International Journal of Industrial Organization 6 (1988) 373-384. North-Holland
THE KINKED DEMAND
CURVE*
A Game-Theoretic Approach V. B H A S K A R University College, London WCIE 6BT, UK
Final version received August 1987 In a simple model of duopoly, firms' price moves are modelled as an extensive form game where firms can respond to undercutting without delay. When firms are not too dissimilar, kinked demand strategies enforcing an arbitrary price may be Nash equilibria; however, these strategies are dominated and perfect equilibrium is unique at the minimum optimal common price. Rather than implying price rigidity, kinked demand strategies are a device for ensuring compliance with a collusive price leadership.
provide a reformulation of the theory which not only meets these theoretical objections but is consistent with both types of evidence. Merton Peck's classic study of the aluminium industry (1961) proposed a modified version of the theory in which the equilibrium price was uniquely determined. Peck questioned the kinked demand theory's assertion that a firm's competitors will not match price increases; if all firms benefit from a higher common price, a price increase will be followed since the initiator will cancel it otherwise. This in turn makes it attractive for firms to initiate a price rise when all firms prefer a higher common price. The equilibrium must hence be at a price where at least one firm does not prefer a higher common price. Defining each firm's optimal common price, as the price which maximizes its profits given that its rivals are pricing in line, Peck argued that the unique equilibrium would be the lowest of these optimal common prices. At this price no firm would have an incentive to reduce price since the outcome would be a lower common price which hurts all. Nor would other firms be able to force the price upward since the firm with the lowest optimal common price has no incentive to match their price increases, Section 2 formalized these arguments by considering a duopoly setting price for a single trading period. I consider physically identical products while allowing for a finite cross elasticity of demand due to customer loyalties and switching costs [Okun (1981), Klemperer (1986)]. The key assumption is that firms can respond to their rival's undercutting without delay - this presumes that secret price reductions are not possible, an assumption which may be tenable in markets with a large number of buyers, as Stigler (1964, p. 47) suggests, since 'no one has yet invented a way to advertise price reductions which brings them to the attention of numerous customers but not to that of any rival'. Price moves are modelled as an extensive form game. Firms simultaneously announce initial prices; if prices differ, the firm pricing higher can reset its price. If it undercuts its competitor on the second move, the latter in turn is given the option of changing its price. The move sequence ends when one firm does not undercut so that its rival has no need to reply. These price moves are assumed to take place sufficiently rapidly that no trade takes place until the final prices are announced; transitory profits are assumed negligible as in the kinked demand theory. This game is equivalent (in the sense that equilibrium outcomes are identical) to a game where the firm pricing higher initially restricts itself on the second move to prices above or equal to its rival. F o r expositional purposes I therefore use the two-move game. The main result is that firms will match undercutting in the relevant range (provided that they are not too dissimilar) and perfect equilibrium is unique at the minimum optimal common price. Interestingly, kinked demand strategies enforcing prices below the minimum optimal common price may be Nash equilibria but these strategies are dominated for both players and
E Bhaskar, The kinked demand curve
375
will hence not be adopted. I also find that the minimum optimal common price is inapplicable if the firms are too dissimilar since the firm with the higher preferred price chooses not to match its rival's lower price on the second move - the unique equilibrium is of a Stackelberg type, the firm with the lowered preferred price acting as a leader, while the follower prices above it. These roles are not exogenously imposed but emerge naturally.2 Section 3 gives a simple example showing how the type of equilibrium can be related to differences in costs or demand elasticities. Section 4 interprets these results; rather than implying price rigidity, this theory provides a rigorous basis for a type of price leadership where the leader uses a kinked demand strategy to enforce the minimum optimal common price. The ability of firms to respond without delay to undercutting ensures that the unique noncooperative equilibrium is collusive; this approach to oligopolistic collusion avoids some of the problems which have arisen in the repeated games approach.