The reactions of chlorine monofluoride with unsaturated compounds and the dehydrohalogenation of some of the derivatives

The reactions of chlorine monofluoride with unsaturated compounds and the dehydrohalogenation of some of the derivatives

Accepted Manuscript The Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks on Inequality Davide Furceri, Prakash Loungani, Aleksandra Zdzienicka PII: DOI: Reference: ...

1015KB Sizes 10 Downloads 104 Views

Accepted Manuscript The Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks on Inequality Davide Furceri, Prakash Loungani, Aleksandra Zdzienicka PII: DOI: Reference:

S0261-5606(17)30227-9 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2017.11.004 JIMF 1856

To appear in:

Journal of International Money and Finance

Please cite this article as: D. Furceri, P. Loungani, A. Zdzienicka, The Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks on Inequality, Journal of International Money and Finance (2017), doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2017.11.004

This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.

The Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks on Inequality Davide Furceri, Prakash Loungani, and Aleksandra Zdzienicka

May 2017

Abstract This paper provides new evidence of the effect of conventional monetary policy shocks on income inequality. We construct a measure of unanticipated changes in policy rates—changes in short-term interest rates that are orthogonal to unexpected changes in growth and inflation news—for a panel of 32 advanced and emerging market countries over the period 1990-2013. Our main finding is that contractionary monetary policy shocks increase income inequality, on average. The effect is asymmetric—tightening of policy raises inequality more than easing lowers it—and depends on the state of the business cycle. We find some evidence that the effect increases with the share of labor income and is mitigated by redistribution policies. Finally, while an unexpected increase in policy rates increases inequality, changes in policy rates driven by an increase in growth and inflation are associated with lower inequality. JEL Classification Numbers: E62, E64, D63. Keywords: monetary policy; monetary policy shocks; income inequality.



International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street NW, Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A. For inquiries please contact [email protected]. University of Palermo. 

International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street NW, Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A. [email protected].



International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street NW, Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A. [email protected].

1

1. INTRODUCTION Growing inequality, in particular in advanced economies, has attracted much attention among policymakers, including many central bankers (e.g., Yellen 2014; Bernanke 2015, Draghi 2016). An extensive literature has suggested many causes of inequality, including technological progress (Bound and Johnson 1992; Acemoglu 2002), demographics (Karahan and Ozkan 2013), globalization (Feenstra and Hanson 2008, Furceri and Loungani 2015), and structure of the labor market (Jaumotte and Osorio-Buitron 2015). Recently, monetary policy has been added to this list as a possible cause. In particular, some have suggested that the accommodative monetary policy stance in many advanced economies since the onset of the Great Recession may have negatively affected income and wealth distribution (Acemoglu and Johnson 2012; Stiglitz 2015). Others, however, suggest that, through its impact on employment, expansionary monetary policy may in fact have reduced inequality. Draghi (2016), for example, has recently argued that: “… monetary policy has positive distributional effects through macroeconomic channels. Most importantly, it reduces unemployment, which benefits poorer households the most.” As these disparate views suggest, the effect of (conventional and unconventional) monetary policy on inequality is difficult to sort out because there are many transmission channels. For instance, expansionary monetary policy can increase inequality through its impacts on asset prices and inflation. In the case of asset prices, the precise effect depends on the composition of household income and the impact of monetary policy on different asset prices (e.g. house prices vs. equity). But since top-income households receive higher shares of financial income than lowincome households, they tend to benefit more. In the case of inflation, expansionary monetary policy increases income inequality as low-income households hold more liquid assets than highincome ones. At the same time, other transmission channels would predict that expansionary 2

monetary policy can reduce inequality. First, an unexpected decrease in policy rates will benefit borrowers—generally those less wealthy—and hurt savers (Doepke and Schneider 2006). Second, since labor earnings at the bottom of the distribution are most affected by changes in economic activity (Heathcote and others 2010), a decrease in monetary policy rates would lead to a decline in inequality. Empirically, a growing literature has usually found the effects of monetary policy on income inequality to be relatively modest—even sometimes of different signs—and varyacross countries (Coibion and others 2012; Bivens 2015; Adam and Tzamourani 2015; Guerello 2016, O’Farrell and others 2016).1 This paper contributes to this literature by assessing how conventional monetary policy affects income inequality for a panel of 32 advanced economies and emerging market countries over the period of 1990-2013. In particular, our contribution is threefold: (i)

identifying the causal effect of monetary policy shocks on inequality—using a strategy similar to the recent literature on fiscal policy shocks (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2013; Abiad and others 2015), we construct unexpected changes in policy rates that are orthogonal to unexpected changes in growth and inflation;

1

Coibion and others (2012) find that in the United States monetary policy tightening increases inequality: highearning households (the 90th percentile) earnabout 4 percent more labor income after contractionary shocks while the labor income for low-earning households (the 10th percentile) declinesby 4 percent in the long run. Guerello (2016) find similar results using survey measures of inequality for the Euro zone countries. O’Farrell and others (2016) conclude that the effects of monetary policy on inequality through financial channels tend to be small and vary significantly for 8 OECD countries: a percentage point lower policy rate increases the net Gini coefficient by up to 0.02 percent after 3 years. Huber and Stephens (2014) find that a 100 basis point reduction in policy rates reduces the Gini coefficient by 0.4 percent. Bivens (2015) argues that expansionary monetary policy could reduce inequality if the economy is close to full employment, but that the relative distributional effects of recent Fed policy actions are small. Saiki and Frost (2014) find evidence that expansionary unconventional monetary policy increases inequality in Japan. Casiraghi and others (2016) find that recent monetary policy measures have a negligible overall effect on inequality in Italy. Adam and Tzamourani (2015), who study asset prices inflation following the adoption of unconventional monetary policy measures find that equity price increases benefit the top 5 percent of the net wealth distribution while house price inflation reduces inequality. 3

(ii)

examining the impact of monetary policy on inequality for a large sample of advanced and emerging market economies, rather than for one or a few countries as has been done thus far in most studies;

(iii)

investigating what factors determine the magnitude of the impact and whether it is symmetric across positive and negative monetary policy shocks (i.e. tightening and easing, respectively).

