Une unité de soins pour adolescents: émergence et résistances

Une unité de soins pour adolescents: émergence et résistances

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B DOI 10.1007/s40031-015-0211-7 ORIGINAL CONTRIBUTION FACTS Devices Cost Recovery During Congestion Management in Deregulat...

1MB Sizes 26 Downloads 92 Views

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B DOI 10.1007/s40031-015-0211-7

ORIGINAL CONTRIBUTION

FACTS Devices Cost Recovery During Congestion Management in Deregulated Electricity Markets Ashwani Kumar Sharma1 • Ram Kumar Mittapalli1 • Yash Pal1

Received: 1 August 2014 / Accepted: 4 June 2015 Ó The Institution of Engineers (India) 2015

Abstract In future electricity markets, flexible alternating current transmission system (FACTS) devices will play key role for providing ancillary services. Since huge cost is involved for the FACTS devices placement in the power system, the cost invested has to be recovered in their life time for the replacement of these devices. The FACTS devices in future electricity markets can act as an ancillary services provider and have to be remunerated. The main contributions of the paper are: (1) investment recovery of FACTS devices during congestion management such as static VAR compensator and unified power flow controller along with thyristor controlled series compensator using non-linear bid curves, (2) the impact of ZIP load model on the FACTS cost recovery of the devices, (3) the comparison of results obtained without ZIP load model for both pool and hybrid market model, (4) secure bilateral transactions incorporation in hybrid market model. An optimal power flow based approach has been developed for maximizing social welfare including FACTS devices cost. The optimal placement of the FACTS devices have been obtained based on maximum social welfare. The results have been obtained for both pool and hybrid electricity market for IEEE 24-bus RTS. Keywords Congestion management  Ancillary services  FACTS devices cost recovery  Hybrid electricity market  ZIP load

& Ashwani Kumar Sharma [email protected] 1

Department of Electrical Engineering, National Institute of Technology Kurukshetra, Kurukshetra 136119, Haryana, India

List of symbols bij Bi ðPDi Þ ¼ b1di  P2Di þb2di  PDi þ b0i BSVC Ci ðPGi Þ ¼ ai  P2Gi þbi  PGi þ ci CS (CS)without FACTS (CS)with

FACTS

CSVC CTCSC CUPFC CFACTS annual CFACTS DF FACTS r Gij;eff ¼ r2 þðx ijx Þ2 ; ij x c Þ ij ðx Bij;eff ¼  r2 þðxij xc Þ2 ij c ij GD, GDij

GDmax ij ISO Nb Ng PS (PS)without (PS)with

FACTS

FACTS

Weighing factor indicating the importance of a particular transaction Bid function for the loads Susceptance of SVC Bid function for the generators Consumer surplus Consumer surplus without FACTS devices Consumer surplus with FACTS devices Cost function of SVC Cost function of TCSC Cost function of UPFC Cost with FACTS devices Annual cost with FACTS devices ac distribution factors Flexible ac transmission systems Effective conductance and susceptance with TCSC Represents a bilateral contract between a supplier (Pgi) of row i with a consumer (Pdj) of column j Maximum transaction amount Independent system operator Number of buses in the system Set of generators Producer surplus Producer surplus without FACTS devices Producer surplus with FACTS devices

123

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

Pdp, Pdb Pfp, Pfb Pgp, Pgb Pgi Pi max Pmin gi ; Pgi Pgi, Qgi Pdi, Qdi Qi max Qmin gi ; Qgi QSVC Rannual FACTS Sij, Sij  Smax ij SVC TCSC UPFC Vi Vsh,, dsh, Vse, dse Vimin ; Vimax Yij ¼ Gij þ Bij di max dmin i ; di gen k , kload kgen;FACTS , kload;FACTS

Vector of pool and bilateral demand Vector of line flows due to the pool and bilateral transactions Vector of pool and bilateral generation Active power pool generator-i Real power injection at bus-i Minimum and maximum generation limit Real and reactive power generation at bus-i Real and reactive power demand at bus-i Reactive power injection at bus-i Minimum and maximum generation limit Reactive support provided by SVC Annual revenue earned with FACTS devices Line flow limit Static VAR compensator Thyristor controlled series compensator Unified power flow controller Voltage magnitude at bus-i Shunt voltage and angle, series injected voltage and angle for UPFC Upper and lower voltage magnitude limit i-j th element of Y-bus matrix Load angle at bus-i Upper and lower angle limit Nodal price at generator and load buses without FACTS devices Nodal prices at the generator and load buses with FACTS devices

Introduction With the emerging competitive electricity markets, new technical challenges have emerged with many market players negotiating power purchase from market at competitive prices in a pool or bilateral coordinated electricity markets. The independent system operator (ISO) has to provide fair and transparent access to all market participants with more and bilateral negotiations of power purchase that may lead to congestion in the transmission system and may threaten system security. The congestion management has become a challenging issue for the ISO for better market operation as it may lead market inefficiency due to rise in the nodal prices with the change in

123

generation schedule [1, 2]. The electricity price will not be able to operate at its competitive equilibrium in congested systems in economic terms and may lead to ‘dead weight’ loss to the society. In order to alleviate congestion, some inexpensive generators in congested zone have to reduce their dispatch and some expensive generators in congested zone have to increase their dispatch. This can further lead to creation of local ‘market power’ and hinders the development of competitive environment in electricity trade [3]. When the system operator sets the electricity price and decides the dispatch amount in order to alleviate congestion, the operation of transmission directly affects the profit of the market participants. Thus, in recent years, congestion management has been a subject of great concern in deregulated electricity market. The market based approaches can be categorized based on locational marginal prices, price area zones, financial transmission rights, generation rescheduling, and load curtailment which are well explained [4–18]. A decomposition of spot prices to reveal congestion and the differences in the locational marginal prices reflect the presence of congestion in a transmission system and the customers charges are based on these locational differences in [4], assessment of impact of congestion to develop appropriate price signals in the pool paradigm for congestion management by Bompard et al. in [5], transmission congestion based on ex ante congestion prices are explained in [6]. A fixed transmission rights that can hedge congestion charges when utilized with locational marginal prices thereby defining zonal boundaries to managing congestion and efficient use of transmission system are presented in [7, 8]. Re-dispatching based schemes and application of FACTS to manage transmission congestion minimizing the congestion cost is presented by many authors [9–19]. Fang and David [9, 10] proposed a transmission dispatch methodology as an extension of spot pricing theory in a pool and bilateral as well as multilateral transactions model with willingness-to-pay for minimum curtailment to deal with the congestion, Ref. [11] presented optimal power dispatch in the presence of congestion, basic concepts using three approaches to mange congestion are proposed [12] and Bompard et al. [13] developed a unified framework and compared the various CM approaches so as to assess their efficiency and effectiveness of the market signals provided to the market participants. Tuan et al. proposed an interruptible load services during congestion management [14]. A comprehensive literature survey of congestion management methods and their categorization are presented [15]. A congestion management approach based on real and reactive power congestion distribution factors based zones and generator’s rescheduling was proposed [16, 17]. Many authors developed the methodology to incorporate FACTS devices to manage the transmission

