continuous review and discrete compound poisson demand. Management Science 24 (9), 899–909. Attanasio, Orazio, Guiso, Luigi, Jappelli, Tullio, 2002. The demand for money, financial innovation and the welfare cost of inflation: an analysis with household data. Journal of Political Economy 110 (2), 318–351. Baccarin, Stefano, 2009. Optimal impulse control for a multidimensional cash management system with generalized cost functions. European Journal of Operational Research 196 (1), 198–206. Bar-Ilan, A., 1990. Overdrafts and the demand for money. The American Economic Review 80 (5), 1201–1216. Bar-Ilan, A., Perry, D., Stadje, W., 2004. A generalized impulse control model of cash management. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 28 (6), 1013–1033. Bates, T.W., Kahle, K.M., Stulz, R.M., 2009. Why do US firms hold so much more cash than they used to? The Journal of Finance 64 (5), 1985–2021. Baumol, William J., 1952. The transactions demand for cash: an inventory theoretic model. Quarterly Journal of Economics 66 (4), 545–556. Bensoussan, A., Chutani, A., Sethi, S.P., 2009. Optimal cash management under uncertainty. Operations Research Letters 37 (6), 425–429. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2012. Payment System Statistics, Fedwire Funds Services. Bounie, D., Francois, A., Houy, N., 2007. The demand for currency versus debitable accounts: a reconsideration. SSRN eLibrary 〈http://ssrn.com/paper〉 987375. Chen, X., Simchi-Levi, D., 2009. A new approach for the stochastic cash balance problem with fixed costs. Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences 23 (04), 545–562. Constantinides, George, 1978. Stochatic cash management with fixed and proportional transaction costs. Management Science 26 (4), 620–636. Constantinides, George, Richard, Scott F., 1978. Existence of optimal simple policies discounted-cost inventory and cash management in continuous time. Operations Research 26 (4), 620–636. Davis, M.H.A., Guo, X., Wu, G., 2010. Impulse control of multidimensional jump diffusions. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization 48, 5276. Duffie, Darrell, Sun, Tong-sheng, 1990. Transactions costs and portfolio choice in a discrete-continuous-time setting. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 14 (1), 35–51. Eppen, Gary D., Fama, Eugene F., 1969. Cash balance and simple dynamic portfolio problems with proportional costs. International Economic Review 10 (2), 119–133. Frenkel, Jacob A., Jovanovic, Boyan, 1980. On transactions and precautionary demand for money. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 95 (1), 25–43. Grossman, Sanford J., Laroque, Guy, 1990. Asset pricing and optimal portfolio choice in the presence of illiquid durable consumption goods. Econometrica 58 (1), 25–51. Harrison, Michael, Taskar, Michael I., 1983. Instantaneous control of Brownian motion. Mathematics of Operations Research 8 (2), 439–453. Harrison, Michael J., Sellke, Thomas M., Taylor, Allison J., 1983. Impulse control of Brownian motion. Mathematics of Operations Research 8 (3), 454–466. Jovanovic, Boyan, 1982. Inflation and welfare in the steady state. Journal of Political Economy 90 (3), 561–577. Lippi, Francesco, Secchi, Alessandro, 2009. Technological change and the households' demand for currency. Journal of Monetary Economics 56 (2), 222–230. Milbourne, Ross, 1983. Optimal money holding under uncertainty. International Economic Review 24 (3), 685–698. Miller, Merton, Orr, Daniel, 1966. A model of the demand for money by firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 80 (3), 413–435. Mooslechner, Peter, Stix, Helmut, Wagner, Karin, 2006. How are payments made in Austria? Results of a survey on the structure of Austrian households use of payment means in the context of monetary policy analysis. Monetary Policy and Economy 2006 (Q2), 111–134. Neave, E.H., 1970. The stochastic cash balance problem with fixed costs for increases and decreases. Management Science 16 (7), 472–490. Sato, K., Suzuki, A., 2011. Stochastic cash management problem with double exponential jump diffusion processes. Operations Research and Its Applications. Song, Jing-Sheng, Zipkin, Paul, 1993. Inventory control in a fluctuating demand environment. Operations Research 41 (2), 351–370. Tobin, James, 1956. The interest elasticity of transactions demand for money. Review of Economics and Statistics 38 (3), 241–247. Whitesell, William C., 1989. The demand for currency versus debitable accounts: note. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 21 (2), 246–251.