The analysis focuses on conventional monetary policy shocks, as exogenous unconventional monetary policy measures are harder to identify.2 At the same time, to the extent the transmission mechanisms through which conventional and unconventional monetary policy measures affect inequality are similar, we believe that our results can also provide an indication of the distributional effects of unconventional measures. The results suggest that an unexpected increase of 100 basis points in the policy rate increases inequality by about 1¼ percent in the short term—1 year after the shock—and by about 2¼ percent in the medium term—5 years after the shock. The effect is also economically significant, given the high persistence and limited variation in the Gini coefficient, and is robust across different measures of inequality (top income shares and the share of wage income in GDP). In particular, the magnitude of the medium-term effect is approximately equivalent to 1 standard deviation of the change in the Gini coefficient (2.4 percent) in the sample. The effect is larger for positive monetary policy shocks (i.e. for tightening)—especially during expansions— than for negative shocks (i.e. for easing). This asymmetry means that monetary policy shocks

2

This would require identifying unconventional monetary policy measures—such as unexpected changes in central banks’ balance sheets—that are orthogonal to changes in economic activity. Previous papers on the effects of unconventional monetary policy measures on inequality, including Saiki and Forst (2014) and Guerrello (2016), assume that changes in central banks’ balance sheets are uncorrelated to contemporaneous changes in economic activity. An assumption that is likely to be violated. 4

over the cycle may lead to persistent effects on inequality. We also find suggestive evidence that the effect increases with the share of labor income and is mitigated by redistribution policies. Finally, the results also point to substantial differences between the effects of systematic and unexpected components of monetary policy. While an unexpected increase in policy rates increases inequality, an increase in the predicted component of policy rates—the part driven by unexpected changes in growth and inflation—is associated with lower inequality. This contrast may help to explain the modest and disparate impact of changes in monetary policy rates on inequality in some of the previous literature which does not make a distinction between systematic and unexpected components. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II discusses the data, the measures of monetary policy shocks and income inequality, and the methodology. Section III presents the results on income inequality. Section IV summarizes the main findings.

2. DATA AND METHODOLOGY 2.1 Data Measures of inequality Data on income inequality are taken from the Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID 5.1).3 The SWIID includes measures of net (post-tax, post-transfers) and market (pre-tax, pre-transfers) income inequality (Gini indices) for 174 countries from 1960 to 2013. It incorporates data from several sources (United Nations University’s World Income Inequality Database, the OECD Income Distribution Database, World Bank, Eurostat, the 3

Income is defined as the sum of monetary and non-monetary income from labour, monetary income from capital, monetary social security transfers (including work-related insurance transfers, universal transfers, and assistance transfers), and non-monetary social assistance transfers, as well as monetary and non-monetary private transfers, less the amount of income taxes and social contributions paid. See http://fsolt.org/swiid/ for more details. 5

Luxembourg Income Study) and standardizes it.4 As a robustness check, we use data on top income shares from the World Top Incomes Databases (WTID) and on the share of wage income in GDP from the OECD. Gini coefficients are theoretically bounded between 0 (each reference unit receives an equal share of income) and 100 (a single reference unit receives all income). In our sample, they range from 18 to 54 for net measures and from 30 to 57 for gross measures, with higher levels of inequality typically recorded for developing countries (Table 1). Within-country income inequality has been on the rise, especially in advanced economies. Measures of inequality based on Gini coefficients of market and net incomes (income net of transfers and taxes) have increased substantially since 1990 in most of the developed world (Figure 1). Fiscal redistribution, the difference between market and net inequality, played an important role in cushioning net income inequality in advanced economies: between 1990 and 2012, market income inequality in advanced economies increased by more than 5 percentage points compared to a 3-percentage point increase in inequality based on net income.

Monetary policy shocks While changes in monetary policy rates are likely to not be driven by inequality (insofar as inequality is not a target of central banks), economic conditions can influence—at least in the short term—both inequality and monetary policy actions. Therefore, estimating the causal effect of monetary policy on inequality requires using “exogenous” monetary policy shocks. We

4

The SWIID starts from the Gini indexes of the Luxemburg Income Study (LIS)—considered fully comparable data—and the Gini indexes in the source data. In the SWIID 5.1, the source data includes ten thousand Gini indexes from 1960 to 2014 based on all or nearly all the countries' population and for which there is sufficient information to identify the equivalence scale and welfare definition used in the calculation. Then, model-based multiple imputation is employed to estimate the missing observation of the LIS starting from the source data. See Solt 2016 for details on the methodology. 6

follow the approach developed by Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) to identify fiscal policy shocks. We proceed in two steps. First, using forecasts from Consensus Economics, we compute unexpected changes in policy rates (proxied by short-term rates) using the forecast error of the policy (short-term) rates (𝐹𝐸𝑡𝑖 )—defined as the difference between the actual policy short-term rates at the end of the year (𝑆𝑇𝑡𝑟 ) and the rate expected by analysts as of beginning of October for the end of the same year (𝐶𝑇𝑡𝑟 ):5 𝑟 𝑟 𝑟 𝑟 𝑟 𝑟 𝑟 𝐹𝐸𝑖,𝑡 = 𝑆𝑇𝑖,𝑡 − 𝐶𝑇𝑖,𝑡 = (𝑆𝑇𝑖,𝑡 − 𝑆𝑇𝑖,𝑡−1 ) − (𝐶𝑇𝑖,𝑡 − 𝑆𝑇𝑖,𝑡−1 )

(1)

We then regress for each country the forecast errors of the policy rates (𝑆𝑇𝑡𝑟 ) on similarly computed forecast errors of inflation (𝐹𝐸 𝑖𝑛𝑓 ) and output growth (𝐹𝐸 𝑔 ): 𝑖𝑛𝑓

𝑔

𝑟 𝐹𝐸𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼𝑖 + 𝛽𝐹𝐸𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛾𝐹𝐸𝑖,𝑡 + 𝜖𝑖,𝑡 𝑖𝑛𝑓

(2)

𝑔

where 𝐹𝐸𝑖,𝑡 (𝐹𝐸𝑖,𝑡 ) is the difference between the CPI inflation (GDP growth) at the end of the year and the inflation (GDP growth) expected by analysts as of beginning of October for the end of the same year; the residuals—𝜖𝑖,𝑡 — capture exogenous monetary policy shocks (MP).6 Monetary policy shocks are identified for each country covered in Consensus Economics (see Table A1 for the list of countries). This methodology overcomes two problems that may otherwise confound the causal estimation of the effect of monetary policy shocks on inequality. First, using forecast errors eliminates the problem of “policy foresight” (see Forni and Gambetti 2010; Leeper, Richter, and Walker 2012; Leeper, Walker, and Yang 2013; and Ben Zeev and Pappa 2014). Agents may

5

The Consensus Economics publications report forecasts for short-term (3-months) rates at the end of the next 3 months. We use the publications released at the beginning of October of each year to get a forecast for the shortterm rate at the end of the year. 6