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

congestion [18–27]. Recently demand side management (DSM) has been considered as a tool for congestion management in deregulated electricity markets [28–31]. For better utilization of existing power system, the role of FACTS devices has become imperative with benefits of increasing power transfer capability, security and stability of the transmission network [32–36]. The modeling of FACTS devices and their impact for loadability enhancement, real and reactive nodal prices determination in deregulated electricity markets are presented [37–41]. The ISO has to ensure secure bilateral transactions for dispatch of generators and these transactions have been determined [42–44]. These transactions have been incorporated along with pool transactions for the study of hybrid system. The ISO may procure the services of FACTS devices as an ancillary service and since, the capital as well as running cost is involved in the installation of FACTS devices and therefore, have to remunerate their services. Several studies, based on OPF calculations, have been carried out to determine the optimal placement of such devices in the system in order to get the maximum benefits out of their capabilities [45–52]. Some of the previous studies took into account the cost of FACTS devices and these can provide cost effective solution [53]. Generally, there are still very few studies of economic benefits arising from installation of FACTS devices. Most of the authors have concentrated on constant P-Q load models; however, the generic load model consideration is essential. The composite constant impedance-currentpower (ZIP) [54, 55] model has widely accepted as a default model among utility industries. The FACTS devices cost model has also been included in an optimization model and the methodology for FACTS cost remuneration was tested for five bus test system with TCSC only in [56]. The study was conducted with P,Q load considering the linear bid curves. However, generic load model incorporation is essential to incorporate as during congestion the voltage profile in the network become poor and bid curves are also non-linear in nature. In this study, a FACTS cost remuneration based approach described in [56] has been extended with three types of FACTS devices (static VAR compensator (SVC), thyristor controlled series capacitor (TCSC), and unified power flow controller (UPFC). The OPF based approach is employed to solve the non-linear optimization problem of maximizing social welfare. Optimal location of the devices has been obtained based on the procedure developed in [56] considering non-linear bid curves. The impact of ZIP load model has also been incorporated. The results have been obtained for pool market along with the secure bilateral transactions with constant P-Q and ZIP load model. The GAMS and MATLAB interfacing has been utilized to obtain optimal values calling CONOPT solver

[57, 58]. The results have been obtained on IEEE RTS-24 test system [59].

Mathematical Model of FACTS Devices and Cost Function In this section, the model of the FACTS devices for congestion management has been presented. For such applications, FACTS devices can be modeled as Power Injection Model (PIM) [37, 38]. The injection model describes the FACTS as a device that injects a certain amount of active and reactive power to a particular selected node, so that the FACTS device is represented as PQ element. The advantage of PIM is that it does not destroy the symmetrical structure of the admittance matrix and allows easy integration of FACTS devices into existing power system software tools [37, 38]. In this paper three FACTS devices namely SVC, TCSC, UPFC, is used to demonstrate the effectiveness of the proposal for investment recovery of these devices. Static VAR Compensator (SVC) The static VAR compensator (SVC) is a shunt compensation device comprising of fixed capacitor and variable inductor controlled through firing angle. It is originally designed for voltage maintenance in power systems. Operation of SVC is controlled by the adjusting by the selection of the firing angle of GTOs (Gate turn off transistors) or thyristors to change the reactance of inductor. During operation SVC behaves like shunt variable susceptance. SVC can work in inductive or capacitive region. For the steady state operation, constant susceptance model is considered. SVC is connected on any bus i shown in Fig. 1 [37]. The reactive power injection at bus i is given by QSVC ¼ Vi2 BSVC

ð1Þ

The cost function of SVC is given by an expression [47] CSVC ¼ 0:0003  s2  0:3051  s þ 127:38 $=kVAR

ð2Þ

Thyristor Controlled Series Compensator (TCSC) The model of a transmission line with TCSC connected between buses i and j is shown in Fig. 2. TCSC behaves as variable capacitive reactance. It reduces the line reactance during the operation which improves the power transfer capability. It works on the principle of series compensation. Reactance of TCSC is the function of firing angle of the thyristors. But the steady-state impedance of the TCSC is that of parallel LC circuit consisting of fixed capacitive

123

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

Vi

Vi

Pijc + jQ cij

Iij

Vs

Bus i

Zse

e

Pjic + jQ cji

Iji

Bus j

Ish Vi

XC

BSVC XL

Vj

Fig. 3 Model of UPFC

-jXc

Pji+jQji

Zij=Rij+jX Bus i

Re(V I∗ − V I* ) = 0 sh sh se ji

Vsh

Fig. 1 SVC and SVC variable susceptance

Pij+jQij

Zsh

jBc

Bus j

connected with the line with two coupling transformers. In the steady state operation, the main objective of an UPFC is to control voltage and power flow. The power injected model of UPFC is as shown Fig. 3 [37, 38]. The active power and reactive power equations at bus i and bus j can be written as: Pcij ¼ Vi2 ðGii þ Gsh Þ þ Vi Vj ½Gij cosðdij Þ þ Bij sinðdij Þ þVi Vse ½Gij cosðdi  dse Þ þ Bij sinðdi  dse Þ þVi Vsh ½Gsh cosðdi  dsh Þ þ Bsh sinðdi  dsh Þ

ð8Þ

Qcij ¼ Vi2 ðBij þ Bsh Þ þ Vi Vj ½Gij sinðdij Þ  Bij cosðdij Þ

Fig. 2 Model of TCSC

þVi Vse ½Gij sinðdi  dse Þ  Bij cosðdi  dse Þ þVi Vsh ½Gsh sinðdi  dsh Þ  Bsh cosðdi  dsh Þ impedance. The static model of TCSC is as shown in Fig. 2 [37, 38]. The power injection equations are Pcij ¼ Vi2 Gij;eff þ Vi Vj ðGij;eff cos dij þ Bij;eff sin dij Þ

ð3Þ

Qcij ¼ Vi2 ðBij;eff þ Bc Þ þ Vi Vj ðGij;eff sin dij  Bij;eff cos dij Þ ð4Þ Pcji ¼ Vj2 Gij;eff þ Vi Vj ðGij;eff cos dji þ Bij;eff sin dji Þ

ð5Þ

Qcji ¼ Vj2 ðBij;eff þ Bc Þ þ Vi Vj ðGij;eff sin dji  Bij;eff cos dji Þ ð6Þ where effective conductance and susceptance is given as rij Gij;eff ¼ 2 rij þ ðxij  xc Þ2 Bij;eff ¼ 

ðxij  xc Þ rij2

The cost function of TCSC is given by [47] ð7Þ

Unified Power Flow Controller (UPFC) An UPFC consists of two converters based on GTO (gate turn off), one is series connected and another is shunt

123

Pcji ¼ Vj2 Gjj þ Vi Vj ½Gij cosðdij Þ þ Bij sinðdij Þ þ Vj Vse ½Gij cosðdj  dse Þ þ Bij sinðdj  dse Þ

ð10Þ

Qcji ¼ Vj2 Bij þ Vi Vj ½Gij sinðdij Þ  Bij cosðdij Þ þ Vj Vse ½Gij sinðdj  dse Þ  Bij cosðdj  dse Þ

ð11Þ

The operating constraint for UPFC Vi Vse ½Gij cosðdi  dse Þ  Bij sinðdi  dse Þ þ Vj Vse ½Gij cosðdj  dse Þ  Bij sinðdj  dse Þ þ Vi2 Gsh þ Vi Vsh ½Gsh cosðdi  dsh Þ  Bsh sinðdi  dsh Þ ¼ 0 ð12Þ The cost function of UPFC is given by [47] CUPFC ¼ 0:0003  s2  0:2691  s þ 189:22 $ /kVAR ð13Þ

þ ðxij  xc Þ2

CTCSC ¼ 0:0015  s2  0:7130  s þ 153:75 $=kVAR

ð9Þ

The cost function of the FACTS devices as presented in [47] is shown in Fig. 4 and has been utilized for FACTS cost calculation along with the social welfare maximization in pool and hybrid market model. The impact of FACTs devices on producer and consumer surplus during the congestion management has been obtained so that FACTS devices can be remunerated according to their services in the electricity markets.