See Table 1 for descriptive statistics of these shocks and Appendix I for their density distribution. 7

receive news about changes in monetary policy in advance and may alter their consumption and investment behaviour well before the changes in policy occur. An econometrician who uses just the information contained in the change in actual policy rate would be relying on a smaller information set than that used by economic agents, leading to inconsistent estimates of the effects of monetary policy shocks.7 In contrast, by using forecast errors in policy rates this methodology effectively aligns the economic agents’ and the econometrician’s information sets. Second, by purging news (that is, unexpected changes) in growth and inflation from the forecast errors in short-term rate we significantly reduce the likelihood that the estimates capture the potentially endogenous response of monetary policy to changes in growth or inflation. To check the validity of the shocks constructed we perform two exercises. In the first, we compare the evolution of these shocks for the United States with those identified by Romer and Romer (2004). Panel A of Figure 2 shows that the two shocks series exhibit a very similar pattern and are highly correlated (correlation about 0.8). In particular, the shocks we constructed match very well the large monetary policy contractions and expansions identified by Romer and Romer (2004) in the last 20 years. As a second exercise, we check whether the effects of our shocks on key macroeconomic variables, such as output, unemployment, and inflation, are comparable with those reported in the literature, in particular by Romer and Romer (2004) for the United States.8 For this purpose, we estimate the response of these variables to monetary policy shocks using the local projection

7

Leeper, Richter, and Walker (2012) demonstrate the potentially serious econometric problems that result from fiscal foresight, showing that when agents foresee changes in fiscal policy, the resulting time series have a nonfundamental representation. 8

We use annual data from the IMF WEO (2016) on unemployment rate, GDP growth and CPI inflation. While correctly assessing the impact of these shocks on variables that are available at monthly or quarterly frequency would require higher frequency shocks, the exercise is still useful to check the validity of these shocks and to understand the transmission channels through which they affect inequality. 8

method proposed by Jorda (2005)—see next section for details—for an unbalanced panel of 32 economies from 1990 to 2013.9 The results reported in Figure 3 show that monetary policy shocks have statistically significant and somewhat persistent effects on output, unemployment, and inflation. Moreover, the estimated average effects in our sample, particularly for unemployment, are comparable and not statistically different from the one reported by Romer and Romer (2004) for the United States.10 2.2 Methodology To estimate the impact of monetary policy shocks on (the level of) inequality in the short and medium term, we follow the method proposed by Jorda (2005), which consists of estimating impulse response functions (IRFs) directly from local projections. Specifically, for each future period k the following equation is estimated on annual data: 𝑘 𝑦𝑖,𝑡+𝑘 − 𝑦𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼𝑖𝑘 + 𝜗𝑡𝑘 + 𝛽 𝑘 𝑀𝑃𝑖,𝑡 + 𝜋 𝑘 𝑋𝑖,𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡

(3)

where 𝑦 is the (log) of net income inequality; 𝑀𝑃𝑖,𝑡 are exogenous monetary policy shocks; 𝑎𝑖 are country fixed effects included to control for unobserved cross-country heterogeneity of inequality and also to control for the fact that in some countries inequality is measured using income data while in other countries using consumption data ; 𝜗𝑡 are time fixed effects to control for global shocks; X is a set of controls including lagged monetary policy shocks and lagged changes in inequality. The baseline analysis focuses on net rather than gross income for two reasons. First, the source of data (the Luxembourg Income Study) through which gross market Gini data are

9

Given the limited time series, we cannot examine the effect of our US shocks on US macroeconomic series.

10

See Coibion (2012) for a discussion of the range of plausible values for the effects of monetary policy shocks. 9

computed in the SWIID dataset are based on household disposable income, and therefore are likely to be less subject to measurement errors.11 Second, we want to capture the overall effects of monetary policy shocks on inequality including through effects on redistribution (that is, tax and transfers). That said, the results based on market income are robust and not statistically different from those based on net income. Equation (3) is estimated for k=0, …, 4—that is, up to five years after the shock. Impulseresponse functions are computed using the estimated coefficients 𝛽 𝑘 and the confidence intervals using the estimated standard errors of these coefficients. The sample period—determined by the availability of the series of monetary policy shocks and inequality—is from 1990 to 2013. The estimates for 32 advanced economies and emerging market countries are based on clustered robust standard errors.

3. RESULTS 3.1 Baseline Results and Robustness Checks Baseline The results obtained by estimating Equation 3 using the Gini coefficient for disposable income (net Gini) as the measure of inequality are presented in Figure 4 (see also Table 2). The figure shows the estimated effect of unanticipated monetary policy shocks and the associated confidence bands (dotted lines). The results show that monetary policy tightening leads to a long-lasting increase in income inequality. An unanticipated policy rate increase of 100 basis increases the Gini index by about 1¼ in the short term—1 year after the shock—and by about 2¼

11

See LIS at: http://www.lisdatacenter.org/data-access/key-figures/disposable-household-income/ 10

percent in the medium term—5 years after the shock. The effect eventually levels off, after seven years, at about 2½ percent. The effect is also economically significant given the high persistence and limited variation in the Gini coefficient. The magnitude of the medium-term effect is approximately equivalent to 1 standard deviation of the change in the Gini coefficient (2.4 percent) in the sample—or to about 8 percentage points—and is larger than the sample average cumulative increase of the Gini coefficient over five consecutive years (about 2 percent). The effect is also slightly larger than—even though not statistically different from—the one found by Coibion and others (2012) for the United States (about 3-5 percentage points—that is, about 1.1-1.5 percent).

Robustness checks To check the robustness of the results, several alternative estimations are carried out. First, we re-estimate equation (3) using the gross (market income) Gini as a measure of inequality to assess whether the results are driven by the effect of monetary policy on redistribution—that is, the difference between gross and net Gini. An increase in policy rates can affect negatively economic activity and therefore reduce budget resources for distribution, which would produce larger estimates on net inequality. The results presented in Panel A of Figure 5 (Table 3A) suggest that the effects on gross inequality, albeit slightly smaller, are not statistically different from those obtained for net inequality. Second, we re-estimate equation (3) only for advanced economies to check whether the results are driven by relatively larger forecast errors in emerging market economies.12 The results

12

The classification of advanced and emerging market economies used in the paper is the one of the IMF WEO (2017). 11

obtained for this sample are quantitatively similar to and not statistically significantly different from those obtained for the full sample (Panel B, Figure 5; Table 3A). Third, since policy rates in many advanced countries have approached their zero lower bounds and have not changed much in recent years, we re-estimate equation (3) only for the 1990-2007 sample. The results presented in Panel C of Figure 5 (Table 3A) suggest that the effects of monetary policy shocks have been larger before 2008, with an unanticipated policy rate shock of 100 basis increasing the Gini index by about 1½ percent in the short term—1 year after the shock—and by about 2¾ percent in the medium term—5 years after the shock. The fact that the effect is larger than the one based on the full sample is not surprising given the limited movements in policy rates in many advanced economies in recent years. That said, in this case too the effects are not statistically significantly different from those presented in the baseline. We also checked whether the effect of monetary policy shocks on inequality could be biased because of endogeneity, as unobserved factors influencing inequality may also affect the magnitude of the monetary policy shocks. We re-estimate equation (3) including as additional controls: (i) dummies for recessions—proxied here as periods of negative growth—which may directly affect inequality (Atkinson and Morelli 2011; Agnello and Sousa 2012) as well as the response of monetary policy to economic conditions, beyond the “normal” effect of growth news on policy rates forecast errors; (ii) change in the budget balance, since fiscal consolidation typically increases inequality (Ball and others 2013) and may affect the response of monetary policy to shocks as well as its impact on economic activity. The results of this exercise are reported in Panel D of Figure 5 (Table 3A) and confirm the robustness of our results. We additionally checked whether the effects of monetary policy shocks on inequality are robust to the inclusion of other drivers of income inequality. In particular, we considered as

12

controls changes in: (i) trade openness (measured as the sum of exports and imports in GDP); (ii) financial openness (defined as the share of total assets and liabilities to GDP); (iii) financial depth (proxied by the private credit-to-GDP ratio); and (iv) labor market regulation (proxied by the Economic Freedom of the World’s indicator of labor market regulation).13 The results also in this case are very similar to those obtained in this baseline (Figure 5, Panel E; Table 3A), further validating that the monetary policy shocks identified in the analysis can be deemed as exogenous. Finally, the results are robust to different lags in the dependent variables and in the monetary policy shocks (Figure 5, Panel F; Table 3B). 3.2 Different measures of inequality The Gini index is the most commonly used measured of inequality, mostly owing to its wider data availability compared to other measures. However, some of the observations in the SWIID database are obtained by model-based imputations and therefore subject to measurement errors (Solt, 2016). 14 While this is less the case for the sample of economies considered in the analysis, we check the validity of our results by re-estimating equation (3) using two alternate measures of inequality: (i) the top income share series (10 , 5, and 1 percent) from the World Top Incomes Databases (WTID); (ii) the share of wage income in GDP from the OECD. Starting with the first of these measures, the results presented in Figure 6 (Table 4) confirm that monetary policy tightening increases inequality. A 100 basis points monetary policy shock

13

The source of the data for these variables are respectively: IMF WEO; Lane and Milesi Ferretti (2007); the World Bank Development Indicator; the Economic Freedom of the World database. 14

The index is also criticized for being more sensitive to the income of the middle class and not capturing the exact distribution of income as identified by the Lorenz curve. 13

has a significant and persistent effect on all top income shares, with the effect being larger for the top 1 percent—about 0.8 percentage point four years after the shock. Similarly, we find that an unexpected 100 basis points increase in the policy rates lead to a statistically significant and persistent decline in the share of wage income in GDP—about ½ percentage point in the short term and about 1½ percentage points in the medium term (Figure 7; Table 4). 3.3 Type of monetary policy shocks Positive versus negative monetary policy shocks Does the direction of the monetary policy shock matter for inequality? There is a growing consensus in the literature (see Barnichon and Mattes 2015, and references cited therein) that the effects of positive monetary policy shocks—that is, a contractionary monetary policy—on economic activity are larger than the effects of negative monetary policy shocks—that is, an expansionary policy. This asymmetry in the monetary policy transmission can reflect, for instance, credit market imperfections. With higher interest rates, less liquid firms cannot access external financing and cut investment and demand for credit (Bernanke and Blinder, 1988); also, smaller less liquid banks might face funding shocks and cut the supply of credit (Kashyap and Stein, 2000).15 To test this hypothesis, we re-estimate the following version of equation (3):

𝑘 𝑦𝑖,𝑡+𝑘 − 𝑦𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼𝑖𝑘 + 𝜗𝑡𝑘 + 𝛽+𝑘 𝐷𝑖,𝑡 𝑀𝑃𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽−𝑘 (1 − 𝐷𝑖,𝑡 )𝑀𝑃𝑖,𝑡 + 𝜋 𝑘 𝑋𝑖,𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 ,

(4)

where D is a dummy variable that takes value one for positive monetary policy shocks and zero otherwise. 15

Florio (2004) and references therein. 14

The results show that the direction of monetary policy shocks does matter. A positive monetary policy shock (unexpected contractionary policy) leads to a statistically significant increase in inequality in the medium term (about 4½ percent). In contrast, the medium-term effect of negative monetary policy shocks (unexpected easing of policy) is not statistically significantly different from zero (Figure 8). In addition, this difference in the response is statistically significant at 5 percent (Table 5).

Exogenous versus growth-driven monetary policy shocks The results of the previous section have shown that innovations in policy rates that are orthogonal to innovations in output growth and inflation lead to a persistent increase in inequality. However, an interesting question at the current juncture is whether an increase in policy rates due to normalization in economic activity—such as the recent lift-off of policy rates in the United States—also has negative distributional consequences. To answer this question, we proceed in two steps (following a procedure used by ̂ as its predicted value of Zdzienicka and others, 2015, in a different context). First, we define 𝐹𝐸 ̂ . equation (2). Second, we modify Equation (3) to trace the response of inequality to FE and 𝐹𝐸 In particular, the following specification is estimated: 𝑘 𝑘 𝑘 ̂ 𝑦𝑖,𝑡+𝑘 − 𝑦𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼𝑖𝑘 + 𝜗𝑡𝑘 + 𝛽1𝑘 𝐹𝐸 𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽2 𝐹𝐸𝑖,𝑡 + 𝜋 𝑋𝑖,𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 ,

(5)

̂ is its predicted value, and the difference where FE is the forecast error in policy rates, 𝐹𝐸 between these two variables is the monetary policy shock (MP) considered in our analysis thus far. The results of estimating Equation (5) suggest that changes in policy rates that are driven by ̂ unexpected changes in growth and inflation (i.e. changes in 𝐹𝐸 𝑖,𝑡 ) are associated with a decrease 15

in inequality (Figure 9, Panel A). This result is likely driven by the effect of improved economic conditions on inequality, rather than the effect of changes in the policy rate per se, and therefore should not be interpreted as a causal effect. Nevertheless, it is informative for the debate on the effect of the current lift-off in policy rates in some economies, including the United States. In contrast, the results suggest that unanticipated changes in policy rates (the forecast errors in policy rates), either driven by economic developments or exogenous, increase inequality in the short and medium term, even though their effect on inequality is smaller than for unanticipated exogenous changes (Figure 9, Panel B). The difference in the response of inequality to these two shocks is statistically significant at 1 percent (Table 6). Additionally, we look at the response of inequality to changes in the policy rates (i.e. to changes in 𝑆𝑇𝑡𝑟 rather than to the forecast errors). The results presented in Figure 9 panel C show that the response of inequality to a 100 basis point increase in the policy rate is positive but much smaller—only about 0.14 percent after a year of the shock—and less persistent than the one in the baseline. As discussed before, this smaller effect is likely to be the result of two sources of bias. The first is that changes in policy rates may well be driven by changes in economic activity, and hence may reflect the impacts of activity on inequality and not purely that of the policy rate. The second is monetary policy foresight: agents may receive news about changes in monetary policy in advance and alter their consumption and investment behaviour well before the changes take place. Finally, we have also tested whether the level of the interest rate has a direct effect on inequality. The results reported in the annex suggest that this is not the case (Figure A2).