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

constant P, Q as well as generic load model (ZIP load). The formulation has been discussed for pool and bilateral market model. Problem Formulation Constant P-Q Load Model Pool Market Model

Fig. 4 Cost functions of the FACTS devices: SVC, TCSC and UPFC. Red curve upper limit: total investment costs; blue curve lower limit: equipment costs: UPFC:TCSC:SVC. (Color figure online)

The operating range of FACTS devices has been obtained based on maximum social welfare solving nonlinear program as discussed earlier. Once the optimum compensation level is found, the corresponding cost of FACTS is calculated from above equations. The cost can be compared with revenue (or benefit) that can be derived from FACTS. In this paper, the comparison is made by converting the cost, as well as the benefit (or revenue) into annual cost (annuity) (US$/year). To compute the annual capital cost and benefit (revenue) of FACTS, the following assumptions have been made: Project lifetime (n): 5 years Discount rate(r): 10 % Average utilization (u): 40 %

i2Ng

Operational cost of FACTS device is neglected. Annual capital cost of FACTS in US$/year can be found as:   r  ð1 þ r Þn Annual CFACTS ¼ CFACTS  s  1000  ð14Þ ð1 þ r Þn 1 The revenue from the use of FACTS is based on additional surplus and have the unit of ‘‘US$/h’’. Annual revenue from use of FACTS in US $/year can be determined as: RAnnual FACTS

¼ CFACTS  8760  u

In a pool market, the ISO dispatches optimally all the generators such that the social welfare is maximized respecting power injection equations as equality constraints and voltage, angle, power flow limits as inequality constraints. The impact of FACTS devices on the social welfare can be accounted taking the cost function of FACTS devices together with the social welfare function. The social welfare function comprises bids offered to the ISO by the Gencos and Discos. These bid functions have been taken as the quadratic bid functions. The objective of the OPF program is to minimize the total cost which is equivalent the maximization of the social welfare. The OPF program calculates the spot prices and the amount of optimal power the Gencos produce and Discos consume. The consumers can be billed based on the spot prices at respective buses. The formulation of social welfare maximization together with the FACTS devices cost function can be expressed as follows:   min Ctotal ¼ CFACTS ðsÞ þ Csurplus Pgi ; Pdi ð16Þ ! X   X Ci Pgi  Bi ðPdi Þ ð17Þ Csurplus ¼ i2Nd

Cost of FACTS devices are represented as quadratic cost functions. The bid offers from the producers and consumers can be expressed as quadratic functions with their cost coefficients. Ci ðPGi Þ ¼ ai  P2Gi þ bi  PGi þ ci Bi ðPDi Þ ¼ b1di 

P2Di

In this section, an optimization based approach of maximizing social welfare with FACTS devices cost function has been formulated. The loads have been modeled as

þ b2di  PDi þ b0i

ð19Þ

Subject to: Equality constraints: Pi ¼ Pgi  Pdi ¼

Nb X

Vi Vj ½Gij cosðdi  dj Þ

ð20Þ

j¼1

ð15Þ

An Optimal Power Flow Based Approach for FACTS Devices Remuneration for Congestion Management

ð18Þ

þ Bij sinðdi  dj Þ Qi ¼ Qgi  Qdi ¼

Nb X

8 i ¼ 1; 2; . . .Nb

Vi Vj ½Gij sinðdi  dj Þ

ð21Þ

j¼1

þ Bij cosðdi  dj Þ 8 i ¼ 1; 2; . . .Nb      Pij ¼ Vi2 Gij  Vi Vj Gij cos di  dj þ Bij sin di  dj ð22Þ

123

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

     Qij ¼ Vi2 Bij þ Vi Vj Bij cos di  dj  Gij sin di  dj ð23Þ 







Pji ¼ Vj2 Gij  Vi Vj Gij cos di  dj  Bij sin di  dj

 ð24Þ

Inequality constrains: Real and reactive power generation for generators is given as follows max Pmin g  Pg  Pg

ð25Þ

max Qmin g  Qg  Qg

ð26Þ

Transaction limit between seller bus-i and buyer bus j can be written as max GDmin ij  GDij  GDij

ð27Þ

Limits on voltage magnitude and angle can be expressed as Vimin  Vi  Vimax

ð28Þ

 di  dmax dmin i i

ð29Þ

MVA power flow limit is given by P2ij

þ Q2ij  Smax2 ij

ð30Þ

Hybrid Market The problem formulation in pool plus bilateral market consists of the above equations along with some additional constraints as power balance equations for demand and generation for hybrid market model using bilateral demand matrix GD. In addition to power balance equations, the bilateral matrix follows limits to be respected and can be added as a range rule. The methodology for the computation of secure bilateral transactions in a hybrid market model is well explained in [43]. The bilateral transactions can be represented as the bilateral negotiations between Gencos (G) and Discos (D).   ½GD ¼ DGT ð31Þ Each element of GD, namely GDij, represents a bilateral contract between a supplier (Pgi) of row i with a consumer (Pdj) of column j. Furthermore, the sum of row i represents the total power produced by generator i and the sum of column j represents the total power consumed at load j. GD can be expressed as 2 3 GD1;1 . . .GD1;nd 6 7 GD  4 GD2;1 . . .GD2;nd 5 ð32Þ GDng;1 . . .GDng;nd where, ng is the number of generators; and nd is the number of loads.

123

In general, the conventional load flow variables generation (Pbg) and load (Pbd) vectors are now expanded into two dimensional transaction matrix as given in (33). "

Pbd Pbg

#



GDT ¼ 0

0 GD

"

ug ud

# ð33Þ

Vector ug and ud are column vectors of ones with the dimensions of ng and nd respectively. There are some intrinsic properties associated with this transaction matrix GD (32). These are column rule, row rule, range rule, and flow rule. These properties have been explained in [42]. Each contract has to range from zero to a maximum allowable value, GDmax ij . This maximum value is bounded by the value of corresponding Pmax or Pdj whichever is gi smaller. The range rule satisfies:

max 0  GDij  GDmax ð34Þ ij  min Pgi ; Pdj It is also possible for some contracts to be firm so that GD0ij is equal to GDmax [20]. According to flow rule the line ij flows of the network can be expressed as follows: h i Pline ¼ DFAC Pbg  Pbd ð35Þ The matrix DFAC is the distribution factors matrix [43]. If the representations of the Pbg and Pbd are substituted by using the definition of GD, the line flows can be expressed in an alternative as follows:

Pline

2 3 1 6   .7 7 ¼ DF GD  GDT 6 4 .. 5

ð36Þ

1 With secure bilateral transaction matrix, the power injection equations can be modified with bilateral demand along with the pool demand. Problem Formulation with ZIP Load The general formulation of the problem is same as that without ZIP load. However, the loads are represented as a function of ZIP load coefficients and the voltages at each buses corresponding to the base case voltages. The real and reactive power injection equations are modified for ZIP load model as [54, 55]: Pi ¼ Pgni  Pdni

ð37Þ

Qi ¼ Qgni  Qdni

ð38Þ

where the real and reactive ZIP loads are represented as [55]:

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

"

#  Vi Pdni ¼ Pd0 ap þ bp þ c p V0i "  #   Vi 2 Vi aq þ b q þ cq Qdni ¼ Qd0 V0i V0i Vi V0i

2



ð39Þ

$/MWh C A

ð40Þ

Consumer surplus

*

D B

Producer surplus

The ZIP load coefficients with real and reactive power demand are ap ? bp ? cp = 1 and aq ? bq ? cq = 1. The different combinations of ZIP load coefficients have been taken for the Pdni and Qdni calculation in the power injection equations considering their impact on the investment recovery of FACTS devices.