16

3.4 Role of Macroeconomic Conditions Role of business cycle Previous empirical evidence regarding the effect of monetary policy on economic activity suggests that while the effects of monetary policy tightening are larger in periods of economic expansions, monetary policy easing has only effects in times of recessions (see, for example, Barnichon and Matthes 2015). Are there similar asymmetric effects of monetary policy shock on inequality? To answer this question, we estimate the following specification: 𝑦𝑖,𝑡+𝑘 − 𝑦𝑖,𝑡 = α𝑘𝑖 + ϑ𝑘𝑡 + β1𝑘 𝐺(𝑧𝑖𝑡 )𝑀𝑃𝑖,𝑡 + β𝑘2 (1 − 𝐺(𝑧𝑖𝑡 ))𝑀𝑃𝑖,𝑡 + ε𝑘𝑖,𝑡,

(6)

with exp(−γ𝑧 )

𝐺(𝑧𝑖𝑡 ) = 1+exp(−γ𝑧𝑖𝑡 ) , 𝑖𝑡

γ > 0,

in which z is an indicator of the business cycle normalized to have zero mean and unit variance, and G(zit) is the corresponding smooth transition function between states.16 Our analysis uses contemporaneous (yearly) GDP growth as a measure of the business cycle. The identifying assumption is that monetary policy shocks do not affect whether the economy remains in either recession or expansion at the time of the shock.17

16

Following Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012), we use 𝛾 = 1.5 for the analysis of recessions and expansions.

17

This finding is robust to different specifications (interacting the shock with a recession dummy instead of a transition function of the state of the economy), definitions of recessions (recessions defined as periods of negative growth or when growth is below the country average GDP growth) and to the use of lagged growth to construct the smooth transition function across states, thus relaxing the assumption that monetary policy shocks do not affect the state of the economy at time t. 17

As discussed in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013a, 2013b), the local projections approach to estimating non-linear effects is equivalent to the smooth transition autoregressive (STAR) model developed by Granger and Teräsvirta (1993). The main advantage of the local projection approach compared to estimating SVARs for each regime is that it uses a larger number of observations to compute the impulse response functions of only the dependent variables of interest, improving the stability and precision of the estimates. This estimation strategy can also more easily handle the possible correlation of the standard errors within countries, by clustering at the country level.18 While monetary policy shocks tend to have, on average, larger effects on inequality during periods of expansions than in recessions (Figure 10, Panel A and B; Table 5), there is significant heterogeneity in the response of inequality to positive and negative shocks during the business cycle. In particular, estimating Equation (6) separately for positive and negative shocks suggests that while positive shocks have statistically significant effects only in periods of economic expansions (Figure 10, Panel C and D), negative shocks have statistically significant effects only during recessions (Figure 10, Panel E and F).19 Finally, we also tested whether the effect of monetary policy shocks on inequality depends on the level of interest rates. The results reported in Figure A3 of the Annex suggest that the response of inequality to monetary policy shocks is similar between period of low and high interest rates.

18

The standard errors of the estimated coefficients discussed below are even smaller if we allow for correlation in the standard errors across countries and cluster at the time level. 19

The effects are similar when these interactions are jointly estimated. 18

Role of labor earnings As discussed in the introduction, an important channel through which an increase in monetary policy rates can lead to an increase in inequality is through a heterogeneous impact on labor earnings for difference income groups. In particular, since labor earnings at the bottom of the distribution are most affected by changes in economic activity (Heathcote and others 2010), an increase in policy rates would lead to an increase in inequality. Therefore, if this channel is effective, one should expect that, other things equal, the effect of monetary policy shocks on inequality is an increasing function of the share of labor earnings. To test this hypothesis, we re-estimate a specification similar to equation (6), in which z is a normalized variable of the share of labor income in total income.20 The results in Figure 11 show that the effect of monetary policy shocks on inequality—in the first five years after the shock—is larger the higher are the labor shares. However, given the relatively large standard errors, the difference between low and high labor share is not statistically significant (Table 6). Role of redistribution policies Finally, we test whether the effect of monetary policy shocks on inequality depends on the size of redistribution policies. To examine this issue, we re-estimate a specification similar to equation (6), in which z is a normalized variable of the level of redistribution, proxied by the difference between market and net inequality. The results suggest that redistribution policies matter (Figure 12; Table 6). In particular, while the effect of monetary policy shocks on inequality is positive and statistically significant in situations of limited redistribution policies (that is, those with redistribution below the average in the distribution of redistribution in the

20

We consider the time-average to reduce endogeneity due to the possible effect on inequality on the share of labor income. 19

sample), the effect is not statistically significantly different from zero in countries with relatively high redistribution.21

4. CONCLUSIONS Rising inequality and the accommodative monetary policy stance in many advanced economies have brought the role of conventional and unconventional monetary policy in affecting inequality to the forefront of policy discussions. Concerns have risen that the recent accommodative monetary policy stance in many advanced economies may negatively affect income and wealth distribution (Acemoglu and Johnson 2012; Stiglitz 2015). We shed light on this issue by estimating the causal effect of conventional monetary policy shocks on inequality for a panel of 32 advanced and emerging market economies. While the analysis focuses on conventional monetary policy shocks, as exogenous unconventional monetary policy measures are harder to identify, we do believe that the results can also provide indication of the effect of unconventional measures to the extent the transmission mechanisms through which conventional and unconventional monetary policy measures affect inequality are similar. Using unexpected changes in monetary policy rates that are orthogonal to unexpected changes in economic activity and inflation, we find that an unexpected decrease of 100 basis points in the policy rate reduces, on average, income inequality by about 1¼ percent in the short term and by about 2¼ percent in the medium term. The effect is also economically significant, given the high persistence and limited variation in the Gini coefficient. The magnitude of the medium-term effect is approximately equivalent to a standard deviation of the change in the Gini

21

Similar results are obtained by splitting the sample in countries with inequality above average (median) inequality and countries with inequality below average. 20

coefficient (2.4 percent) in the sample. The effect also varies over time, depending on the type of the shocks (tightening versus expansionary monetary policy) and the state of the business cycle: the effect is larger for positive monetary policy shocks, especially during expansions. In addition, we find suggestive evidence that the effect increases with the share of labor income and is mitigated by redistribution policies. Finally, while an unexpected increase in policy rates increases inequality, predictable changes in policy rates driven by an improvement in economic conditions (as reflected in higher forecasts of growth and inflation) are associated with lower inequality. As Voinea and Monnin (2017) note, “central bankers have long been discreet about the impacts of monetary policy and inequality”. However, the very accommodative monetary policies followed since the onset of the Great Recession, combined with concerns over rising inequality, have brought discussions of the possible links between monetary policy and inequality into the open. Our results point to the importance of making a distinction between the systematic (predictable) component of policy and monetary policy shocks. We find that expansionary monetary policy shocks lower income inequality. Likewise, contractionary monetary policy shocks raise inequality and their quantitative impact (in absolute terms) is larger than the impact of expansionary monetary policy. This result is particularly salient as many central banks contemplate a ‘lift-off’ from very low interest rates. While output gaps and the behaviour of inflation relative to target are likely to be the dominant considerations in setting policy interest rates, central banks may want to be aware of the distributional impacts of both systematic policy and shocks for a couple of reasons. First, as Voinea and Monnin (2017) write, “solving inequality is certainly not the primary job of central banks, but it is a factor that they should not ignore. Securing balanced growth and a fair distribution of the benefits and costs of

21

price stability … is a public good, too.” Second, recent research suggests that the distribution of income—and changes in that distribution—may itself affect the transmission mechanism of monetary policy. Hence, even if the central bank is primarily concerned with the aggregate effects of its policies, understanding the impacts of policies on inequality may be important.