Aggregate supply curve

Aggregate demand curve

Production cost O

P*

MW

Fig. 5 Surplus under unconstrained case

Investment Recovery of FACTS Devices for Congestion Management In the electricity market, Gencos and Discoms are the entities to generate and consume power. The generation companies sell power at a marginal price to recover the cost of capital investment and operating costs with a marginal profit to execute the new plant after the life of the plant is over. In a competitive electricity markets, both the Gencos as well as consumer must get benefits in terms of producer’s profit and the consumer’s benefit. The sum of Gencos and consumer surplus represents the social profit or social welfare (SW). Both the parties obtain the surplus for the economic and efficient electricity market operation. Thus, the objective of maximizing the social welfare recovers the price the electricity and makes the market operation economically efficient and viable. With both bid based market mechanism in a competitive electricity markets, the market clearing (MCP) is obtained at the point of cross section of aggregate marginal cost of production of Gencos and the aggregate willingness to pay curve of loads at point D as shown in Fig. 5. The MCP is denoted as k* at the cross section of aggregate curves corresponding to a power P* under unconstrained transmission case. The market equilibrium is disturbed due to the physical limits violation of the transmission system and other reasons like voltage limits, generation capacity constraints etc. Due to the transmission constraints called as transmission system congestion, the social surplus reduces as congestion rent. With a transmission physical limits violations, the power transfer will reduce from P* to Plimit as shown in Fig. 6. There will be two different prices at the two buses due to congestion in the network. At generator surplus bus the price reduces and at consumer bus the price goes up. This causes decrease in both consumer and producer surplus as shown in Fig. 6. An area representing a surplus loss with an arrow is shown in the Fig. 6. The congestion results an overall loss to society called as ‘dead-weight’

loss [56]. The congestion cost collected by the ISO is used either to compensate for the losses or to reinforce the transmission grid or transfer to the participants based on market rules. The price and quantity can be solved by solving the optimization problem with the objective of social welfare maximization subject to equations for power balance, line limits, voltage limits, and capacity limits constraints. The Lagrange multiplier of the real power balance equation as equality constraint gives the nodal price of energy. The producer’s surplus (PS) and consumer’s surplus (CS) can be calculated using equations based on the bid curves for both demand and supply submitted to the ISO and market clearing price. Form Fig. 5, PS and CS surplus can be defined. Producer surplus (PS) can be calculated as: Z Pdi PS ¼ ðki  CðPgi ÞÞoPgi ; i 2 Ng ð41Þ Pmin di

Consumer surplus (CS) can be calculated as: Z Pdi ðC ðPdi Þ  ki ÞoPdi ; i 2 Nd CS ¼

ð42Þ

Pmin di

C

Consumer surplus

surplus loss A

load

D Congestion cost

B Aggregate demand curve

gen

Producer surplus O

Aggregate supply curve

Production cost Plimit

P*

MW

Fig. 6 Surplus under constrained case

123

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

The congestion rent is given as: X X  ðki Pdi Þ ki Pgi CC ¼ i2Nd

ð43Þ

i2Ng

A

E load

where ki is the price of energy (that is, LMP) at bus i, the cost functions taken as quadratic equations for both producer and consumer is given as the quadratic generator bid curve and quadratic demand bid curve. Remuneration Cost Calculation for FACTS Devices During Congestion Management The FACTS devices have the capability of changing power flow patterns and voltage profile improvement in the network. With their incorporation in the network, these devices control transmission congestion due to change in the power flow patterns. These devices help the ISO for security enhancement and in future can play a role of ancillary service providers. Since huge capital cost is involved for their installation and these devices needs to be remunerated to recover capital as well as operating cost during their life time as an ancillary service providers. With the incorporation of FACTS devices, the resulting situation for the simple two-bus system as an example is shown in Fig. 6 also explained well in [57]. In the case of transmission congestion, the decrease in producer and consumer surplus as a congestion cost is shown in Fig. 7 with area EGHFE. The nodal price at generator and load buses is kgen and kload respectively. The congestion rent collected by the ISO shown by area EGHFE can be calculated as the product of the price differences and the area maximum flow through the link, that is, Plimit(kload - kgen). With FACTS devices installed in the system for congestion control, the Plimit increase to PFACTS and the nodal prices at the generator and load buses changes and are kgen;FACTS and kload;FACTS respectively. Therefore, the congestion cost now is represented by an area IMNJI. The congestion rent collected by the ISO shown by an area IMNJI can be calculated as the product of the price difference and the area maximum flow through the link, that is, PFACTS(kload,FACTS - kgen,FACTS) as shown in Fig. 7. Comparing areas with and without FACTS devices, the congestion cost reduces with FACTS devices with improvement in both consumer and producer surplus. The congestion rent that the ISO collect from the market participants, due to LMP difference at source and sink decreases due to the decrease in nodal prices difference. There is considerable increase in the surplus of consumer as shown by area IMCI as well as producer surplus shown by area JNOJ as shown in Fig. 7. Comparing the areas in the Fig. 7 with FACTS, the corresponding increase in the producer surplus is EGMIE and producer surplus is JNHFJ. The surplus areas are also shown in Figs. 8, 9 and the surplus loss as dead weight also decreases.

123

surplus lossnew

Consumer surplus

$/MWh C

G

load,FACTS

Congestion K L cost

J gen,FACTS

B

N

Aggregate demand curve

F

gen

Aggregate supply curve

M D

I

H

Production cost

Producer surplus O

Plimit

P*

MW

PFACTS

Fig. 7 Surplus under constrained case with FACTS

The corresponding increase in both producer and consumer surplus is due to the impact of FACTS devices and it can be considered as a benefit to FACTS devices installation. This increase in surplus can be transferred to investment on FACTS devices and recovery of operational cost of FACTS devices. The increase in the consumer surplus is shown in Fig. 8 as an area EMIE. This increase in the producer can be calculated knowing the CS without and with FACTS devices. The CS without and with FACTS devices can be expressed as: Z Pdi ;limit   ðCSÞwithout FACTS ¼ C ðPdi Þ  kload oPdi ; i 2 Nd i Pmin di

ð44Þ ðCSÞwith FACTS ¼

Z

Pdi ;FACTS



Pmin di

CðPdi Þ  kload;FACTS oPdi ; i

i 2 Nd ð45Þ

$/MWh

C E

load load,FACTS

G I

M

K

B Aggregate demand curve

O

Plimit

PFACTS

MW

Fig. 8 Transfer of consumer surplus to FACTS investment at load bus

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

$/MWh A

gen,FACTS

L

J

gen

Aggregate supply curve

N

H F

O

Plimit

PFACTS

MW

Fig. 10 ZIP load coefficients taken at each load bus in the system Fig. 9 Transfer of producer surplus to FACTS investment at generator bus

The consumer surplus enhancement with FACTS can thus be calculated as area EMIE and can be expressed as difference of CS with and without FACTS devices as: ðCSÞenhancement ¼ ðCSÞwith FACTS ðCSÞwithout FACTS ð46Þ Z Pdi ;FACTS

C ðPdi Þ  kload;FACTS ðCSÞenhancement ¼ oPdi i Pmin di Z Pdi ;limit   oPdi ;  C ðPdi Þ  kload i Pmin di

i 2 Nd ð47Þ The producer surplus enhancement with incorporation of FACTS devices is shown in Fig. 9 as an area JNHFJ. The enhanced area can be calculated knowing the PS without and with FACTS devices. PS without FACTS is given as: Z Plimit gi  gen   ðPSÞwithout FACTS ¼ ki  C Pgi oPgi ; i 2 Ng Pmin gi

ð48Þ PS with FACTS is given as: Z PFACTS

gi   kgen;FACTS  C Pgi oPgi ; ðPSÞwith FACTS ¼ i Pmin gi

load bus decreases with FACTS, then the contribution to FACTS investment comes from increase in consumer surplus as given by the shaded area. This increment in surplus can be given to the investor of FACTS devices. In a similar manner, the marginal prices at generator bus without and with FACTS are shown in Fig. 7 and with contribution of FACTS, the additional producer surplus can be obtained with different marginal prices obtained at the generator buses without and with FACTS. This additional surplus can be transferred to FACTS devices during congestion management. With the installation of FACTS devices, there can also be a situation where the marginal price at the load bus increases or marginal prices decrease at generator bus. In such case, the methodology proposed in [56] can be adopted for remuneration of FACTS devices. A portion of revenue that is a part of congestion rent can be utilized to investment recovery of FACTS devices, as FACTS devices help to relieve the network congestion. The methodology was tested for five bus test system with TCSC only [56]. In the present work, the methodology has been extended taking into consideration the cost of FACTS devices in an objective function along with social welfare maximization for IEEE 24 bus test system with three FACTS devices viz. SVC, TCSC, and UPFC for both pool and bilateral market environment.

ð49Þ

i 2 Ng

Results and Discussion

The enhancement in PS is given as: ðPSÞenhancement ¼ ðPSÞwith FACTS ðPSÞwithout FACTS Z PFACTS

gi   kgen;FACTS  C Pgi oPgi ðPSÞenhancement ¼ i

ð50Þ

Pmin gi



Z

Plimit gi Pmin gi



  kgen  C Pgi oPgi ; i

ð51Þ

i 2 Ng The marginal prices with and without FACTS installation at load bus are shown in Fig. 7. It shows that if the price at

The results have been obtained for the IEEE RTS-24 test system [59]. The system consists of 38 lines and 24 buses including 17 load buses and 10 generation buses. The total numbers of generating units are 32 with the installed capacity of 3405 MW. The annual peal load is 2850 MW. The results have been obtained considering three lines congestion cases as: 1.

The rating of 23rd line which is connected between buses 14 and 16 is taken as 2.60 p.u while the actual rating is 5.00 p.u

123

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B Table 1 Different parameters without ZIP load WOF

SVC

TCSC

UPFC

Producer surplus ($/h)

67.5500

67.57188

67.66357

67.66966

Customer surplus ($/h)

108.4865

108.498

108.606

108.646

Revenue (US $ million)



0.6278

0.791

0.903

Capital cost (US $ million)



0.266

0.768

0.937

Facts cost ($/kVAR)



126.7395

153.7043

187.5455

Size (kVAR)

1015.0

475.2692

890.7336

Location

Bus 6

Line 6–10

Bus 6, Line 6–10

Table 2 Different parameters with ZIP load WOF

SVC

TCSC

UPFC

Producer surplus

66.8834

66.90118

66.92453

68.0812

Customer surplus

105.0145

105.139

105.089

105.347

Revenue (US $ million)



0.892

0.639

0.762

Capital (US $ million)



0.1742

0.7684

0.9405

FACTS cost ($/kVAR)



126.9618

153.695

188.1114

Size (kVAR)

1015.6

475.2628

890.098

Location

Bus 6

Line 6–10

Bus 6, Line 6–10

Table 3 Various parameters without ZIP load WOF

SVC

TCSC

UPFC

Social welfare ($/h)

14,581.2240

14,581.25

14,581.22

14,580.73

Producer surplus ($/h)

67.5467

67.57114

67.6526

68.80726

Customer surplus ($/h)

108.4683

108.479

108.582

108.855

Revenue (US $ million)



0.624

0.786

0.721

Capital (US $ million)



0.6337

0.7684

1.046918

FACTS cost ($/kVAR)



126.7405

153.6939

187.9527

Size (kVAR)

1014.9

475.2613

890.5106

Location

Bus 6

Line 6–10

Bus 6, Line 6–10

2.

3.

The rating of 18th line which is connected between buses 11 and 13 is taken as 2.25 p.u while the actual rating is 5.00 p.u The rating of 11th line which is connected between buses 7 and 8 is taken as 1.50 p.u while the actual rating is 1.75 p.u. The different combinations for ZIP load model taken for the study are shown in Fig. 10.

The location for the FACTS devices has been obtained based on the social welfare maximization as described. Each FACTS device is placed at a time at respective buses and social welfare is calculated. The location where maximum social welfare has been obtained, it is taken as the optimal location for the FACTS devices. Optimal location of the devices has been described well in [56]. The location and the sizes obtained for the maximum social welfare is

123

shown in the red color in the Tables 1, 2 for pool model with constant P-Q load and ZIP load model and in Tables 3, 4 for hybrid market model with constant P-Q load and ZIP load model. Results for Pool Market with Constant P-Q Load Model and ZIP Load Model The proposed methodology for FACTS cost benefit evaluation is implemented on IEEE 24 bus RTS with FACTS devices, such as, SVC, TCSC, and UPFC. The results have been obtained with pool market model and hybrid market model considering secure bilateral transaction matrix. The determination of secure bilateral transactions is well explained in [43, 44]. The results obtained without and

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B Table 4 Various parameters with ZIP load WOF

SVC

TCSC

UPFC

Social welfare ($/h)

14,571.9894

14,571.99

14,571.99

14,571.64

Producer surplus ($/h)

66.862

66.87985

66.91184

68.14574

Customer surplus ($/h)

104.9217

105.045

104.994

105.286

Revenue (US $ million)



0.88

0.625

0.898

Capital (US $ million)



0.6348

0.7684

0.9401

FACTS cost ($/kVAR)



126.9618

153.6946

188.0199

Size (kVAR)

1015.6

475.2643

898.7595

Location

Bus 6

Line 6–10

Bus 6, Line 6–10

Table 5 LMP with and without FACTS devices and without and with ZIP load model Bus no

Without ZIP load

With ZIP load

WOF

SVC

TCSC

UPFC

WOF

SVC

TCSC

UPFC

1

25.45112

25.46602

25.48389

25.49263

25.73018

25.7017

25.74706

26.51303

2

25.45143

25.46263

25.48735

25.49683

25.71593

25.75055

25.73484

26.41233

3

25.93828

25.94925

25.97232

25.98701

30.92398

30.90214

30.86925

31.19723

4

26.33459

26.36552

26.37907

26.39572

27.1202

28.26886

27.16584

27.45158

5

26.12985

26.14889

26.17999

26.19465

26.38816

26.37611

26.41352

27.70024

6

26.35448

26.35188

26.46488

26.48326

26.60554

26.6366

26.63923

26.65765

7 8

20.1373 26.32156

20.13728 26.32365

20.13726 26.37977

20.13722 26.40104

20.1357 26.98817

20.1357 26.98791

20.1357 27.00794

20.13583 26.84638

9

25.9475

25.95197

25.99383

26.01158

27.09526

27.09606

27.14739

27.1191

10

26.00658

26.00872

26.06985

26.08854

26.36131

26.36522

26.39366

26.20044

11

25.90783

25.90359

25.96227

25.97122

26.14497

26.14549

26.16966

26.10281

12

25.83835

25.83591

25.87927

25.88138

26.13129

26.13197

26.15719

26.08649

13

25.32762

25.32904

25.36485

25.36744

25.34472

25.34543

25.36463

25.30988

14

25.79388

25.78618

25.86532

25.87647

25.74246

25.7423

25.75947

25.72315

15

25.04023

25.03984

25.03788

25.03776

25.05308

25.05297

25.05082

25.05806

16

25.07704

25.07702

25.07161

25.06923

25.05367

25.05374

25.05122

25.05303

17

24.60374

24.60342

24.593

24.58927

24.41226

24.41364

24.403

24.40978

18

24.46281

24.46192

24.45157

24.44942

24.21188

24.21359

24.2032

24.20957

19

25.29748

25.29617

25.28774

25.29874

25.24822

25.24806

25.24286

25.24709

20

25.25984

25.25903

25.2365

25.26338

25.2281

25.22807

25.2096

25.22474

21

24.38409

24.38248

24.37323

24.37251

24.15905

24.16095

24.15057

24.15698

22 23

23.76215 25.152

23.76099 25.15249

23.75012 25.15978

23.74823 25.15754

23.50218 25.14361

23.50542 25.14365

23.48757 25.14847

23.49566 25.13888

24

25.62903

25.62921

25.63964

25.64726

27.002

26.9956

26.98784

27.09376

with FACTS devices considering constant P,Q loads as well as ZIP load model. The producer surplus, consumer surplus, annual revenue with FACTS devices, capital cost, and FACTS devices cost with the location of FACTs devices and their sizes for providing reactive support are given in Table 1. As observed from table that there is increase in producer surplus of 67.57188 $/h with SVC, 67.6657 $/h with TCSC and 67.669661 $/h with UPFC. The FACTS devices cost obtained for UPFC is more