22

References Acemoglu, D., and Johnson, S., (2012) ‘Who Captured the Fed?’, New York Times, 29. Auerbach, A., and Gorodnichenko, Y., 2013a, “Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion.” In Fiscal Policy After the Financial Crisis, eds. Alberto Alesina and Francesco Giavazzi, NBER Books, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., Cambridge, Massachusetts. Auerbach, A., and Gorodnichenko, Y., . 2013b. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2): 1–27. Ben Zeev, Nadav, and Evi Pappa. 2014. “Chronicle of a War Foretold: The Macroeconomic Effects of Anticipated Defense Spending Shocks.” CEPR Discussion Paper 9948, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. Bernanke, B. S., (2015), “Monetary Policy and Inequality” available at http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/ben-bernanke/posts/2015/06/01-monetary-policy-andinequality. Bernanke, B. S., and Kuttner, K. N., (2005), “What explains the stock market’s reaction to Federal Reserve policy?”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 60/3, pp. 1221-1257. Bitler, M., and Hoynes, H., (2015) ‘Heterogeneity in the Impact of Economic Cycles and the Great Recession: Effects Within and Across the Income Distribution’, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 2015, 105(5): 154-160. Bivens, J., (2015) ‘Gauging the impact of the Fed on inequality during the Great Recession’, Brookings Institution Working Paper. Card, D., (2001), “The effect of unions on wage inequality in the U.S. labor market,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 54(2), pp. 296-315. Claeys, Grégory (2014) ‘The (not so) Unconventional Monetary Policy of the European Central

23

Bank since 2008’, paper for the Monetary Dialogue discussions in the Economic and Monetary Affairs Committee (ECON) of the European Parliament, Claeys, Grégory, Zsolt Darvas, Alvaro Leandro and Thomas Walsh (2015)” The effects of UltraLoose Monetary Policies on inequalities,” Policy Contribution 2015/09, Bruegel. Coibion, O., “Are the Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks Big or Small?”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 4, No. 2 (April 2012), pp. 1-32. Coibion, O., Y. Gorodnichenko, L. Kueng and J. Silvia (2012) ‘Innocent bystanders? Monetary policy and inequality in the US’, Working Paper 18170, National Bureau of Economic Research. Doepke, M., and M. Schneider (2006), “Inflation and the redistribution of nominal wealth,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 114/6, pp. 1069–1097. Draghi, Marion (2016), “Stability, Equity and Monetary Policy” 2nd DIW Europe Lecture, http://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2016/html/sp161025.en.html Feenstra, R. and G. Hanson (2004), “Global production sharing and rising inequality: A survey of trade and wages”, Chapter 6 of Part I in K. M. Choi and J. Harrigan (eds), Handbook of International Trade. Forni, Mario, and Luca Gambetti. 2010. “Fiscal Foresight and the Effects of Government Spending.” Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 7840. Guerello, Chiara (2016). “Conventional and Unconventional Monetary Policy vs. Household Income Distribution: An Empirical Analysis for the Euro Area,” (mimeo). Jaumotte, F. and C. Osorio Buitron (2015), “Inequality and labor market institutions”, IMF Staff Discussion Note, No. 15/14.

24

Karahan, F., and Ozkan, S., (2013), “On the persistence of income shocks over the life cycle: Evidence, theory, and implications”, Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 16/3, pp. 452– 476. Leeper, Eric M., Alexander W. Richter, and Todd B. Walker. 2012. “Quantitative Effects of Fiscal Foresight.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2): 115–44. Leeper, Eric M., Todd B. Walker, and Shu-Chun S. Yang. 2013. “Fiscal Foresight and Information Flows.” Econometrica 81 (3): 1115–45. O’Farrell, R., Ł. Rawdanowicz and K. Inaba (2016), "Monetary Policy and Inequality", OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1281, OECD Publishing, Paris. DOI: Saiki, A., and J. Frost (2014) ‘Does unconventional monetary policy affect inequality? Evidence from Japan’, Applied Economics, 46(36), 4445-4454. Stiglitz, J. (2015) ‘New theoretical perspectives on the distribution of income and wealth among individuals: Part IV: Land and Credit’, Working Paper 21192, National Bureau of Economic Research. Voinea, Liviu and Pierre Monnin (2017), “Inequality should matter for Central Banks,” CEP, 16 February 2017. Yellen, J. (2014), “Perspectives on inequality and opportunity from the survey of consumer finances”, speech at the Conference on Economic Opportunity and Inequality, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, Massachusetts, October 17. Zdzienicka, A., S. Chen, F. Diaz Kalan, S. Laseen, and K. Svirydzenka (2015) “Effects of Monetary and Macroprudential Policies on Financial Conditions: Evidence form the United States”, IMF Working Paper, 15/288.

25

Acknowledgements We would like to thank editor Kees G. Koedijk, Pierre Monnin and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. We are thankful to participants at the IMF-CEP Workshop on monetary policy and inequality, and to seminar participants at the ILO, IMF and ECB. We thank Zidong An for outstanding research assistance. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors, and not necessarily those of the International Monetary Fund. This research did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.

26

Figure 1. Evolution of Inequality (change, 1990-2013) Advanced economies

Emerging markets

Source: Solt (2016).

Figure 2 Exogenous Monetary Policy Shocks for the United States (percentage points) 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 -0.5 -1 -1.5

correlation=0.79

-2 Ours

R&R

Note: “Ours” refers to the monetary policy shocks identified as in equations (1) and (2). “R&R” refers to the monetary policy shocks identified by Romer and Romer (2004). 27

Figure 3. The effect of monetary policy on output, unemployment and inflation Panel A. Output (%)

Panel B. Unemployment (ppt)

Panel C. CPI level (%)

0

0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 -0.1 -0.2

-0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8

-1 -1.2 -1.4 -1.6 -1

0

1

2

3

4

-1

0

1

2

3

4

0.4 0.2 0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 -1 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid lines denote the response to an unanticipated increase in monetary policy rates of 100 basis points, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on equation (3).