compared to the cost of other devices due to higher reactive support obtained from UPFC compared to other FACTS devices as well as its cost curve. The producer surplus, consumer surplus, annual revenue with FACTS devices, capital cost, and FACTS devices cost with the location of FACTs devices and their sizes for providing reactive support with ZIP load are given in Table 2. With ZIP load it is observed that social welfare reduces. The produce and consumer surplus also reduces compared to the case with

123

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B WOF (P,Q)

SVC(P,Q)

TCSC(P,Q)

UPFC(P,Q)

WOF(ZIP)

SVC(ZIP)

TCSC(ZIP)

Marginal prices ($/MWh)

35 30 25 20 15 10 5

21

23

r

17

umbe

WOF(ZIP)

19

13

Bus n

15

9

Fig. 14 Customer surplus 11

5

7

1

3

0

WOF (P,Q)

Fig. 11 Comparison of LMPs without and with FACTS devices and ZIP load model

Fig. 15 Annual revenue Fig. 12 FACTS cost comparison Table 6 Coefficients for ZIP load Bus no

Fig. 13 Producer surplus

P,Q load model. This is due to the slight reduction in the loads due to the voltage dependency as voltage decrease during congestion in a system. The FACTS devices cost obtained for UPFC is more compared to the cost of other devices due to more reactive support obtained from UPFC compared to other FACTS devices. The cost is also found slightly higher with ZIP load compared to constant P,Q load due to higher reactive support requirements with ZIP load. The nodal prices obtained without and with FACTS devices are also given in Table 5. It is found that LMPs at each bus with FACTS devices are found different than without FACTS devices. With UPFC, LMPs are observed lower compared to the other FACTS devices. With ZIP

123

Real power

Reactive power

ap

bp

cp

aq

bq

cq

1

0.1

0.2

0.7

0.1

0.2

0.7

2

0.2

0.3

0.5

0.2

0.3

0.5

3

0.3

0.2

0.5

0.3

0.2

0.5

4

0.2

0.1

0.7

0.2

0.1

0.7

5

0.1

0.1

0.8

0.1

0.1

0.8

6

0.2

0.2

0.6

0.2

0.2

0.6

7 8

0.3 0.2

0.2 0.1

0.5 0.7

0.3 0.2

0.2 0.1

0.5 0.7

9

0.1

0.2

0.7

0.1

0.2

0.7

10

0.1

0.1

0.8

0.1

0.1

0.8

13

0.2

0.3

0.5

0.2

0.3

0.5

14

0.3

0.2

0.5

0.3

0.2

0.5

15

0.2

0.1

0.7

0.2

0.1

0.7

16

0.1

0.1

0.8

0.1

0.1

0.8

18

0.3

0.2

0.5

0.3

0.2

0.5

19

0.2

0.1

0.7

0.2

0.1

0.7

20

0.1

0.2

0.7

0.1

0.2

0.7

load, the marginal prices are obtained different and LMPs at some buses reduces with FACTS devices. The comparison of marginal prices obtained without and with ZIP load is shown in Fig. 11.

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B Table 7 LMP with and without ZIP load Bus no

Without ZIP load

With ZIP load

WOF

SVC

TCSC

UPFC

WOF

SVC

TCSC

1

25.45403

25.47113

25.4861

26.25056

25.72554

25.69728

25.74203

26.55775

2

25.45308

25.46611

25.48813

26.15286

25.71138

25.74584

25.73

26.45304

3

25.93651

25.94814

25.96898

26.15674

30.94599

30.9242

30.87754

31.21111

4

26.33134

26.36337

26.37471

26.7007

27.13883

28.28044

27.18543

27.45363

5

26.12544

26.14546

26.17408

27.65623

26.36878

26.35683

26.394

28.00983

6

26.32881

26.32192

26.43468

26.04916

26.56813

26.59901

26.6019

26.71749

7 8

20.1375 26.29321

20.1375 26.29377

20.1375 26.34727

20.1375 26.23523

20.13538 26.72894

20.13538 26.72869

20.13538 26.74734

20.13535 26.65078

9

25.94284

25.94722

25.98795

26.02741

27.11963

27.12042

27.17302

27.09416

10

25.99637

25.99749

26.0576

25.80542

26.33132

26.33522

26.36378

26.22583

11

25.90639

25.90187

25.96007

25.88376

26.14301

26.14353

26.16785

26.09779

12

25.83737

25.83475

25.87759

25.79854

26.12895

26.12963

26.15516

26.08059

13

25.32455

25.32567

25.36101

25.30126

25.34336

25.34407

25.36345

25.30583

14

25.79304

25.78496

25.86393

25.81232

25.74187

25.74171

25.75864

25.72072

15

25.0404

25.04002

25.03669

25.04664

25.05333

25.05322

25.05104

25.05855

16

25.07717

25.07717

25.07128

25.0741

25.05363

25.0537

25.05124

25.05291

17

24.60358

24.60323

24.59235

24.60318

24.41117

24.41254

24.40305

24.40997

18

24.46288

24.46195

24.45122

24.4637

24.21051

24.21222

24.20329

24.20988

19

25.29842

25.29716

25.28833

25.29449

25.24827

25.24811

25.2428

25.24669

20

25.26029

25.25949

25.23655

25.25601

25.228

25.22797

25.20946

25.22414

21

24.38448

24.38285

24.37274

24.38634

24.15748

24.15938

24.15061

24.15737

22 23

23.76233 25.15146

23.76114 25.1519

23.7496 25.15909

23.76319 25.14732

23.49939 25.14343

23.50262 25.14347

23.4875 25.14827

23.49595 25.13825

24

25.62955

25.62995

25.63887

25.71701

27.00879

27.0024

26.99063

27.0996

The FACTS cost comparison is shown in Fig. 12. It is observed from the figure that FACTS cost per kVAR is higher for UPFC compared to other FACTS devices. This is due to the higher reactive support and correspondingly higher cost component for UPFC. With ZIP load, the FACTS cost component is found slightly higher due to more reactive support demanded by the ZIP load due to its voltage dependency. The producer surplus, customer surplus, and annual revenue obtained with FACTS devices without and with ZIP load is shown in Figs. 13, 14 and 15. With ZIP load, the customer surplus slightly reduces compared to constant P,Q load. However, the surplus improves with all FACTS devices for P,Q as well as ZIP load model. The producer surplus with ZIP load model improves with all FACTS devices and with UPFC in case of ZIP load model, PS is observed slightly higher due to increase in marginal prices at respective nodes with UPFC. Annual revenue earned with UPFC is higher compared to other FACTS devices due to the higher support of reactive power obtained from UPFC. In case of SVC, the annual revenue earned is more for ZIP load compared to constant P,Q load due to its higher reactive power support in case of ZIP load.

UPFC

Results for Hybrid Market For hybrid market model, 30 % bilateral and 70 % have been taken as Pool demand. The results are obtained with ZIP load as well as constant P-Q load. The date for the ZIP load coefficients is given in Table 6. The producer surplus, consumer surplus, annual revenue with FACTS devices, capital cost, and FACTS devices cost with the location of FACTs devices and their sizes for providing reactive support are given in Table 3. As observed from table producer surplus of 67.57144 $/h with SVC, 67.6526 $/h with TCSC and 68.80726 $/h with UPFC are obtained and it increases with FACTS devices. The FACTS cost obtained for UPFC is more compared to the cost of other devices due to more reactive support obtained from UPFC compared to other devices as well as higher cost component. For ZIP load model, the FACTS devices cost slightly increases compared to constant P-Q load due to higher reactive support in the system. The producer’s and customers’ surplus increase with FACTS devices for both load models. The producer surplus, consumer surplus, annual revenue with FACTS devices, capital cost, and FACTS devices cost

123

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

Marginal prices ($/MWh)

WOF (P,Q)

SVC(P,Q)

TCSC(P,Q)

UPFC(P,Q)

WOF(ZIP)

SVC(ZIP)

TCSC(ZIP)

UPFC(ZIP)

35 30 25 20 15 10 5

21

23

er

17

SVC(ZIP)

19

13

nu mb

15

9

Bus

11

5

7

1

3

0

Fig. 18 Producer surplus

WOF (P,Q)

Fig. 16 Comparison of LMPs without and with FACTS devices and ZIP load model

Fig. 19 Customer surplus

Fig. 17 Comparison of FACTS cost

with the location of FACTs devices and their sizes for providing reactive support with ZIP load are given in Table 4. With ZIP load it is observed that the producer and consumer surplus reduces slightly compared to the case with P-Q load model. This is due to the reduction in the loads due to the voltage dependency as voltage profile becomes poor during congestion in the system. During congestion, the reactive power consumption and loss pattern increases due to higher current in the system that results in voltage profile to become poor and thereby reducing loads at some buses. The nodal prices obtained without and with FACTS devices are also given in Table 7. It is found that LMPs changes at each bus for both load models. With FACTS devices LMPs at some buses increases and at some other buses these decreases. The comparison of LMPs obtained at each bus without and with FACTS devices without and with ZIP load is also shown in Fig. 16. With ZIP load model, LMPs are found different with and without FACTS devices. The FACTs cost comparison is shown in Fig. 17. It is observed from the figure that FACTS cost per kVAR is higher for UPFC compared to other FACTs devices. This is due to the higher reactive support and correspondingly higher cost component for UPFC. With ZIP load, the FACTS cost component is found slightly higher due to more reactive support demanded by the ZIP load due to its

123

Fig. 20 Annual revenue

voltage dependency. The producer surplus, customer surplus, and annual revenue obtained without and with FACTS devices and constant P,Q load and ZIP load is shown in Figs. 18, 19 and 20. Both PS and CS increases with FACTS devices for constant P,Q load as well as ZIP load model. With UPFC, the PS and CS are higher compared to other FACTS devices both for P,Q and ZIP load models. Annual revenue with SVC and UPFC with ZIP load is found higher due to the higher reactive support from SVC and UPFC with ZIP load.

Conclusions In this paper, the investment recovery of FACTS devices for congestion management has been implemented for both pool and hybrid electricity market models considering both

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B

constant power loads and generic load model. In hybrid market model, the secure bilateral transactions have been obtained and incorporated in the model. The impact of ZIP load model has also been studied for both the market model and the producers and consumers surplus has been obtained. The annual revenue with the FACTS devices has been also obtained. The PS and CS increases with all FACTS devices considering both P,Q and ZIP load models. With ZIP load, PS as well as CS reduces slightly due to the changes in marginal prices at both load and generator buses. Annual revenue earned with UPFC is more compared to other FACTS devices. It is important to consider realistic load model for FACTS cost remuneration as FACTS devices provide reactive support services along with change in marginal prices. In future electricity markets, FACTS devices will sell their support services as ancillary services provider and need to be remunerated for their services.

References 1. M. Shahidepour, M. Alomoush, Restructured electrical power systems, operation, trading, and volatility (Marcel Dekker, Inc., New York, 2001) 2. D. Shirmohammadi, B. Wollenberg, A. Vojdani, P. Sandrin, M. Pereira, F. Rahimi, T. Schneider, B. Stott, Transmission dispatch and congestion management in the emerging energy market structures. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 13(4), 1466–1476 (1998) 3. P.L. Joskow, J. Tirole, Transmission rights and market power on electric power networks. RAND J. Econ. 31(Autumn 3), 450–487 (2000) 4. H. Singh, S. Hao, A. Papalexopoulos, Transmission congestion management in competitive markets. IEEE Trans. Power Systems 13(2), 672–680 (1998) 5. E. Bompard, E. Carpenato, G. Chicco, G. Gross, The role of load demand elasticity in congestion management and pricing, in Proceedings of IEEE PES, Summer Meeting (2009), pp. 2229–2234 6. S. Hao, D. Shirmohammadi, Congestion management with Ex Ante pricing for decentralized markets. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 17(4), 1030–1036 (2002) 7. M.I. Alomoush, S.M. Shahidehpour, Fixed transmission rights for zonal congestion management. IEE Proc. Gener. Transm. Distrib. 146(5), 471–476 (1999) 8. M.I. Alomoush, S.M. Shahidehpour, Generalized model for fixed transmission rights auction. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 54(6), 207–220 (2000) 9. R.S. Fang, A.K. David, Transmission congestion management in an electricity market. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 14(2), 877–883 (1999) 10. R.S. Fang, A.K. David, Optimal dispatch under transmission contracts. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 14(2), 732–737 (1999) 11. S.C. Srivastava, P. Kumar, Optimal power dispatch in deregulated market considering congestion management, in Proceedings of the International Conference on Electric Utility Deregulation and Restructuring and Power Technologies, DRPT (2000), pp. 53–59 12. R.D. Christie, B.F. Wollenberg, I. Wangstien, Transmission management in the deregulated environment. Proc. IEEE 88(2), 170–195 (2000)