28

Figure 4. The effect of monetary policy shocks on income inequality (Net Gini), 1990-2013 (percent) 5 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid lines denote the response to an unanticipated increase in monetary policy rates of 100 basis points, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on equation (3).

29

Figure 5. The effect of monetary policy shocks on income inequality, robustness checks (percent) Panel A. Gross Inequality 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1

0

1

2

3

4 -1

Panel B. Advanced economies 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 -1

0

1

2

30

3

4

Panel C. Pre-2008 5 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Panel D. Controlling for recessions and fiscal stance 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid lines denote the response to an unanticipated increase in monetary policy rates of 100 basis points, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on equation (3).

31

Panel E. Controlling for changes in trade and financial openness, labor market regulations and financial depth

4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 -0.5 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Panel F. Different lags

4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 -0.5 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid lines denote the response to an unanticipated increase in monetary policy rates of 100 basis points, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on equation (3). Black dashed lines= no lags in dep. variable; orange dashed line= 4 lags in dep. variable; orange dotted line= 0 lags in monetary policy shocks; dotted green line= 4 lags in monetary policy shocks.

32

Figure 6. The effect of monetary policy on top income shares (percentage points)

Panel A. Top 10 percent

Panel B. Top 5 percent

Panel C. Top 1 percent

1.4 1.4

1.4

1.2

1.2

1

1

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.2

0.4

0.4

0

0.2

0.2

-0.2

0

0

1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4

-1

0

1

2

3

-1

0

1

2

3

-1

0

1

2

3

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid blue lines denote the response to an unanticipated positive (negative) monetary policy rates of 100 basis points, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on equation (3).

33

Figure 7. The effect of monetary policy shocks on the share of wage income in GDP (percentage points) 0.4 0.2 0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 -1 -1.2 -1.4 -1.6 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid lines denote the response to an unanticipated increase in monetary policy rates of 100 basis points, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on equation (3).

34

Figure 8. The effect of monetary policy on income inequality, positive vs. negative shocks (percent)

Panel A. Negative monetary policy shocks

Panel B. Positive monetary policy shocks

10 10 8

8

6

6

4

4

2

2

0

0

-2

-2

-4

-4 -1

0

1

2

3

4

-1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid blue lines denote the response to an unanticipated positive (negative) monetary policy rates of 100 basis points, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Figure 3.2. Estimates based on equation (4).

35

Figure 9. The effect of monetary policy on income inequality, exogenous vs. growth driven shocks (percent) Panel A. Growth-driven monetary policy shocks

Panel B. Innovations in policy rates

Panel C. Changes in policy rates 4

4 4

2

3

0

2

-2

3 2

1

1

0

0

-4 -6 -8

-1 -1

0

1

2

3

4

-1

0

1

2

3

4

-1 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid blue lines denote the response to, alternatively, a growth-driven increase, innovations or changes in monetary policy rates of 100 basis points; dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Figure 3.2. Growth-driven monetary policy shocks are identified as the forecast error in policy rates explained news in growth and inflation—that is, the fitted value of equation (2). Innovations in policy rates are the forecast error in policy rates. Estimates based on equation (5).

36

Figure 10. The effect of monetary policy on income inequality, the role of business cycle (percent) Panel A. Monetary policy shocks-recessions

B. Monetary policy shocks-expansions

7

7

2

2

-3

-3 -1

0

1

2

3

4

-1

Panel C. Positive monetary policy shocks-recessions

0

1

2

3

4

D. Positive policy shocks-expansions 12

17 12 7 2 -3

7 2 -3 -1

0

1

2

3

4

-1

Panel E. Negative policy shocks-recessions

0

1

2

3

4

F. Negative policy shocks-expansions

10

10

5

5

0

0

-5

-5 -1

0

1

2

3

4

-1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid blue lines denote the response to an unexpected increase (or decrease) in monetary policy rates of 100 basis points, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Figure 3.2. Estimates based on equation (6). 37

Figure 11. The effect of monetary policy on income inequality, the role of labor earnings (percent) Panel A. Very low labor share

Panel B. Very high labor share

9

9

3

3

-3

-3

-9

-9 -1

0

1

2

3

4

-1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid blue lines denote the response to an unanticipated monetary policy rates of 100 basis points in countries with relatively higher (lower) inequality, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Figure 3.2.

38

Figure 12. The effect of monetary policy on income inequality, the role of redistribution (percent) Panel A. Low redistribution

Panel B. High redistribution

9

9

7

7

5

5

3

3

1

1

-1

-1

-3

-3 -1

0

1

2

3

4

-1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid blue lines denote the response to an unanticipated monetary policy rates of 100 basis points in countries with relatively high (low) redistribution, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Figure 3.2.

39

Table1. Descriptive statistics Mean

SD

Min

Max

Net Gini

33.6

7.2

18.0

54.1

Gross Gini

45.5

5.2

30.0

57.3

Top 1 percent

11.1

4.3

5.2

23.5

Top 5 percent

24.6

5.7

14.6

38.8

Top 10 percent

35.9

6.6

23.6

50.6

Share of wage income in GDP

51.5

4.0

39.2

58.8

Monetary policy shocks

0.0

1.13

-3.9

4

Inequality

Top income shares

Table 2. The effect of monetary policy shocks on income inequality (Net Gini), 1990-2013 K=0

K=1

K=2

K=3

K=4

K=5

K=6

K=7

Gini growth(t-1)

0.176** (2.16)

0.266** (2.53)

0.080 (0.58)

-0.074 (-0.49)

-0.175 (-1.12)

-0.217 (-1.27)

-0.282 (-1.47)

-0.207 (-0.94)

Gini growth(t-2)

0.071 (1.17)

-0.139 (-1.58)

-0.274** (-2.41)

-0.346*** (-2.81)

-0.305** (-2.27)

-0.335** (-2.25)

-0.323* (-1.74)

-0.523** (-3.02)

Monetary policy shock (t)

0.531 (1.56)

1.176** (2.13)

1.886*** (2.88)

2.018*** (2.59)

2.154** (2.40)

2.444** (2.16)

2.147* (1.72)

2.662** (2.03)

Monetary policy shock (t-1)

0.441 (1.62)

0.389 (1.08)

0.074 (0.16)

0.160 (0.30)

0.221 (0.34)

0.366 (0.51)

0.246 (0.30)

-0.581 (-0.71)

Monetary policy shock (t-2)

-0.034 (-0.16)

-0.114 (-0.36)

0.278 (0.74)

0.364 (0.84)

0.235 (0.49)

-0.085 (-0.17)

-0.585 (-0.97)

-0.164 (-0.25)

N 467 439 409 379 349 323 295 267 2 R 0.16 0.18 0.19 0.24 0.28 0.33 0.37 0.43 Note: T-statistics based on robust clustered standard errors in parenthesis. ***,**,* denote significance at 1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent, respectively. Estimates based on equation (3).