13. E. Bompard, P. Correia, G. Gross, M. Amelin, Congestionmanagement schemes: a comparative analysis under a unified framework. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 18(1), 346–352 (2003) 14. L.A. Tuan, K. Bhattacharya, J. Daalder, Transmission congestion management in bilateral markets: an interruptible load auction solution. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 74, 379–389 (2005) 15. A. Kumar, S.C. Srivastava, S.N. Singh, Congestion management in competitive electricity markets—a bibliographical survey. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 76(4), 153–164 (2005) 16. A. Kumar, S.C. Srivastava, S.N. Singh, A zonal congestion management approach using real and reactive power rescheduling. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 18(1), 554–562 (2004) 17. A. Kumar, S.C. Srivastava, S.N. Singh, A zonal congestion management approach using AC transmission congestion distribution factors. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 72(11), 85–93 (2004) 18. S. Phichaisawat, Y.H. Song, X.L. Wang, X.F. Bang, Combined active and reactive congestion management with FACTS devices. Electr. Power Compon. Syst. 30, 1195–1205 (2002) 19. G.M. Huang, P. Yan, TCSC and SVC as re-dispatch tools for congestion management and TTC improvement. Proc. IEEE Power Eng. Soc. Winter Meet. 1, 660–665 (2002) 20. G. Yesuratnam, M. Pushpa, Congestion management for security oriented power system operation using generation rescheduling, in Proceedings of IEEE 11th International Conference on Probabilistic Methods Applied to Power Systems PMAPS (2010) 21. K.S. Verma, S.N. Singh, H.O. Gupta, Location of unified power flow controller for congestion management. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 58, 89–96 (2001) 22. S. Singh, A. David, A new approach for placement of FACTS devices in open power markets. IEEE Power Eng. Rev. 21, 58–60 (2000) 23. S. Singh, A. David, A new approach for placement of FACTS devices in open power markets. IEEE Power Eng. Rev. 21, 58–60 (2001) 24. N. Acharya, N. Mithulananthan, Influence of TCSC on congestion and spot price in electricity market with bilateral contract. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 77, 1010–1018 (2007) 25. N. Acharya, N. Mithulananthan, Locating series FACTS devices for congestion management in deregulated electricity markets. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 77, 352–360 (2007) 26. H. Besharat, S.A. Taher, Congestion management by determining optimal location of TCSC in deregulated power systems. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 30, 563–568 (2008) 27. S. Rahimzadeh, M. Tavakoli Bina, Looking for optimal number and placement of FACTS devices to manage the transmission congestion. Energy Convers. Manag. 52, 437–446 (2011) 28. M.H. Albadi, E.F. El-Saadany, A summary of demand response in electricity markets. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 78(12), 1989– 1996 (2008) 29. C.M. Affonso, L.C.P. da Silva, Potential benefits of implementing load management to improve power system security. Int J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 32(11), 704–710 (2010) 30. A. Yousefi, T.T. Nguyen, H. Zareipour, O.P. Malik, Congestion management using demand response and FACTS devices. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 37(1), 78–84 (2012) 31. A. Kumar, C. Sekhar, DSM based congestion management in pool electricity markets with FACTS devices. Elsevier Energy Procedia 14(1), 94–100 (2012) 32. P. Bhasaputra, W. Ongsakul, Optimal placement of multi-type FACTS devices by hybrid TS/TA approach, in ISCAS 2003, International Symposium on Circuits and Systems, Bangkok, Thailand, IEEE, May 25–28 (2003) 33. S.S. Gerbex, R. Cherkaoui, A.J. Germond, Optimal location of multi-type FACTS devices in a power system by means of genetic algorithm. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 16, 537–544 (2001)

123

J. Inst. Eng. India Ser. B 34. F.D. Galiana, K. Almeida, M. Toussaint, J. Griffin, D. Atanackovic, Assessment and control of the impact of FACTS devices on power system performance. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 11(4), 1931–1936 (1996) 35. A. Sode-Yome, N. Mithulananthan, Comparison of shunt capacitor, SVC and STATCOM in static voltage stability margin enhancement. Int. J. Electr. Eng. Educ. 41, 158–171 (2004) 36. C. Schaffner, G. Anderson, Determining the value of controllable devices in a liberalized electricity market: a new approach, in Proceedings of Seventh International Conference on AC–DC Power transmission (2001) 37. L. Gyugyi, N.G. Hingorani, Understanding FACTS: Concept and Technology of Flexible AC Transmission System (IEEE Press, Piscataway, 2001) 38. E.E. Acha, C.R.E. Fuerte, H. Ambize-Perez, C. Angeles-Camacho, FACTS: Modelling and Simulation in Power Networks (Wiley, New York, 2002). ISBN 0-470-85271-2 39. A. Kumar, W. Gao, Power flow model of ‘Sen’ transformer for loadability enhancement and comparison with UPFC in hybrid electricity markets. Electr. Power Compon. Syst. 37, 189–209 (2009) 40. C. Saurabh, A. Kumar, Effect of optimally located FACTS devices on active and reactive power prices in deregulated electricity markets, in Proceedings of International Conference IEEE PIC (2006) 41. S. Chanana, A. Kumar, Comparison of sen transformer and UPFC for real and reactive power marginal price under maximum loadability condition. Electr. Power Compon. Syst. 36, 1369–1387 (2008) 42. J.W.M. Cheng, F.D. Galiana, D.T. McGills, Studies of bilateral contracts with respect to steady state security in a deregulated environment. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 13(3), 1020–1025 (1998) 43. A.K. Sharma, New secure bilateral transaction matrix determination using AC distribution factors and impact of TCPAR and TCSC on its pattern. Electr. Power Compon. Syst. 35, 21–943 (2007) 44. A. Kumar, S. Chanana, New multi-objective problem for secure bilateral transaction determination with UPFC in hybrid electricity markets. Electr. Power Compon. Syst. 36(6), 555–574 (2008) 45. E.J. Oliveria, J.W.M. Lima, K.C. Almedia, Allocation of FACTS devices in hydrothermal systems. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 15, 276–282 (2000) 46. L. Pilotto, W. Ping, A. Carvalho, A. Wey, W. Long, F. Alvarado, A. Edris, Determination of needed FACTS controllers that increase assets utilization of power systems. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 12, 364–371 (1997) 47. L.J. Cai, I. Erlich, Optimal choice and allocation of FACTS devices using genetic algorithm, in ISAP, Intelligent Systems

123

48.

49.

50.

51.

52.

53.

54.

55. 56.

57. 58.

59.

Applications to Power Systems, Lemnos, Greece, Aug 31–Sept 3 (2003) A.A. Alabduljabbar, J.V. Milanovic, Assessment of techno-economic contribution of FACTS devices to power system operation. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 80, 1247–1255 (2010) D. Watts, H. Ren, FACTS: characteristics, applications and economical value, a literatural review, in Proceedings of Seventh IASTED International Conference Power and Energy Systems, Palma de Mallorca, Spain (2007) A. Aladbuljabbar, J.V. Milanovic, Placement and tuning of SVCs for the improvement of techno-economic performance of the network based on sequential number theoretic optimization algorithm, in CD-ROM of the IEEE Power Systems Conferences and Expositions, PSCE’06, Atlanta, GA, USA, Oct 29–Nov 1 (2006) A. Aladbuljabbar, J.V. Milanovic, Generation costs reduction through optimal allocation of FACTS devices using low discrepancy sequences, in CD-ROM of the IEEE Power Systems Conferences and Expositions, PSCE’06, Atlanta, GA, USA, Oct 29–Nov 1 (2006) K. Habur, D. O’Leans, FACTS-flexible alternating current transmission systems: for cost effective and reliable transmission of electrical energy, available at www.worldbank.org/html/fpd/ em/tr,Transmission/facts_seimens.pdf, downloaded date Aug 15 (2004) A. Kumar, P. Kumar, Nodal pricing with different reactive power cost models in Hybrid electricity markets, in Proceedings of the International Conference on Power, Control, and Embedded Systems (ICPCES), at MNIT Allahabad, Nov 28–Dec 1 (2010) F.L. Qulumba, L. Wei-Jen, H. Huang, D.Y. Wang, R.L. Szabados, Load model development for next generation appliances, in IEEE Transactions (2011), pp. 1–7 P. Kundur, Power system stability and control, EPRI (Power Syst. Eng. Ser., TMH, 2007) N. Mithulananthan, N. Acharya, A proposal for the investment recovery of FACTS devices in deregulated electricity markets. Int. J. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 77, 695–703 (2007) M.C. Ferris, MATLAB and GAMS: Interfacing Optimization and Visualization Software, Aug 10 (1999) D.A. Kendrick, A. Meeraus, R. Raman, R.E. Rasenthal, A User’s Guide, GAMS Software (GAMS Development Corporation, Brooke, 1998) IEEE Reliability Test System, A report prepared by the reliability test system task force of the applications of probability methods subcommittee, in IEEE Transactions on Power Apparatus and Systems, PAS-98 (1979), pp. 2047–2054