40

Table 3a. The medium-term effect of monetary policy shocks on income inequality, robustness check-1 Gross

AEs

Pre-2008

Control 1

Control 2

Gini growth(t-1)

-0.176 (-1.26)

-0.131 (-0.74)

-0.194 (-1.19)

-0.337*** (-2.85)

-0.266 (-1.56)

Gini growth(t-2)

-0.248* (-1.87)

-0.236 (-1.58)

-0.299* (-2.17)

-0.359*** (-3.18)

-0.339** (-2.32)

Monetary policy shock (t)

1.717** (1.99)

2.332** (2.20)

2.154** (2.20)

2.154** (1.88)

2.374** (2.40)

Monetary policy shock (t-1)

0.077 (0.13)

0.534 (0.69)

0.221 (0.79)

-0.408 (-0.52)

1.033 (1.58)

Monetary policy shock (t-2)

0.110 (0.23)

0.197 (0.96)

0.235 (0.38)

0.308 (0.52)

0.596 (1.13)

N 349 282 319 271 280 R2 0.30 0.17 0.29 0.36 0.36 Note: T-statistics based on robust clustered standard errors in parenthesis. ***,**,* denote significance at 1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent, respectively. Estimates based on equation (3). Control1=recession dummies and changes in the budget balance-to-GDP ratio; Control2=changes in trade and financial openness, changes in labor market regulations and changes in the financial depth,

Table 3b. The medium-term effect of monetary policy shocks on income inequality, robustness check-2

Monetary policy shock (t)

No lags in Gini growth

Four lags in Gini growth

No lags in monetary policy shocks

Four lags in monetary policy shocks

2.627** (2.28)

2.280** (2.12)

1.986* (1.76)

1.988** (1.75)

N 349 347 376 322 2 R 0.25 0.33 0.25 0.29 Note: T-statistics based on robust clustered standard errors in parenthesis. ***,**,* denote significance at 1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent, respectively. Estimates based on equation (3).

41

Table 4. The medium-term effect of monetary policy shocks on income distribution Top 10 %

Top 5 %

Top 1 %

Labor share

Dep. Variable (t-1)

-0.285* (-1.95)

-0.396** (-2.36)

-0.537*** (-2.88)

-0.145 (-0.70)

Dep. Variable (t-2)

-0.356* (-1.77)

-0.428* (-1.83)

-0.517** (-2.06)

-0.278 (-1.39)

Monetary policy shock (t)

0.596* (1.92) 0.078 (0.42)

0.753** (2.45) 0.218 (1.15)

0.848*** (3.16) 0.349** (2.03)

-0.804* (1.95) 0.229 (0.69)

-0.067 (-0.48)

0.031 (0.21)

0.117 (0.81)

-0.149 (-0.48)

Monetary policy shock (t-1) Monetary policy shock (t-2)

N 97 97 97 153 2 R 0.66 0.68 0.71 0.35 Note: T-statistics based on robust clustered standard errors in parenthesis. ***,**,* denote significance at 1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent, respectively. Estimates based on equation (3).

Table 5. The medium-term effect of monetary policy shocks on income distribution Positive vs. negative monetary policy shocks

Positive Monetary policy shock (t) Negative Monetary policy shock (t) F-test difference

Positive--Recessions vs. expansions

Negative--Recessions vs. expansions

4.415*** (2.60) -0.583 (-0.36) 3.93**

Positive Monetary policy shock (t)— recessions

2.923 (1.33)

Positive Monetary policy shock (t)— expansions F-test difference

5.416** (2.50) 0.49

Negative Monetary policy shock (t)— recessions

5.033* (1.71)

Negative Monetary policy shock (t)— expansions F-test difference

0.705 (0.27) 0.79

N 349 349 349 R2 0.29 0.52 0.52 Note: T-statistics based on robust clustered standard errors in parenthesis. ***,**,* denote significance at 1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent, respectively. Estimates based on equation (4) and (6), respectively. Controls included but not reported. 42

Table 6. The medium-term effect of monetary policy shocks on income distribution Growth driven monetary policy shocks vs. innovations in policy rates

Growth driven monetary policy shock (t)

Changes in policy rates

-4.349*** (-3.43) 2.053** (2.40)

Innovation in policy rates (t) Changes in policy rates

0.224* (1.61)

F-test difference

12.57***

N 349 370 R2 0.53 0.25 Note: T-statistics based on robust clustered standard errors in parenthesis. ***,**,* denote significance at 1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent, respectively. Estimates based on equation (5) and (3), respectively.

Table 7. The medium-term effect of monetary policy shocks on income distribution Role of labor share

Monetary policy shock (t)—low labor share

Role of redistribution

4.867 108) 1.435 (0.57) 0.45

Monetary policy shock (t)—high labor share F-test difference Monetary policy shock (t)—low redistribution

4.604*** (-3.43) 1.159 (0.74) 1.05

Monetary policy shock (t)—high redistribution F-test difference

N 349 349 R2 0.53 0.52 Note: T-statistics based on robust clustered standard errors in parenthesis. ***,**,* denote significance at 1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent, respectively. Estimates based on equation (3).

43

Annex Table A1. List of countries in the sample Advanced Economies

Emerging Market Countries

Australia Canada Czech Republic France Germany Hong Kong SAR Italy Japan Korea Netherlands New Zealand Norway Singapore Slovak Republic Spain Sweden Switzerland Taiwan Province of China United Kingdom United States

Argentina Brazil Chile Hungary India Indonesia Malaysia Mexico Philippines Poland Thailand Turkey

Note: the classification of advanced and emerging market economies is based on the IMF WEO (2017).

44

Figure A1. Distribution of monetary policy shocks (percentage points)

.3 .2 0

.1

kdensity res

.4

.5

All Countries

-4

-2

0 x

2

4

0

.2

kdensity res

.4

.6

Advanced Economies

-4

-2

0 x

2

4

0

.1

kdensity res

.2

.3

Emerging Market Economies

-4

-2

0 x

45

2

4

Figure A2. The effect of the level of interest rate on income inequality (Net Gini) (percent) 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 -0.5 -1 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid blue lines denote the response to the level of interest rates. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Figure 3.2. Estimates based on equation (3).

46

Figure A3. The effect of monetary policy on income inequality, the role of the level of interest rate (percent) Panel A. Low interest rate

-1

0

1

2

Panel B. High interest rate

3

4

8

8

6

6

4

4

2

2

0

0

-2

-2

-4

-4 -1

0

1

2

3

4

Note: t=0 is the year of the shock. Solid blue lines denote the response to an unanticipated monetary policy rates of 100 basis points in countries with relatively high (low) interest rates, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Figure 3.2. Estimates based on equation (5).

47